Political Incentives to Suppress Negative Financial Information: Evidence from China - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 34
About This Presentation
Title:

Political Incentives to Suppress Negative Financial Information: Evidence from China

Description:

The 'common consensus' is that Chinese firms suffer from poor corporate ... a China that is more capitalist than ever, the instinctive official response to ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:132
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 35
Provided by: bafCu
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Political Incentives to Suppress Negative Financial Information: Evidence from China


1
Political Incentives to Suppress Negative
Financial Information Evidence from China
  • Joseph D. Piotroski
  • T.J. Wong
  • Tianyu Zhang
  • Conference on Contemporary Issues of Firms and
    Institutions

2
Financial Transparency in China
  • The common consensus is that Chinese firms
    suffer from poor corporate governance and weak
    corporate transparency.
  • For example, China ranked 2nd in terms of
    corporate opacity among a set of 40 developing
    economies (Gelos and Wei, 2005).
  • In terms of market-based measures of the
    information environment
  • China ranked 2nd in terms of stock price
    synchronicity (Morck, Yeung and Yu, 2000)
  • Heightened degree of negative skewness in
    returns, consistent with the suppression of
    negative financial information / downside trading
    frictions.
  • In terms of financial reporting practices
  • Low levels of timely loss recognition (Ball,
    Robin and Wu, 2001).
  • Prevalence of propping activity among
    state-controlled firms (Jian and Wong, 2006)

3
Impact of Primitive Institutions on Financial
Reporting Practices
  • Prior research shows that legal, political,
    financial, regulatory and cultural institutions
    exert strong pressures on economic behavior and
    outcomes.
  • Institutions associated with strong investor
    protections are associated with more favorable
    financial reporting practices
  • Less earnings management (Leuz, Nanda and
    Wysocki, 2003)
  • Greater corporate transparency (Bushman,
    Piotroski and Smith, 2004)
  • Stronger timely loss recognition practices (Ball,
    Kothari and Robin, 2000)
  • Greater earnings informativeness (Fan and Wong,
    2002 DeFond Hung and Trezevant, 2004)
  • Greater use of high quality auditor (Francis,
    Khurana and Pereira, 2003)
  • Cross-country variation in financial reporting
    are driven by market demands and
    contracting-related forces.
  • However, other institutions in the economy can
    produce adverse incentives.
  • One such potential institutional is the States
    control of economic assets.

4
Adverse Incentives Created by State Ownership of
Firms
  • Economic policies of the State frequently reflect
    the desire of politicians to consolidate power
    and accumulate wealth (e.g., Lindbeck (1976)
    North (1990) Olson (1993))
  • State controlled firms are not oriented towards
    maximizing firm value.
  • Politicians use their control to achieve
    political objectives or to maximize their private
    benefits (e.g., Shleifer and Vishny, 1993
    LaPorta et al., 2002 Rajan and Zingales, 2003).
  • These objectives produce weak corporate
    governance practices and enormous inefficiencies
    among state firms (Shleifer and Vishny, 1997
    OECD, 2005 Wurgler, 2000).
  • Poor performance vs. non-state-owned firms
    Inefficient investment behavior and asset
    management.
  • Moreover, serious conflicts can arise between the
    State (as the controlling shareholder) and
    minority shareholders.
  • Research Question Do political forces create
    adverse financial reporting incentives among
    publicly-traded state-controlled firms? And do
    these forces dominate traditional market demand
    and contracting-related incentives in certain
    settings?

5
Prior research Political Costs and Financial
Reporting Practices
  • Political forces are expected to shape the
    financial reporting incentives of
    non-state-controlled firms
  • Watts and Zimmerman (1986) Accounting choices
    are influenced by the expected political costs of
    a given financial reporting outcome.
  • Political costs include
  • Heightened tax burdens (e.g., windfall profits
    tax).
  • Greater regulation.
  • Threat of greater government intervention into
    firms business activities.
  • Outright expropriation of productive assets.
  • And a host of other direct and indirect costs.
  • Prior cross-country research documents that
    political forces shape financial reporting
    practices among non-state-controlled firms.
  • Bushman, Piotroski and Smith (2004) Bushman and
    Piotroski (2006) Leuz and Oberholzer (2007)
  • Basic conclusions As the likelihood of
    government intervention increases, firms have an
    incentive to reduce transparency and to tilt
    reported valuations to minimize these costs.

