General Principles - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 66
About This Presentation
Title:

General Principles

Description:

Directly, using expected value ... Utility function provides a procedure for ranking random ... Sybil, a moderately successful venture capitalist, is anxious ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:51
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 67
Provided by: Indus7
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: General Principles


1
General Principles
  • Evaluation of a random cash flows
  • Directly, using expected value and variance.
  • Indirectly, using combination of other known or
    estimated cash flow.

2
Utility Functions
  • Utility function provides a procedure for ranking
    random wealth levels.
  • Denote by U a utility function and by x,y outcome
    random wealth variables.
  • U- utility function
  • Defined on real numbers and gives a real value
  • Utility for random variable x is better then for
    y if E(U(x)) gt E(U(y))
  • U(x) is an increasing continuous function, that
    is
  • if x gt y then U(x) gt U(y)

3
  • Types of Utilities functions
  • Exponential
  • U(x) - e-ax, where a gt 0
  • Logarithmic
  • U(x) ln(x), where x gt 0
  • Power
  • U(x) bxb, where b lt 1, b ? 0 (if b 1, then
    the

  • riskneutral utility)
  • Quadratic
  • U(x) x bx2, where some b gt 0

4
(No Transcript)
5
  • Example (The Venture Capitalist)
  • Two investment alternatives
  • (1) Buy T-bill which will give 6M for sure.
  • (2) An alternative with random outcomes 10M,
    5M, and 1M with corresponding probabilities of
    .2, .4, and .4 .
  • Utility U(x)x1/2 . Expected utilities
  • (1) v6 2.45
  • (2) .2 x v 10 .4 x v 5 .4 x v 1
  • .2 x 3.16 .4 x 2.24 .4 1.93
  • 2.45 gt 1.93 gt The first alternative is
    preferred.

6
  • Equivalent Utility Functions
  • Utility functions are used to rank alternatives.
  • Equivalent utility functions give identical
    ranking.
  • Can be proved that
  • V(x) a U(x) b
    ()
  • is equivalent to U(x) if agt0.
  • Transformation () is the only transformation
    which preserves ranking of all random outcomes.

7
  • Risk Aversion
  • The main purpose of a utility function is to
    provide a systematic way to rank alternatives
    that captures the principle of risk aversion.
  • Concave utility and risk aversion.
  • A function U defined on am interval a,b of
    real numbers is said to be concave if for any a
    with
  • 0 lt a lt 1 and any x and y in a,b there holds
  • Ua x (1- a)y gt a U(x) (1 - a)U(y) .
  • Risk aversion, usually means strict concavity
    (gt).

8
  • A utility function U is said to be risk averse on
    a,b if it is concave on a,b. If U is concave
    everywhere, it is said to be (just) risk averse.
  • Average utility of outcomes is less the utility
    of average outcomes

9
  • Example
  • Suppose you face two options.
  • (1) Toss of a coin heads, you win 10 tails,
    you win nothing.
  • (2) amount M for certain.
  • Utility function for money is x - .04x2.
  • (1) EU(x) ½(10 - .04 102) ½ 0 3.
  • (2) M - .04M2
  • If M 5, for example, then the (2) utility value
    is 4, which is greater then value of the (1)
    utility value. This means that you would prefer
    to have 5 for sure rather then 50-50 chance of
    getting 10 or nothing.

10
  • Example (Contd)
  • We solve M - .04M2 3. This gives M 3.49.
    Therefore there are two indifferent choices
  • to get 3.49 for sure or 50-50 chance of getting
    10 or 0.

11
  • Derivatives
  • U(x) is increasing if U(x) gt 0.
  • U(x) is strictly concave if U(x) lt 0.
  • Example
  • U(x) -e- a x
  • U(x) a e- a x gt 0 gt U is increasing
  • U(x) - a 2e- a x lt 0 gt U is concave.

12
  • Risk Aversion Coefficients
  • The degree of risk aversion is defined by
  • Arrow-Pratt absolute risk aversion coefficient
  • a(x) - U(x) /U(x)
  • U (x) normalizes the coefficient a(x) is the
    same for all equivalent utility functions. a(x)
    shows how risk aversion changes with the wealth
    level.

