Tax Evasion and the Firm - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

Tax Evasion and the Firm

Description:

Nature of concealment costs. Structure of audit probabilities ... 'MC concealment equals reduction in expected tax' Optimal output satisfies. p = m g te ' ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:93
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 48
Provided by: frank246
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Tax Evasion and the Firm


1
Tax Evasion and the Firm
  • Frank Cowell
  • Encuentros de Economía Pública
  • Almeria, February 2006

2
Purpose
  • This talk is about modelling in public economics
  • I want to focus on a puzzle
  • Then a suggestion for answering the puzzle
  • But first a history lesson
  • an English history lesson

3
William the Conqueror
  • 1066 a date known to British schoolchildren
  • But 1086 should be better known to tax
    researchers
  • The Domesday Book
  • a detailed audit of the kingdom
  • what is the place that I have conquered worth?
  • who owns what?
  • where are the resources?
  • A thorough operation
  • extensive teams of investigators
  • multiple information sources
  • penalties for wrong information

4
Lessons from the Conqueror
  • Not just a system of national accounts
  • Clearly concerned with revenue raising
  • Note questions on valuation
  • An early example of a tax audit problem
  • But questions are about assets rather than income
  • A forerunner of the Allingham-Sandmo problem?

5
Tax Compliance Background
  • Typically focus on the personal taxpayer
  • exogenous income
  • isolated economic agent
  • Simplified information structure
  • Since Allingham and Sandmo lots of specifications
  • But broadly two categories
  • TAG models
  • Taxpayer As Gambler
  • Cat-and-mouse models
  • The main economic actors play games with each
    other

6
TAG
  • The individual taxpayer behaves just as a
    gambler
  • Taxpayer has fixed income
  • Conceals a part of this income
  • Knows the penalty and probability of audit
  • Audit probability is fixed
  • Taxpayer takes a risk on whether he is audited

7
Cat-and-mouse
  • Audit probability depends on report
  • Generates strategic interaction
  • Known distribution of income and types
  • Condition audit on report
  • Get a cut-off rule
  • Alternatively models use other forms of
    information
  • Reinganum and Wilde (1985,1986)

8
A modelling strategy
  • Is the analysis well suited to analysing taxpayer
    behaviour
  • when the taxpayers are producers?
  • when the taxpayers are grouped in an industry?
  • Lets see how well the models work
  • Do they capture the essential features of tax
    compliance with firms?
  • Start with TAG

9
TAG competitive firms
  • Assume expected profit maximisation
  • Only source of randomness is due to audit..
  • Behaviour driven by two things
  • Nature of concealment costs
  • Structure of audit probabilities
  • Tax evasion incurs resource costs
  • Firm declares proportion of output a.
  • Incurs total concealment cost C(1 a).
  • Average cost c(1 a) C(1 a) / 1 a.

10
TAG model structure
  • Can treat this as modified Allingham-Sandmo
  • Tax-enforcement parameters
  • Proportional tax rate t.
  • Probability of audit b.
  • Penalty rate for concealed output f.
  • Compute expected effective tax rate te
  • te 1 bat b t 1 a ft a 1
    a b 1ft
  • Expected profits are
  • p m c te q
  • p price
  • m marginal production cost

11
Competitive model results
  • Only c and te depend on concealment
  • increasing marginal cost of concealment
  • reduced effective expected tax rate
  • Firm always conceals if te lt t
  • Optimal concealment satisfies
  • 1 a g'(1 a) t te
  • MC concealment equals reduction in expected tax
  • Optimal output satisfies
  • p m g te
  • Price (adjusted) marginal cost
  • Essentially a separation result
  • Makes it easy to get comparative statics
  • But does it survive more generalised modelling?

