THE INTERNAL POLICIES OF - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 65
About This Presentation
Title:

THE INTERNAL POLICIES OF

Description:

Differences in car prices across the EU are narrowing, in part thanks to the ... multi--brand car dealerships possible, enabled non-authorised dealers to sell ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:44
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 66
Provided by: kab99
Category:
Tags: internal | policies | the

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: THE INTERNAL POLICIES OF


1
  • THE INTERNAL POLICIES OF
  • THE EUROPEAN UNION
  • Competition policy of the EU
  • Prof. D-r Jovan Pejkovski

2
  • Effective competition is crucial to an open
    market economy.
  • It cuts prices, raises quality and expands
    customer choice.
  • Competition allows technological innovation to
    flourish.

3
  • The European Commission has wide powers to make
    sure businesses and governments stick to European
    Union rules on fair play in trade in goods and
    services, while allowing governments to step in
    if markets are failing consumers or business, or
    to promote innovation, unified standards, or
    small business development.

4
  • The main areas of competition policy are
  • antitrust and cartels
  • merger control
  • liberalisation
  • state aids.

5
Market Structures
  • firms operate in markets, these are structured
    differently
  • we can look at three different types of market
    structure and find examples of each
  • monopoly
  • duopoly
  • oligopoly

6
Monopoly
  • a market structure where there is a single seller
    of a unique product
  • no competition, as the firm the market
  • potential for abuse of monopoly position
  • the market may be a natural monopoly
  • having competition amongst firms in this kind of
    market would be costly

7
Example of Monopoly
  • there may be significant savings to be had from
    having one company running the market
  • Network Rail are responsible for the maintenance
    and upgrading of the rail network
  • is it safer to have one company in charge?

8
Duopoly
  • two large producers or sellers
  • exactly two equally dominant firms seldom found
  • tend to compete or collude

9
Example of Duopoly
  • global aircraft market
  • two dominant firms are Airbus and Boeing
  • how do they compete with each other?

10
Oligopoly
  • markets dominated by a small number of large
    firms
  • the most common types of market
  • large firms are involved in selling either
    identical or very similar products
  • significant barriers to entry into the industry

11
Example of Oligopoly
  • the personal and domestic care product markets
  • dominated by
  • Unilever
  • Procter and Gamble
  • Colgate-Palmolive

12
Liberalisation
  • Ending monopolies has brought prices down.
  • In an open economy, monopolies are rarely
    justified. They tend to result in high prices and
    poor service, and to stifle innovation.
    Exceptions and subsidies are allowed for
    inherently uneconomic services, which can be
    considered a basic right, such as postal
    deliveries in rural areas.

13
  • However, a monopoly supplier cannot use revenue
    from monopoly activities to cross-subsidise
    commercial operations in which it competes with
    other firms.
  • If infrastructure constitutes a natural monopoly,
    like gas pipelines and some telecommunications
    infrastructure, then everyone must be allowed to
    use it on the same terms.

14
  • If there is no natural monopoly, then the process
    of selecting a company to provide the service
    must be transparent.
  • Professional services are another area where
    barriers to operating across borders have been
    slow to come down, but the European Commission
    has recently stepped up action to produce change.

15
Antitrust and cartels
  • It is illegal for businesses, including the
    professions, to collude with each other to fix
    prices or carve up markets between them.
  • If a single company has a dominant position in a
    particular market, it may not abuse its market
    power to drive out competitors.
  • Nor may a large company exploit the weaker
    negotiating position of its smaller customers and
    suppliers.

16
  • Large firms may not, for example, impose
    conditions on suppliers which hamper their
    freedom to do business with other companies.
  • The Commission can (and does) fine companies for
    all these practices.
  • Some exceptions are allowed.

17
  • The Commission can allow companies to cooperate
    in developing a single technical standard for the
    market as a whole.
  • It can allow smaller companies to cooperate if
    this strengthens their ability to compete with
    larger ones.

18
  • Some types of cooperation deal need specific
    Commission approval, but others are covered by
    rules on blanket exemptions.
  • The overriding considerations are whether
    consumers will benefit or other businesses be
    harmed.