6
Prior research Political Costs and Financial
Reporting Practices
  • Minimal evidence on how political forces shape
    the financial reporting incentives and practices
    of state-controlled firms.
  • Wang, Wong and Xia, 2006 Gul, 2006 Guedhami and
    Pittman, 2007 Examine the impact of political
    economy forces on audit choice and audit
    practices among newly privatized firms.
  • Jain and Wong (2006) document the use of related
    party transactions that are designed to allow the
    listed firm to meet specific bright line
    profitability targets in the context of China.
  • In this paper, we examine the impact that
    political incentives have on the financial
    reporting practices of state-controlled entities.
  • Focus on one particular dimension The incentive
    to release or suppress negative financial
    information in a timely manner.
  • Focus on one reporting environment The Peoples
    Republic of China

7
Motivation Why China?
  • Vast majority of Chinese listed firms are
    state-controlled enterprises.
  • Political forces matter in China considerable
    variation across regions.
  • Differences in economic policy and performance
    (Value max. versus Full Employment).
  • Differences in ownership structure (Decentralized
    pyramids versus direct control).
  • Differences in the type of shares issuances (A
    shares H shares Overseas listings).
  • Differences in the level of investor protections,
    regulation and market development.
  • Differences in level of domestic / foreign
    investor interest.
  • Economic Significance China is the worlds
    largest developing economy
  • 4th largest GDP Growth in GDP expected to be
    10.5 in 2007.
  • 60 Billion (US) in actual foreign investment in
    2006 Commitments 3x.
  • Recent adoption of IFRS.

8
Incentives to Release Negative Financial
Information in China
  • From the traditional market demand and
    contracting perspective, greater transparency
    will benefit the firm and the State.
  • Limit the consumption of private benefits by
    controlling shareholders.
  • Increase the ability of both the State and
    foreign investors to monitor local politicians
    and managers
  • Reduce information gathering costs
  • Improve the efficiency of capital allocation and
    asset management decisions.
  • Lead to greater levels of foreign direct
    investment (e.g., Gelos and Wei, 2005)
  • Lower the firms / countrys cost of capital and
    enhance market development.
  • Foreign investors have a demand for greater
    transparency.
  • Impact of decentralization through pyramidal
    ownership arrangements.
  • Information asymmetry between owners and managers
    creates demand for information about bad outcomes
    (for monitoring purposes).

9
Incentives to Suppress Negative Financial
Information in China
  • Managers and local politicians incur a personal
    cost by reporting poor performance.
  • Performance influences political promotions and
    demotions (Chen, Li and Zhou, 2005 Li and Zhou,
    2005).
  • Bad news could have material impact on foreign
    investment activity and perceptions.
  • Negative news translates into a loss of face
    for local politicians and the State.
  • Negative news undermines investor confidence,
    leading to a torpedo effect.
  • In both cases, the cost of reporting poor
    performance is expected to be greater in regions
    with strong expected performance, value max.
    orientation and strong foreign interest than in
    neglected or underperforming regions.
  • Suppression of bad news allows politicians and
    politically astute managers to
  • Hide inefficiencies in project selection and
    asset management.
  • Hide expropriation-related activities from
    minority shareholders.
  • Mask the inefficient allocation of resources to
    achieve political objectives.
  • Hide the diversion of resources as a result of
    political cronyism and corruption.
  • The value of retaining control is expected to be
    larger in wealthy provinces and provinces with
    greatest foreign investment.

10
Empirical Proxies for Financial Reporting
Incentives
  • Strength of provincial-level legal and
    market-development institutions.
  • Marketization index (Fan and Wang, 2001).
  • Legal environment Index (Fan and Wang, 2001).
  • Property rights protection index (Fan and Wang,
    2001).
  • Deregulation index (Demerger et al, 2002).
  • Provincial conditions and government policy
    incentives
  • Unemployment rate in the region.
  • Average return on equity for state-owned firms in
    the region.
  • Average percentage of non-operating assets.
  • RD spending as a percentage of fiscal
    expenditures.