13
  • Example 1
  • U(x) -e- a x ,
  • U(x) a e- a x ,
  • U(x) - a 2e- a x ,
  • a(x) a ,
  • aversion coefficient is constant for all x .
  • Example 2
  • U(x) ln x ,
  • a(x) 1/x ,
  • risk aversion decreases.

14
  • Certainty Equivalent
  • The certainty equivalent of a random wealth
    variable x is defined to be the amount of a
    certain (that is risk-free) wealth that has a
    utility level equal to the expected utility of x.
    The certainty equivalent C of a random wealth
    variable x is the value C satisfying
  • U(C) EU(x)
  • For concave utility function the certainty
    equivalent of a random outcome x is less or
    equal to the expected value, i.e., C lt Ex .

15
EU(x)
16
  • Picture illustrates the certainty equivalent for
    two outcomes x1 and x2 is. The certainty
    equivalent is found by moving horizontal
    leftwards from the point where the line between
    U(x1) and U(x2) intersects the vertical line
    drawn at E(x).
  • Example The certainty equivalent of the 50-50
    chance of winning 10 or 0 is 3.49 because that
    is the value that, if obtained with certainty,
    would have the same utility as reward based on
    the outcome of the coin toss.

17
Specification of Utility Functions
  • There are systematic approaches for assigning an
    appropriate utility function to an investor.
    Several approaches will be outlined.
  • One way to measure an individuals utility
    function is to ask the individual to assign
    certainty equivalents to various risky
    alternatives.

18
  • Direct Measurement of Utility
  • Let A and B are selected as wealth reference
    points.It is proposed that lottery has outcome A
    with probability p and outcome B with probability
    1-p. For various values of p the investor is
    asked how much certain wealth C he/she would
    accept in in place of the lottery. C will vary as
    p changes.
  • A lottery with probability p has an expected
    value of e pA (1 p)B. However, a risk
    averse investor would accept less than this
    amount to avoid the risk of the lottery gt C lt e
    .

19
(No Transcript)
20
  • The values of C reported by investor for various
    ps are plotted. The value of C is placed under
    the corresponding e. A curve is function C(e).
  • To define a utility function from this diagram,
    we normalize by setting U(A) A and U(B) B.
    The expected utility is
  • pU(A) (1 p)U(B) pA (1 p)B,
  • which is the same as the expected value e.
    Since C is defined so that U(C) is expected
    utility of the lottery gt U(C) e. Therefore C
    U-1(e) gt curve define by C(e) is inverse of the
    utility function.

21
  • Example
  • Sybil, a moderately successful venture
    capitalist, is anxious to make her utility
    function explicit. A consultant ask her to
    consider lotteries with outcomes of either 1M or
    9M. She is asked to follow the direct procedure
    as the probability of p of receiving of 1M
    varies. For a 50-50 chance of the two outcomes,
    the expected value is 5M, but she assigns a
    certainty equivalent of 4M. Other values she
    assigns are shown in the table on the next slide.

22
Table 9.1. Expected Utility Values and Certainty
Equivalents
Here is shown the utility function (U(C) e).
For example U(4) 5. However, the values of C in
the table are not the whole numbers and a new
table of utility values could be constructed by
interpolation in the table. For example U(2)
3.4(2.00 1.96) 2.6(2.56 2.00) / (2.56
1.96) 2.65
23
  • Parameter Families
  • Another method of assigning a utility function is
    to select a parameterized family of functions and
    then determine a suitable set of parameter
    values.
  • Many people prefer to use a logarithmic or power
    utility function, since these functions have the
    property that risk aversion decreases with
    wealth. For the logarithmic utility, the risk
    aversion coefficient is a(x) 1/x, and for the
    power utility function U(x) ?x? the coefficient
    is
  • a(x) (1 - ?)/x. We will see further that these
    are appropriate utility functions for investors
    concerned with long-term grows in their wealth.