19
  • Differences in car prices across the EU are
    narrowing, in part thanks to the efforts of the
    Commission in bringing greater transparency in
    pricing. Commission intervention has made
    multi--brand car dealerships possible, enabled
    non-authorised dealers to sell parts and carry
    out repairs, and since 1 October 2005 - allowed
    dealers to operate in more than one EU country.

20
  • Some significant country-to-country price
    differences remain because tax systems vary, but
    the Commission is seeking a restructuring of all
    tax systems to create a true single market.

21
Merger control
  • The Commission can ban or impose conditions on
    mergers and takeovers of one firm by another if
    the enlarged company would too easily be able to
    squeeze out its competitors or if a merger would
    leave so few players in the market that
    innovation would be stifled, or price competition
    or consumer choice significantly reduced.
  • In practice, most mergers are cleared without
    further action being necessary.

22
  • The Commission is generally only called upon to
    scrutinise the largest cross-border mergers,
    though smaller companies have the option of
    asking for Commission clearance if they think
    that will be less complex than going to several
    member states individually.
  • On the other hand, the Commission will leave a
    member state to decide if the impact of a merger
    involving large companies with international
    operations will essentially be restricted to a
    single country.

23
  • It makes no difference, on the other hand, where
    the companies are based.
  • If their sales figures in EU markets are large
    enough, the Commission has jurisdiction, and can
    prevent mergers even when the competition
    authorities in the country where the companies
    are headquartered have no objections.

24
State aids
  • The Commission monitors closely how much aid
    member state governments make available to
    business.
  • It looks not just at obvious forms of aid, such
    as loans and grants, but also at tax breaks,
    goods and services made available at preferential
    rates and at loan guarantees which make the
    borrower a better credit risk.

25
  • Aid to businesses which have no chance of ever
    standing on their own feet is not allowed.
  • Temporary assistance is permissible if there is a
    real chance that a business in difficulty can
    eventually become more competitive as a result.
  • Aid for research and innnovation, regional
    development or small and medium-sized enterprises
    is often allowable because these serve overall EU
    goals.

26
  • The litmus tests are (1) whether the aid is in
    the interest of the Union as a whole and (2)
    whether a private investor would provide money in
    the same circumstances.
  • The second test can justify start-up assistance
    granted by airports to attract low-cost airlines.
  • Aid to low-cost airlines is also acceptable if
    the revenues they generate offset the cost to the
    taxpayer of underutilised infrastructure at
    secondary airports.

27
  • There are public services, such as broadcasting,
    which governments may legitimately fund, but they
    must be careful not to pay a disproportionate
    amount.
  • Overpayment to the detriment of commercial
    competitors would be an illegal subsidy.

28
Checks and balances
  • The Commission's extensive powers to investigate
    and halt violations of EU competition rules are
    subject to judicial review by the European Court
    of Justice.
  • Companies and member states regularly lodge and
    sometimes succeed in appeals against Commission
    decisions, particularly in anti-trust, merger or
    state aid cases.

29
The challenge of globalisation
  • In an age of globalisation, global players must
    not be able to do as they please just because
    they escape any single governments control or to
    take advantage of gaps in the coverage of
    competition legislation in some countries.

30
  • The EU takes part in discussions within the World
    Trade Organisation (WTO) on the relationship
    between investment and competition, and is an
    active member of the International Competition
    Network (ICN).
  • More than 80 competition authorities are members
    of this network.
  • The ICN does not make rules, but promotes best
    practice, particularly in enforcement.

31
Guidelines on vertical restraints
  • DEFINITION OF VERTICAL RESTRAINTS
  • Vertical restraints are agreements or concerted
    practices entered into between two or more
    companies each of which operates, for the
    purposes of the agreement, at a different level
    of the production or distribution chain, and
    relating to the conditions under which the
    parties may purchase, sell or resell certain
    goods or services.

32
  • These guidelines set out the principles for the
    assessment of vertical agreements with a view to
    determining whether they affect competition
    between Member States.
  • The negative effects on the market that may
    result from vertical restraints which EC
    competition law aims to prevent are as follows

33
  • foreclosure of other suppliers or other buyers by
    raising barriers to entry
  • reduction of inter-brand competition between the
    companies operating on a market
  • reduction of inter-brand competition between
    distributo33rs
  • limitations on the freedom of consumers to
    purchase goods or services in a Member State.