11
Empirical Proxies for Financial Reporting
Incentives
  • Strength of provincial-level legal and
    market-development institutions.
  • Marketization index (Fan and Wang, 2001).
  • Legal environment Index (Fan and Wang, 2001).
  • Property rights protection index (Fan and Wang,
    2001).
  • Deregulation index (Demerger et al, 2002).
  • Provincial conditions and government policy
    incentives
  • Unemployment rate in the region.
  • Average return on equity for state-owned firms in
    the region.
  • Average percentage of non-operating assets.
  • RD spending as a percentage of fiscal
    expenditures.

Market Demand and Contracting arguments Transpar
ency will be greater in strong regions
12
Empirical Proxies for Financial Reporting
Incentives
  • Strength of provincial-level legal and
    market-development institutions.
  • Marketization index (Fan and Wang, 2001).
  • Legal environment Index (Fan and Wang, 2001).
  • Property rights protection index (Fan and Wang,
    2001).
  • Deregulation index (Demerger et al, 2002).
  • Provincial conditions and government policy
    incentives
  • Unemployment rate in the region.
  • Average return on equity for state-owned firms in
    the region.
  • Average percentage of non-operating assets.
  • RD spending as a percentage of fiscal
    expenditures.

Market Demand and Contracting Arguments Transpar
ency will be greater in strong regions
Political Incentive Arguments Suppression will
be greater in strong regions
13
Anecdotal Evidence Suppression of Bad News in
China
  • Environmental / Health Issues
  • Notable Examples SARS virus (2003) and Bird Flu
    Virus (2005)
  • Even in a China that is more capitalist than
    ever, the instinctive official response to bad
    news is to suppress it with all the force
    available to the nominally communist state.
    Financial Times (July 2007)
  • Economic and Business Activities
  • Unfavorable news information that could put
    local leaders in a bad light in Beijing is
    routinely suppressed by multiple layers of party
    propaganda officials in towns, counties, cities
    and provinces. The Seattle Times (August 2007)
  • Chinese officials often suppress bad news
    because they fear upsetting the public or their
    bosses or to prevent economic losses. Cox
    International (August 2007)
  • The suppression of bad news remains an
    unedifying habit that dies hard on the Mainland.
    South China Morning Post (June, 2007)

14
Anecdotal Evidence Suppression of Bad News in
China
  • Measurement of Economic performance
  • The Chinese government had systematically
    falsified its gross domestic product data to hide
    an economic downturn that took place in 1998 and
    1999. Thomas Rawski (2001)
  • Many have reluctantly, and to varying degrees,
    come around to his view. Earlier this year, for
    example, Goldman Sachs endorsed Rawskis take
    that the Chinese economy was caught in a
    downdraft in the late 1990s.
  • The governments handling of the SARS epidemic
    earlier this year has also strengthened Rawskis
    case. Now everyone knows the Chinese government
    suppressed health statisticsThe only question
    now is whether the governments suppression of
    bad news spreads into the economics area as
    well. Forbes (November 2003)
  • Question Do these tendencies spill over into the
    financial reporting realm?

15
Empirical Proxies for Suppression of Negative
Financial Information Stock price crash metrics
  • We interpret the presence of large, negative
    stock prices crashes as a proxy for the delayed
    flow of negative information into prices.
  • Following Jin and Myers (2006) and Chen, Hong and
    Stein (2001).
  • The release of current and previously suppressed
    negative information at one time will lead to
    larger negative returns and greater negative
    skewness.
  • As opposed to the alternative return distribution
    where negative news is released in a timely
    sequential manner.
  • Utilized two crash statistics
  • NCSKEW Third moment of each stocks daily
    residual return, scaled by the cubed
  • standard deviation of residual
    returns, times negative one.
  • DUVOL Ratio of the log standard deviation of
    returns on down days to the log of the
  • standard deviation of returns on up
    days.
  • Greater skewness, ceteris paribus, is indicative
    of a greater likelihood that earlier negative
    news was withheld.

16
Empirical Proxies for Suppression of Negative
Financial Information Stock price crash metrics
  • Prior research supports this interpretation of
    negative skewness as a measure of information
    suppression (or constrained flow of information)
    about bad outcomes.
  • Jin and Myers (2006) show that cross-country
    crash measures are significantly related to
    measures of firm disclosure, corporate opacity
    and stock return synchronicity.
  • Bris, Goetzmann and Zhu (2007) show that downside
    volatility is significantly larger when
    short-selling is constrained, consistent with a
    build up (i.e., artificial suppression) of
    non-priced negative financial information in
    those settings with downside trading frictions.
  • Hutton, Marcus and Tehranian (2007) and Kothari,
    Shu and Wysocki (2007) provide U.S. evidence
    supporting this interpretation of these crash
    statistics.