12
Generalisations
  • Monopoly / imperfect competition
  • Determinate demand curve
  • Replace q with q(p)
  • Little changes replace "price" with "MR" in FOC
  • Separation result persists. (Marrelli 1984,
    Marelli and Martina 1988)
  • Risk aversion
  • max Eu(p m g t q)
  • Separation result is preserved
  • Change the tax/penalty regime.
  • b not only a function of over-reported cost?
  • b or penalty not constant?
  • No longer get the separation result Lee (1998)

13
TAG and firms a puzzle
  • The puzzle is that the firm seems to have
    disappeared
  • write out FOC
  • solve for output and profits
  • back into an Allingham-Sandmo world
  • Tax-neutrality argument is central
  • but it appears artificial
  • not robust to different tax base
  • seems to run counter to experience
  • zealous enforcement has no effect on output?
  • Perhaps the answer is in the audit rule?
  • Audit rule is naïve
  • Does not make full use of industry information
  • Consider cat-and-mouse

14
Cat-and-mouse firms
  • The cat-and-mouse model is a reporting game
  • tax-payer and tax authority (TA)
  • With or without precommitment
  • Is cat-and-mouse a suitable for firms?
  • Simple reporting models may be inappropriate
  • There is no fixed income to uncover
  • Dont have independent estimate of distribution
  • May omit some of the key strategic aspects of the
    game
  • Do we have the right players?
  • What do the players know?

15
William the Conqueror again
  • How does the modern tax-audit differ from the
    Domesday book?
  • production
  • nature of report
  • nature of reporting process
  • We need to address a key practical question
  • how would we expect the TA to act?
  • clearly depends on the type of tax
  • corporation tax? VAT?
  • Recognise the contrast with the situation of
    personal taxpayers
  • who knows what the taxable profit is?
  • how handle of heterogeneity of firms?
  • how handle inter-relations amongst firms?
  • Design an audit strategy that
  • uses the available information
  • recognises its own ignorance

16
Learning from the tax authority
  • What will the TA do?
  • sort firms by industry grouping
  • sort firms by size
  • monitor over time
  • adapt audit procedure accordingly
  • Can we adapt the standard approaches?
  • Neglect some important features and information
  • Production
  • Creation / disappearance of taxable units
  • Structure of industry
  • This provides an answer to our puzzle of the
    vanishing firm

17
Taking the firm seriously
  • What makes the firm special?
  • Internal organisation
  • Interrelation with other firms
  • The role of information
  • Internal organisation
  • Not a single decision-making entity
  • Role of Chief Financial Officer?
  • Effective separation of functions within the
    firm?
  • Interrelations
  • Several models that deal with this for example
    Benjamini-Maital
  • But why should firms care about each other?
  • Not stigma but profits
  • Information
  • needs closer examination

18
Information
  • What does the firm know about itself?
  • incomplete information may lead to agency
    problems
  • Crocker and Slemrod (2005)
  • What does the tax authority know about the firm?
  • What do firms know about each other?

19
A way forward
  • How to capture the essence of the tax-compliance
    problem with firms?
  • We will focus on two main features
  • 1. Industry-group typing
  • incorporates interrelations among taxpaying firms
  • arises naturally from informational structure of
    the problem
  • results in a well-behaved equilibrium in a
    minimalist model
  • 2. Production and industry
  • incorporates industrial organisation
    considerations
  • again uses naturally arising information
  • introduces an output-security tradeoff
  • modifies standard IO equilibria in an interesting
    way

20
Approach 1 Industry-group typing
  • Consider the cat-and-mouse model
  • simple versions use a cut-off rule Reinganum
    and Wilde (1985)
  • ignore income declarations greater than d
  • But this based on a particular strategic
    interaction
  • TA versus representative taxpayer
  • Can the model be made richer?
  • In some cases yes
  • see tax-payers as a group
  • allow natural group interaction (Sánchez 2006)
  • particularly important for firms
  • Role of the industry
  • classify according to broad observable
    characteristics
  • enough information to condition audit policy