34
Method of analysis for vertical restraints
  • In general, the assessment of a vertical
    restraint involves the following four steps
  • the companies involved need to define the
    relevant market in order to establish the market
    share of the supplier or the buyer, depending on
    the agreement. In order to calculate the market
    share, the relevant product market (which
    comprises any goods or services which are
    regarded by the buyer as interchangeable) and the
    relevant geographic market (which comprises the
    area in which the companies concerned are
    involved in the supply and demand of the relevant
    goods and services) are taken into account

35
  • If the relevant market share does not exceed the
    30 threshold, the vertical agreement is covered
    by the Block Exemption Regulation, subject to the
    conditions set out in Regulation No 2790/1999
  • If the relevant market share is above the 30
    threshold, it is necessary to assess whether the
    vertical agreement distorts competition. The
    following factors to be taken into consideration
    are the market position of the supplier,
    competitors and the buyer, entry barriers, the
    nature of the product, etc

36
  • If the vertical agreement falls within Article
    81(1), it is necessary to examine whether it
    fulfils the conditions for exemption. In that
    case, the vertical agreement must contribute to
    improving production or distribution or to
    promoting technical or economic progress and must
    allow consumers a fair share of those benefits.
  • At the same time, the vertical agreement must not
    impose on the companies concerned restraints
    which are not indispensable to the attainment of
    those benefits or to eliminate competition.

37
The most common vertical restraints
  • Single branding
  • Single branding results from an obligation or
    incentive which makes the buyer purchase
    practically all his requirements on a particular
    market from only one supplier. It does not mean
    that the buyer can only buy directly from the
    supplier but that he will not buy and resell or
    incorporate competing goods or services.
  • The possible competition risks are foreclosure of
    the market to competing and potential suppliers,
    facilitation of collusion between suppliers in
    cases of cumulative use and, where the buyer is a
    retailer selling to final consumers, a loss of
    in-store inter-brand competition.

38
  • Exclusive distribution
  • In an exclusive distribution agreement, the
    supplier agrees to sell his products only to one
    distributor for resale in a particular territory.
    At the same time, the distributor is usually
    limited in his active selling into other
    exclusively allocated territories.
  • The possible competition risks are mainly
    reduced intra-brand competition and market
    partitioning, which may in particular facilitate
    price discrimination. When most or all of the
    suppliers apply exclusive distribution, this may
    facilitate collusion, both at the suppliers' and
    the distributors' level.

39
  • Exclusive customer allocation
  • In an exclusive customer allocation agreement,
    the supplier agrees to sell his products only to
    one distributor for resale to a particular class
    of customer. At the same time, the distributor is
    usually limited in his active selling into other
    exclusively allocated classes of customer.
  • The possible competition risks are mainly reduced
    intra-brand competition and market partitioning,
    which may in particular facilitate price
    discrimination. When most or all of the suppliers
    apply exclusive customer allocation, this may
    facilitate collusion, both at the suppliers' and
    the distributors' level.

40
  • Selective distribution
  • Selective distribution agreements, like exclusive
    distribution agreements, restrict the number of
    authorised distributors, on the one hand, and the
    possibilities of resale on the other. The
    difference vis-à-vis exclusive distribution is
    that the restriction of the number of dealers
    does not depend on the number of territories but
    on selection criteria linked in the first place
    to the nature of the product.

41
  • Another difference vis-à-vis exclusive
    distribution is that the restriction on resale is
    not a restriction on active selling to a
    territory but a restriction on any sales to
    non-authorised distributors, leaving only
    appointed dealers and final customers as possible
    buyers. Selective distribution is almost always
    used to distribute branded final products.
  • The possible competition risks are a reduction in
    intra-brand competition and, especially in cases
    of cumulative effect, foreclosure of a certain
    type or types of distributor and facilitation of
    collusion between suppliers or buyers.