24
  • Example
  • Suppose that an investor has the exponential
    utility functions
  • U(x) - e-xa
    .
  • Let us ask how much he/she would accept in
    place of a lottery that offers a 50-50 chance of
    winning 1M or 100,000. Suppose the investor
    felt that this was equivalent to a certain wealth
    of 400,000. We then set
  • -e-400,000a - .5e-1,000,000a - .5e-100,000a
  • where a 1/623,426.

25
  • Example
  • The Table 9.1 results can be expressed compactly
    by fitting a curve to the results. Assume
  • U(x) ax? c.
  • From normalization
  • ac 1
  • a9? c 9

26
  • Example (Contd)
  • Consequently,
  • a 8/9? -1
  • c (9? - 9)/ (9? - 1)
  • Using Excel optimizer we can find the best value
    ?
  • matching U(C) to e.
  • The best value equals ? ½ . gt U(x) 4vx
    3

27
  • Questionnaire Method
  • Sometimes, the best way to deduce the
    appropriate risk factor and utility function is
    to administer a questionnaire. This must include
    questions related to the investors situation,
    investors investment approach, characteristics
    of the market, and the value of a managed fund.
  • The risk tolerance is defined by the internal
    feeling toward risk and by investors financial
    environment.

28
(No Transcript)
29
Utility and Mean Variance Approach
  • Mean-variance criterion used by Markowitz can be
    reconciled with expected utility approach by two
    ways
  • (1) using a quadratic utility functions,
  • (2) making the assumption that returns are
    normally distributed

30
  • Quadratic Utility
  • Suppose that a portfolio has a random wealth y .
  • Using quadratic utility function we get
  • EU(y) E(ay - (1/2)by2) aE(y) - (1/2)b E(
    y2)
  • aE(y) - (1/2)b E( y)2 - (1/2)b
    var(y),
  • Recall that var(y) E( y2) - E( y)2 .

31
  • Quadratic Utility (Contd)
  • Let us consider the problem
  • maxx E U (y(x))
  • Suppose that at the optimal point x , Ey(x )
    R .
  • We can reformulate
  • maxx E U (y(x))
  • maxx aE(y(x)) - (1/2)b E(y(x))2 - (1/2)b
    var(y(x))
  • maxx aR - (1/2)b R2 - (1/2)b var(y(x))

32
  • Quadratic Utility (Contd)
  • The last problem is equivalent to
  • minx var(y(x))
  • s.t. Ey(x) R
  • Different mean-variance efficient points are
    obtained by selecting different values for the
    parameters a and b .

33
  • Normal Returns
  • When all returns are normal random variables, the
    mean-variance criterion is also equivalent to the
    expected utility approach.
  • Since the probability distribution is completely
    defined by mean M and s
  • EU(y)f(M,s)
  • If U is risk averse, then f(M,s) will be
    increasing w.r.t. M and decreasing w.r.t. s .
  • The portfolio of normally distributed assets is
    also normally distributed.
  • The portfolio optimization problem is therefore
    equivalent to minimizing variance with fixed
    return.

34
Linear Pricing
  • Fundamental property of security pricing
    linearity.
  • Security is formalized as a random payoff
    variable.
  • Example. Security pays d10 if it rains
    tomorrow, and d-10 if it is sunny (weather
    derivatives electricity, agriculture).

35
  • Type A Arbitrage (give an example with strips)
  • If an investment produces an immediate positive
    reward with no future payoff (either positive or
    negative), that investment is said to be a TYPE A
    ARBITRAGE.
  • Linearity follows from the assumption that there
    is no possibility of a type A arbitrage.
  • Example. Suppose d is a security with price P.
    Consider the security 2d (pays always twice more
    than d). Suppose that its price Plt2P. Then we
    can buy the 2d security at a reduced price, brake
    in two parts and sell making profit 2P- P. No
    future obligations. Similar argument can be
    reverted that price of double security can not be
    more than 2P (can buy two d securities, combine
    and sell with profit).