21
Cut-off rule
  • Well-known to be wasteful
  • the cut-off rule wastes ammunition auditing
    genuine taxpayers
  • but what if firms in an industry are subject to
    common shocks
  • unobserved from the outside?
  • problem gets worse
  • Negative shock
  • more firms than expected by the TA have profits
    below the cut-off level
  • more firms declare low
  • Positive shock
  • more than expected by the TA have profits above
    the cut-off level d
  • but each successful firm will declare only d,
    thus increasing the number of evaders that go
    undetected.
  • Result more resources wasted
  • find systematic mis-targeting by the TA
  • under-auditing in good years
  • over-auditing in bad years

22
Policy with shocks
  • Can the TA do better than a cut-off rule?
  • Suppose TA is concerned about wasted
    ammunition
  • resources spent on audits of compliant taxpayers
  • TA better off if policy is contingent on the
    industry information
  • Use the industry typing
  • form fairly homogeneous audit class
  • let D be average declaration for the class
  • di be declaration for firm i within the class
  • condition on D ? di
  • Changes nature of the compliance game
  • the D component induces interaction among firms
    (Alm and McKee 2004)
  • improves TAs ability to estimate probability of
    firm i being an evader.
  • Firms who declare relatively low are more likely
    to be evaders
  • homogeneity within a given industry category
  • since firms share characteristics expect to have
    similar profits
  • consequently expect similar income declarations.
  • declaration significantly below the class average
    seen as suspect

23
How interaction works
  • Consequences for TA policy
  • knows relationship between D ? di and probability
    that i is an evader
  • so make auditing intensity for low declarers
    increase with D.
  • Introduces an externality among taxpayers
  • fundamental nature of the tax compliance problem
  • each firm has to interact strategically with
    other firms
  • not just with TA as in conventional cat-and-mouse
  • Firms forced to participate in a coordination
    game
  • if the average declaration is high (most firms
    comply)
  • probability of detection is also high too
  • if the average declaration is low (so most people
    evade)
  • the probability of detection is low
  • Each firm always has incentive to join the
    majority.

24
A paradox?
  • Auditing intensity increases with the average
    declaration?
  • A waste of resources?
  • most firms would have declared truthfully.
  • Will this policy harm the goal of discouraging
    evasion?
  • Low auditing intensity when D is low
  • means TA lets evaders get away undetected.?
  • But auditing intensity applies only to low di
  • those who declare high are never audited
  • the greater is D the greater is the TA's belief
    that the class faces a favourable shock
  • the greater is its belief that a low di means i
    is an evader.
  • So no paradox

25
The contingent rule
  • Contingent policy slightly resembles the cut-off
    rule
  • non-increasing in true income
  • But there is a big difference
  • probability of detection for those who declare
    low
  • an increasing function of the class-wide average
    declaration.
  • Why the contingent rule?
  • not a consequence of new elements added to the
    model
  • simply an application of common sense
  • making efficient use of all the available
    information.
  • Implications for TA
  • take advantage of strategic uncertainty it
    generates
  • manipulate this by imposing severe penalties in
    the case of a coordination failure

26
Fundamental uncertainty
  • But how do firms view the government?
  • A second element of uncertainty
  • the type of the government
  • value it puts on resources wasted on auditing
    compliant taxpayers
  • this information is private to the government
  • Firms do not know this type
  • faced with a the probability distribution
  • need to estimate it
  • results in a system of beliefs

27
The role of firms beliefs
  • Beliefs generate heterogeneity
  • expectations over type of the government differ
    among taxpayers
  • eliminates all but one equilibrium
  • the presence of different signals
  • leads to different taxpayers to make different
    decisions
  • Simplifies the model
  • each firm has a unique optimal strategy
  • unlike a coordination game without
    heterogeneity...
  • get multiple solutions (one for each possible
    equilibrium)
  • Sánchez (2006) model yields unique, interior
    equilibrium

28
The industry-typing model
  • Presence of two kinds of uncertainty
  • strategic generated by the coordination game
  • fundamental firms imperfect information about
    government type
  • makes the tax evasion problem well suited to be
    modelled as a global game.
  • Global game captures the interaction among its
    actors
  • firms in an industry a bit like subjects in the
    kingdom of William I
  • leaves open scope for manipulating beliefs
  • Capture stylized facts missing in other models
  • Unique interior equilibrium where some comply,
    some evade
  • TA's comprehensive and efficient use of all
    available information
  • But incomes (profits) are still exogenous
  • consider the second approach