42
  • Franchising
  • Franchise agreements contain licences of
    intellectual property rights relating in
    particular to trade marks or signs and know-how
    for the use and distribution of goods or
    services. In addition to the licence of IPRs, the
    franchiser usually provides the franchisee during
    the life of the agreement with commercial or
    technical assistance. The licence and the
    assistance are integral components of the
    business method being franchised.

43
  • The franchiser is in general paid a franchise fee
    by the franchisee for the use of the particular
    business method. Franchising may enable the
    franchiser to establish, with limited
    investments, a uniform network for the
    distribution of his products. From the
    competition viewpoint, in addition to provision
    of the business method, franchise agreements
    usually contain a combination of different
    vertical restraints concerning the products being
    distributed, in particular selective distribution
    and/or non-compete and/or exclusive distribution
    or weaker forms thereof.

44
  • Exclusive supply
  • Exclusive supply means that there is only one
    buyer inside the Community to which the supplier
    may sell a particular final product. For
    intermediate goods or services, exclusive supply
    means that there is only one buyer inside the
    Community or that there is only one buyer inside
    the Community for the purposes of a specific use.
    For intermediate goods or services, exclusive
    supply is often referred to as industrial supply.
    The main competition risk of exclusive supply is
    the foreclosure of other buyers.

45
  • Tying
  • Tying exists when the supplier makes the sale of
    one product conditional upon the purchase of
    another distinct product from the supplier or
    someone designated by the latter. The first
    product is referred to as the tying product and
    the second is referred to as the tied product.
  • If the tying is not objectively justified by the
    nature of the products or commercial usage, such
    practice may constitute an abuse of a dominant
    position. Agreements of this type, which are
    designed to make the sale of one product
    conditional upon the purchase of another distinct
    product, may be incompatible with the competition
    rules.

46
  • Recommended and maximum resale prices
  • The practice consists in recommending a resale
    price to a reseller or requiring the reseller to
    respect a maximum resale price.
  • The possible competition risk of maximum and
    recommended prices is that they will work as a
    focal point for the resellers and might be
    followed by most or all of them. They may then
    facilitate collusion between suppliers.

47
  • DEFINITION OF A HORIZONTAL COOPERATION AGREEMENT
  • Cooperation is of a "horizontal nature" if an
    agreement or concerted practice is entered into
    between companies operating at the same level(s)
    in the market. In most instances, horizontal
    cooperation amounts to cooperation between
    competitors, which may lead to competition
    problems where it causes negative market effects
    with respect to prices, output, innovation or the
    variety and quality of products.

48
  • On the other hand, horizontal cooperation can
    lead to substantial economic benefits where it is
    a means of sharing risk, making cost savings,
    pooling know-how and launching innovations
    faster. These guidelines provide an analytical
    framework for horizontal cooperation agreements
    with a view to determining their compatibility
    with Article 81 of the EC Treaty.

49
  • Article 81(1) applies to horizontal cooperation
    agreements which have as their object or effect
    the prevention, restriction or distortion of
    competition. Many horizontal cooperation
    agreements, however, do not have as their object
    a restriction of competition and therefore an
    analysis of their effects in the market is
    necessary. For that analysis it is not sufficient
    that the agreement limits competition between the
    parties it must also be likely to affect
    competition in the market to such an extent that
    negative market effects as to prices, output,
    innovation or the variety or quality of products
    and services can be expected.

50
  • The agreement's ability to cause such negative
    market effects depends on the economic context,
    taking into account the nature of the agreement
    and the parties' combined market power together
    with other structural factors.

51
  • Each cooperation agreement must be analysed on a
    case-by-case basis. However, it is possible to
    identify in general terms cooperation agreements
    which
  • do not infringe the competition rules
  • This is normally true for cooperation that does
    not involve coordination of the parties'
    competitive behaviour in the market, such as (a)
    cooperation between non-competitors, (b)
    cooperation between competing companies that
    cannot independently carry out the project or
    activity covered by cooperation, and (c)
    cooperation concerning an activity which does not
    influence the relevant parameters of competition.
    These categories of cooperation restrict
    competition only if they involve firms with
    significant market power and are likely to cause
    foreclosure problems vis-à-vis third parties.