17
Research Design Stock price crash metrics
  • Our primary research design will test for an
    association between these crash statistics and
    institutional variables designed to proxy for
    political incentives to suppress negative
    financial information.
  • Estimate pooled cross-sectional model
  • NSCKEWi,t or DUVOLi,t ? ?1INSTITUIONSi,t
    ?2LOGSIZEi,t ?3GROWTHi,t ?4SIGMAi,t
  • ?5TURNOVERi,t ?6TURNOVERi,t-1 ?7BETAi,t
    ?8RETi,t ?9RETi,t-1 ?i,t
  • Control variables drawn from Chen, Hong and Stein
    (2001).

18
Table 1 Composition of the Sample
19
Table 2 Descriptive Statistics
20
Table 3 Correlation MatrixPanel A Firm
characteristics and regional institutions
21
Table 3 Correlation MatrixPanel B Correlation
among regional institutions
22
Table 4 Influence of provincial institutions on
the incentives to suppress negative financial
information
23
Table 5 Influence of regional economic policies
and performance on the incentives to suppress
negative financial information
24
Table 6 Influence of provincial-level foreign
investment on the incentive to suppress negative
financial information
25
Table 7 Influence of industry-level foreign
investment on the incentive to suppress negative
financial information
26
Alternative Research Design Timely Loss
Recognition Practices
  • The preceding results hinge upon our
    interpretation of crash statistics as proxies for
    the extent to which adverse financial news is
    suppressed.
  • Examine variation in a financial accounting
    practice related to the timely incorporation of
    negative financial information into earnings
    Timely loss recognition.
  • Following Basu (1997), prior cross-country
    studies (e.g., Ball, Kothari and Robin, 2000)
    measure timely loss recognition practices using
    variations of the following model
  • NIi,j,t a0 a1NEGi,j,t ß1RETi,j,t
    ß2NEGi,j,tRETi,j,t ei,j,t,
  • where NEG1 if RET lt 0.
  • Ball, Robin and Wu (2001) shows that TLR, on
    average, is low in China.
  • We search for variation in TLR practices within
    China conditional on the underlying regional
    incentives

Incremental Bad News Sensitivity
27
Table 8 Timely loss recognition practices of
state-controlled firmsPanel A Provincial
institutions
28
Table 8 Timely loss recognition practices of
state-controlled firmsPanel B Foreign
investment activity
29
Influence of decentralization on the reporting
incentives of state-controlled firms
  • Pyramidal ownership structure in China is one
    mechanism by which the State credibly delegates
    decision rights to managers.
  • Fan, Wong and Zhang (2007) - Pyramids improves
    labor and investment efficiency and total factor
    productivity.
  • In our sample, nearly 85 of these publicly firms
    are controlled by the state through a multi-layer
    pyramid.
  • To the extent that decentralization reduces the
    likelihood of government reprisal for poor
    performance, we would expect the incentive to
    suppress to be weaker among firms controlled
    through a pyramidal arrangement.
  • Preliminary Analysis In terms of reporting
    incentives
  • We find no evidence that decentralization impacts
    the suppression or release of negative financial
    information using our crash statistics.
  • We do find evidence that the pyramid structure
    increases the incentives for TLR.

30
Summary of Results and Conclusions
  • We find that the suppression of negative
    financial information, as proxied by both stock
    return crashes and weaker timely loss recognition
    practices, is stronger in those regions
    characterized by
  • Strong investor protections and pro-market
    regulation.
  • Strong economic performance / value maximization
    policy orientation.
  • High levels of foreign investment and ownership.
  • These patterns are consistent with managers and
    local politicians responding to political
    incentives when releasing information about
    state-controlled firms.
  • Thus, in those settings where market demand and
    contracting arguments would suggest transparency
    should be greatest, these alternative incentives
    appear to dominate.
  • Understanding the various financial reporting
    incentives of politicians and politically-astute
    managers is a first-order concern for investors
    in China

31
(No Transcript)
32
(No Transcript)
33
Comparison of Chinese TLR practices versus
Developed Countries
34
Comparison of Chinese TLR practices versus Other
Asian and Emerging-Market Countries
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com