29
Approach 2 production and industry
  • Explicitly model the industry
  • Make the multi-firm setting essential
  • Model differential information of insiders and
    outsiders
  • Bayer and Cowell (2005)
  • Make better use of information by the TA
  • On part of firms
  • On part of tax authority
  • Compare with
  • Naïve audit rules
  • Simple models of compliance

30
Model motivation
  • How much does the tax authority know about firms?
  • May be reasonably well informed about a specific
    industry or sector.
  • But firms probably have better information about
    their own industry
  • This information may concern both production and
    financial performance
  • Yields a natural way to model output and evasion
    linkage

31
Firms
  • Production
  • Identical cost structures
  • Details of these subsumed within profit function
  • Evasion
  • Opportunities to evade are common knowledge
  • Specify cost-of-evasion function C(?)
  • Argument is concealed output
  • Increasing, convex
  • C(0) 0
  • Objectives
  • Firms are risk-neutral
  • Objective function is expected profits

32
Industry
  • Fixed number of firms n.
  • Firms compete
  • Cournot style
  • Bertrand style
  • Firms make profit declarations
  • d (d1, d2, ..., dn )
  • New possibilities for tax authority
  • independent audits
  • use information from all declarations in audit
    rule

33
Taxation, audit and enforcement
  • Conventional tax/penalty regime
  • linear profits tax
  • simple fine structure for non-compliance
  • both could be generalised
  • But a variety of audit regime
  • Instead of considering a policy of independent
    audit
  • given a fixed audit probability ß for all firms
  • Consider the use of a relative audit rule
  • Audit probability for firm i is given as ß(i, d)
  • depends on firm i's declaration relative to the
    rest.
  • Again we could use the D ? di rule
  • Under the relative rule each firm knows that
  • ...own declaration may reduce the probability
  • ...others' declaration may increase the
    probability

34
Tax, profits and penalties
  • Firm is profits gross of tax and depend on q
  • output vector of industry
  • Profits form base of tax
  • assume linear tax function
  • The tax it actually pays depends on evasion
    decision
  • assume a fixed proportional fine f.
  • Risk-neutrality firm i maximises expected net
    profit

cost of concealment
probability of audit
gross profit if audited
gross profit if not audited
35
How the model works
  • Timing in the model is intuitive
  • The TA announces taxes and an audit regime
  • Firms choose quantities
  • Firms observe gross profits of the others
  • Firms choose profit declarations
  • TA audits and punishes where appropriate
  • The solution is found as usual
  • by working backwards
  • start with the declaration stage

36
Declaration decision
  • At this stage, outputs have been determined
  • profits are determined
  • and known within the industry
  • Declaration problem for each firm is simple
  • driven by the known audit rule
  • To get an interior solution need two conditions
  • 1 If marginal concealment costs are high for
    extensive tax evasion
  • then, near di 0, expected payoff increases
    with di
  • 2 If C'(0) 0 and detection probability is low
  • then, near full declaration, expected profits
    decrease with di.
  • Latter condition corresponds to usual TAG case.

37
Output decision
  • Changes in quantity are known to affect optimal
    declarations of others
  • there is the usual Cournot interdependence
  • and the audit rule is common knowledge
  • Changes in others' declarations affect i's audit
    probability
  • the audit rule is common knowledge
  • Decisions on output will reflect this
    interdependence
  • Condition for is optimal output reflects
  • the induced change in js declarations
  • the indirect impact on is probability of audit

38
Role of information
  • Announcement of audit regime is crucial
  • If tax authority uses relative rule
  • interdependence of firms declarations is common
    knowledge
  • Each firms declaration creates an externality
  • Tax authority can use this in selecting the type
    of audit rule
  • can influence the climate of the industry
  • Imagine starting with simple independent audits.
  • Would there be a dividend in refining and
    announcing the refinement?