36
  • Similar to the example, if d1 and d2 are
    securities with prices P1 and P2 , the price of
    the security d1d2 must be P1P2 . If the price
    of d1d2 were Plt P1P2 we can purchase the
    combined security with price P then brake it and
    sell with profit. As before this argument can be
    reverted.
  • In general Linear Pricing means
  • P(a 1d1 a 2d2) a 1 P(d1) a 2 P( d2)

37
  • Portfolios
  • Suppose that there are n securities d1,,dn .
    Portfolio is a vector ? (? 1,, ? n). Payoff of
    the portfolio is a random variable
  • d ? 1 d1 ? ndn ,
  • under assumption of no A arbitrage, the price of
    the portfolio ? must be
  • P(d) ? 1 P(d1) ? n P( dn) .

38
  • Type B Arbitrage
  • If an investment has nonpositive cost but has a
    positive probability yielding a positive payoff
    and no probability of yielding a negative payoff,
    that investment is a TYPE B ARBITRAGE.
  • Type B arbitrage pay nothing but have a chance
    to get something.
  • Example a free lottery ticket is a type B
    arbitrage.
  • Usually, it is assumed that there is no arbitrage
    (both A and B).

39
Portfolio Choice
  • This section combines results of the previous
    sections and consider a portfolio with the
    expected utility performance function.
  • Let x be a random variable. We write xgt0 if the
    variable is never less than 0 and it is strictly
    positive with some positive probability.
  • Suppose that U is a strictly increasing utility
    function and initial wealth W is available. There
    are n securities d1,,dn . The investor wishes to
    form a portfolio ? (? 1,, ? n) maximizing the
    expected utility .

40
  • Mathematical programming problem
  • max EU(x)
  • s.t. ?? idi x
  • xgt0
  • ? ? iPi W
  • Note summation ? is over n securities in the
    portfolio.

41
  • Portfolio choice theorem.
  • Suppose that U(x) is continuous and increases
    toward infinity as x tends to infinity. Suppose
    also that there is a portfolio ?0 such that
  • ? ?0i di gt 0.
  • Then, the optimal portfolio problem (on the
    previous transparence) has a solution if and only
    if there is no arbitrage possibility.

42
  • Proof. We prove only one direction statement.
  • (1) Suppose that there is a type A
    arbitrage. Using this portfolio it is possible to
    infinitely increase wealth W. This implies that
    EU(x) does not have a maximum.
  • (2) If there is type B arbitrage, it is possible
    to obtain (at zero or negative cost) an asset
    that has payoff xgt0 (with nonzero probability of
    being positive). We can acquire arbitrarily large
    amounts of this asset to increase EU(x)
    arbitrary.
  • Hence if there is a solution, there can be no
    type A or B arbitrage.

43
  • We can characterize the solution. Suppose that
    there is no arbitrage and hence there is an
    optimal portfolio ? . We also assume that the
    corresponding payoff x ? ?i di satisfies
    x gt0.
  • We can deduce that the constraint ? ?iPi W is
    active (equality at the solution) otherwise we
    can improve the performance function.
  • To derive the equation we substitute x ? ?i di
    in the objective and ignore constraint x gt0 . The
    problem becomes
  • max EU(? ?i di )
  • s.t. ? ?iPi W

44
  • Lagrange function for this problem is (see
    appendix B in the book)
  • EU(? ?i di ) - ?(? ?iPi - W )
  • Differentiation with respect to each ?i and
    equating to zero (at optimal point x ? ?i di
    ) gives
  • d( EU(? ?i di ) ) / d(?i) EU( x )
    di ?Pi
  • for i 1,,n.

45
  • We have n equations
  • EU(x) di ? Pi ()
  • and one more equation
  • ? ?iPi W .
  • Altogether there are n1 equations for n1
    variables ?1,, ?n and ? .
  • If there is a risk-free asset with the return R,
    then () must apply when di R and Pi 1 . Thus
  • ? EU(x) R ()

46
  • Substituting () into () gives
  • EU(x) di / (R EU(x) ) Pi
  • Summary Portfolio pricing equation.
  • If x ? ?i di is the solution of the
    optimal portfolio problem on page 7, then
  • EU(x) di ? Pi
  • for i 1,2,,n where ? gt0 . If there is a
    risk-free asset with the return R, then
  • EU(x) di / (R EU(x) ) Pi
  • for i 1,2,,n.