39
A double dividend
  • Bayer and Cowell show that there are two
    dividends from refining the audit policy
  • First audit efficiency
  • Under the relative audit rule with mean
    equilibrium detection probability ß firms
    declare more profits than under independent
    audits with the fixed detection probability ß(i)
    ß.
  • Second production efficiency
  • A relative audit rule leads to outputs higher
    than in under the independent audit rule

40
Audit rules and output
  • Independent audit rule
  • fixed audit probability
  • output is independent of the evasion decision and
    equals the Cournot quantities.
  • rather like the simple competitive model
  • Relative audit rule
  • audit probability depends on D ? di
  • outputs are higher than in Cournot competition
    without taxes.

41
Changing the audit rule shifts the output
reaction function
42
Another paradox?
  • What is gained from increasing output beyond the
    Cournot level?
  • Surely a firm reduces its own profit
  • as well as its competitors profits?
  • A loss rather than a gain?
  • Informational externality
  • As qi increases, profits of other firms fall
  • Optimal declarations of the other firms fall
  • Given the relative audit rule
  • probability of audit of firm i decreases
  • This gives firm i more scope for evasion
  • So it is rational for the Cournot firm to operate
    in this way

43
The non-paradox again
  • A tradeoff
  • by increasing output beyond the Cournot quantity
  • a firm loses some gross profit
  • but gets a better environment for evasion.
  • A malicious incentive?
  • other firms decrease their declaration if their
    profits fall
  • but this decreases firm i's audit probability
  • firm i has an incentive to sabotage other firms'
    profits
  • by producing more than under the usual Cournot

44
Changing the industry rules
  • The result is not special to quantity competition
  • Similar results for Bertrand price-competition
    model
  • you need differentiated products
  • and a regularity condition on demand curves
  • The intuition is the same
  • forgo some gross profits
  • for a better evasion environment

45
Changing the audit rule shifts the price reaction
function
46
Conclusions
  • We can suggest an answer to our puzzle
  • can we find an approach to the topic
  • where the firm does not vanish?
  • two main components to the answer
  • Whos in the game?
  • firms versus the TA
  • firms versus firms
  • perhaps a little like William Is Domesday
    investigation
  • How is the tax-base determined?
  • profits created by firms
  • firms in the context of an industry
  • where TAs could learn something that king
    Williams investigators did not know

47
References
  • Allingham, M. and A. Sandmo (1972). Income tax
    evasion a theoretical analysis. Journal of
    Public Economics 1, 323-338.
  • Alm, J. and M. Mckee (2004). Tax compliance as a
    coordination game. Journal of Economic Behavior
    Organization 54, 297-312.
  • Bayer, R.-C. and F. A. Cowell (2005). Tax
    compliance and firms strategic interdependence.
    Distributional Analysis Discussion Paper 81,
    STICERD, London School of Economics, London WC2A
    2AE.
  • Crocker, K. J. and J. Slemrod (2005). Corporate
    tax evasion with agency costs. Journal of Public
    Economics 89, 1593.1610.
  • Lee, K. (1998). Tax evasion, monopoly and
    nonneutral profit taxes. National Tax Journal 51,
    333-338.
  • Marrelli, M. (1984). On indirect tax evasion.
    Journal of Public Economics 25, 181.196.
  • Marrelli, M. and R. Martina (1988). Tax evasion
    and strategic behaviour of firms. Journal of
    Public Economics 37, 55.69.
  • Reinganum, J. F. and L. L. Wilde (1985). Income
    tax compliance in a principal-agent framework.
    Journal of Public Economics 26, 1.18.
  • Reinganum, J. F. and L. L. Wilde (1986).
    Equilibrium verification and reporting policies
    in a model of tax compliance. International
    Economic Review 27, 739.760.
  • Sánchez, M. (2006). Divide and conquer Tax
    evasion as a global game. Distributional Analysis
    Discussion Paper 80, STICERD, London School of
    Economics, London WC2A 2AE.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com