47
  • Example 9.5 (A film venture)
  • Three possible incomes and possibility to make
    20 risk free. Investor want to know how much to
    invest . Initial prices of both instruments 1.
  • The expected return is
  • 0.330.410.30 1.3 gt 1.2

48
  • Example 9.5 (Contd)
  • Utility U(x) ln (x) . Let (?1, ?2) be weights
    of risky and risk free instruments. The
    optimization problem
  • max EU(x) .3 ln(3?11.2 ?2) .4 ln(?11.2 ?2)
  • .3 ln(1.2 ?2)
  • s.t. ?1 ?2 W

49
  • The portfolio pricing equation EU(x) di ?
    Pi gives
  • .9/(3?11.2 ?2) .4/(?11.2 ?2) ?
  • .36 /(3?11.2 ?2) .48/(?11.2 ?2) .36 ln(1.2
    ?2) ?
  • By solving these equations together with
  • ?1 ?2 W
  • we obtain ?10.089W , ?20.911W , and ? 1/ W .

50
Finite State Models
  • Finite number of possible states (outcomes)
    1,2,,S
  • Example. Two states it rains tomorrow, or it is
    sunny.
  • Initial point States

51
  • States define uncertainty in a vary basic manner.
  • Security is a vector of the form dd1,,dS ,
  • where di is a payoff at state i .
  • P is security price .
  • Example. Security pays d110 if it rains
    tomorrow, and d1-10 if it is sunny. This
    security is represented by the vector d10,-10
    .

52
  • State Prices
  • S elementary state securities es0,,0,1,0,,0).
    Payoff is obtained in only one state.
  • ?s denotes the price of elementary security es .
  • The security dd1,,dS can be expressed as a
    combination of elementary state securities
  • d ? ds es
  • By linearity of pricing price P of d equals
  • P ? ds ?s

53
  • Positive State Prices
  • If a complete set of elementary securities exists
    or can be constructed as a combination of
    existing securities, it is important that their
    prices be positive. Otherwise there would be an
    arbitrage opportunity.
  • The condition of no arbitrage is equivalent to
    the existence of positive state prices.
  • Positive State Prices Theorem.
  • A set of positive state prices exists if and
    only if there are no arbitrage opportunities.

54
  • Proof of Positive State Prices Theorem
  • 1. (Positive prices gt no arbitrage)
  • Suppose the there are positive state prices and
    that the security with d0 can be constructed
  • (ds 0 for s1,2,,S).
  • Since P ? ds ?s , ?s gt0, and ds 0 for
    s1,2,,S, we have P 0 . Also, Pgt0 if at least
    one ds gt0, i.e., there is no B type arbitrage.

55
  • Proof of Positive State Prices Theorem (Contd)
  • 2. (No arbitrage gt positive prices)
  • Assume that there is no arbitrage.
  • Assume that there is a portfolio ?0 (?01 ,,
    ?0s ) such that ? ?0s ds gt 0 .
  • Assign state probabilities ps 0 for s1,2,,S
  • such that ? ps 1 .
  • Select a strictly increasing utility function
    U(x) .
  • Since there is no arbitrage there is an optimal
    portfolio (see section 9.8). Assume that optimal
    portfolio payoff x gt 0.

56
  • Proof of Positive State Prices Theorem (Contd)
  • Portfolio pricing equation (Pportfolio price,
    ?Lagrange multiplier)
  • EU(x) d ? P gt
  • P 1/ ? ? ps U(x)s ds
  • where U(x)s is value of U(x) in state s.
  • Define ?s (ps U(x)s ) / ? .
  • Consequently, ?s gt0, because, psgt0, U(x)s
    gt0, and ? gt0 .

57
  • Example 9.8 (Film venture)
  • Three possible incomes and possibility to make
    20 risk free. Investor want to know how much to
    invest. Initial prices of both instruments 1.
  • Optimal values are found in Example 9.5
    ?10.089W , ?20.911W , and ?1/ W . Assuming W1
    we have ?10.089, ?20.911 , and ?1 .

58
  • Example 9.8 (Contd)
  • By construction ?s (ps U(x)s ) / ?
  • Utility in state 1 ln(3?11.2 ?2)
  • Utility in state 2 ln(?11.2 ?2)
  • Utility in state 3 ln(1.2 ?2)
  • ?1 .3/(3?11.2 ?2) .221
  • ?2 .4 /(?11.2 ?2) .338
  • ?3 .3 /(3?11.2 ?2) .338

59
  • Example 9.69.9 (Residual Rights)
  • Comparing to the previous example, there is one
    more instrument residual rights, which gives
    return 60 if the film is successful.
  • Utility U(x) ln (x) .
  • Initial prices of all instruments 1 .
  • Expected utility
  • EU(x) .3 ln(3?11.2 ?26 ?3) .4 ln(?11.2
    ?2)
  • .3 ln(1.2 ?2)

60
  • Example 9.69.9 (Contd)
  • Portfolio pricing equation EU(x) d ? P
  • .9/(3?11.2 ?2 6 ?3) .4/(?11.2 ?2) ?
  • .36 /(3?11.2 ?2 6 ?3).48/(?11.2 ?2)
    .36ln(1.2 ?2) ?
  • 1.8/(3?11.2 ?26 ?3) ?
  • ?1 ?2 ?3 W
  • Solution ?1-1.0W , ?21.5W , ?30.5W, and
  • ?1/ W . When W1, ?1-1, ?21.5, ?30.5, and
  • ?1.

61
  • Example 9.69.9 (Contd)
  • Instrument 1 (film venture) d1 3,1,0
  • Instrument 2 (risk free) d2 1.2, 1.2, 1.2
  • Instrument 3 (residual rights) d3 6, 0, 0
  • Linearity of pricing Pi ? dsi ?s
  • 3 ?1 ?2 1
  • 1.2 ?1 1.2 ?2 1.2 ?3 1
  • 6?1
    1
  • This system has the solution
  • ?1 1/6, ?2 1/2, ?3 1/6.
  • Therefore
  • P 1/6d1 1/2d2 1/6d3
  • E.g., the price of basic venture P 3/6 1/2
    1.

62
Risk-Neutral Pricing
  • Suppose the there are positive state prices ?s gt0
  • for s1,2,,S. Then the price of security
    dd1,,dS equals
  • P ? ds ?s
  • Normalize state prices so their sum equals 1.
  • Let ?0 ? ?s and q s ?s / ?0 .
  • Pricing formula
  • P ? ds ?s ?0 ? ds ?s / ?0 ?0 ? qsds

63
  • Quantities qs , s1,2,,S can be thought as
    (artificial) probabilities since they are
    positive and sum to 1.
  • Pricing equation
  • P ?0 ? qsds ?0 E (ds)
  • where E? is an expectation with respect to
    artificial probabilities.
  • The value ?0 has a useful interpretation.
    Since ?0 ? ?s , ?0 is the price of security
    1,,1 that pays 1 in every state a risk free
    bond. By definition its price is 1/R, where R is
    a risk free return.

64
  • Thus we can write a pricing formula which we term
    neutral pricing (price is linear with respect to
    probabilities)
  • P ?0 E (ds) (1/R) E (ds)
  • qs , s1,2,,S are called risk neutral
    probabilities

65
  • Three ways to calculate neutral probabilities.
  • Can be found by multiplying prices by risk free
    rate
  • q s ?s / ?0 ?s / (1/R) ?s R
  • If the positive state prices were found from a
    portfolio problem
  • ?s (ps U(x)s ) / ?
  • ?0 ? ?s ? (ps U(x)s ) / ?
  • qs ps U(x)s / ? (ps U(x)s )
  • If there are n states, and n securities, then the
    risk-neutral probabilities can be found by
    solving system of equations
  • Pi(1/R) ? qs dsi
  • The expected return is
  • 0.330.410.30 1.3 gt 1.2

66
  • Example 9.10 (Film venture)
  • We found
  • ?1 1/6, ?2 1/2, ?3 1/6
  • Multiplying by risk free rate 1.2 we get
  • q1 0.2, q2 0.6, q3 0.2
  • Hence the price of a security with payoff
  • d1, d2, d3 is
  • P 0.2 d1 0.6 d2 0.2 d3 /1.2
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com