52
  • do infringe the competition rules
  • These are cooperation agreements designed to
    restrict competition by means of price fixing,
    output limitation or sharing markets or
    customers.
  • may infringe the competition rules
  • These are agreements which do not belong to the
    above-mentioned categories and which need further
    analysis of the market position and structure.

53
  • Market power and market structure
  • The starting point for the analysis is the
    position of the parties in the markets affected
    by cooperation. This determines whether or not
    they are likely to maintain, gain or increase
    market power through cooperation, i.e. whether
    they have the ability to cause negative market
    effects as to prices, output, innovation or the
    variety or quality of products and services.

54
  • To carry out this analysis, the relevant
    market(s) have to be defined and the parties'
    combined market share calculated. If it is low,
    cooperation is unlikely to produce restrictive
    effects. Given the variety of types of
    cooperation and the different effects they may
    cause in different market situations, it is
    impossible to indicate a general market share
    threshold above which sufficient market power for
    causing restrictive effects can be assumed.
  • Market concentration, i.e. the position and
    number of competitors, may have to be taken into
    account as an additional factor in assessing the
    impact of cooperation on market competition.

55
  • ASSESSMENT CRITERIA FOR EXEMPTION (Article 81(3)
    of the EC Treaty)
  • Cooperation agreements may be exempted provided
    that the following conditions are met
  • Economic benefits
  • Economic benefits, such as improvements in the
    production or distribution of products or the
    promotion of technical or economic progress, may
    outweigh restrictive effects on competition. The
    parties must demonstrate that the efficiency
    gains are likely to be caused by the cooperation
    and cannot be obtained by less restrictive means.

56
  • Fair share for consumers
  • The economic benefits must favour not only the
    parties to the agreement but also consumers.
  • Indispensability
  • If there are less restrictive ways of achieving
    similar benefits, the claimed efficiency gains
    cannot be used to justify restrictions of
    competition.

57
  • No elimination of competition
  • The criterion of "no elimination of competition"
    for a substantial part of the products in
    question is related to the concept of dominance.
    Where a dominant position exists, a horizontal
    agreement which produces anti-competitive effects
    cannot be exempted.

58
  • Block Exemption Regulations for RD and
    specialisation
  • In RD and specialisation agreements, the
    combination of skills can be the source of
    substantial efficiency gains. Agreements of this
    type are usually exempted up to a certain market
    share threshold under the Block Exemption
    Regulations for RD and specialisation agreements.

59
  • TYPES OF COOPERATION AGREEMENT
  • RD agreements
  • Production agreements
  • Purchasing agreements
  • Commercialisation agreements
  • Agreements on standards
  • Environmental agreements

60
  • Action plan guidelines
  • The reform of state aid policy must be a
    consistent and comprehensive. The action plan
    sets out guidelines for this reform that will be
    common to the various instruments involved.
  • Less state aid more efficiently applied The
    objective is to target state aid towards
    activities to which the financial markets are
    reluctant to loan money or which contribute to
    growth, competitiveness or the creation of
    sustainable jobs. However, achieving this
    objective depends partly on a more refined
    economic approach.

61
  • A more refined economic approach This involves
    finding out why, without public intervention, the
    market does not achieve an optimum result,
    whether it is because there is a "market failure"
    or because it produces social or regional
    inequalities which must be corrected. It is
    therefore necessary to better evaluate whether
    state aid is justified, whether it represents the
    most appropriate solution and how it can be
    implemented without distorting competition to an
    extent contrary to the common interest.

62
  • This approach would facilitate and speed up
    authorisation of the aid which least distorts
    competition and, at the same time, would focus
    attention on the aid likely to have the most
    serious distortive effect on competition.

63
  • More effective procedures, better enforcement,
    higher predictability and enhanced transparency
    Improving the rules on state aid will require
    more effective and more transparent procedures,
    extension of the scope of block exemptions, a
    reduction in the number of aid measures to be
    notified, faster decision-making and procedural
    rules adapted to the enlarged European Union.

64
  • This will result in greater legal certainty and
    will facilitate administrative tasks for the
    Commission and the Member States.
  • Moreover, as a result of enhanced transparency,
    firms, competition specialists, consumers and the
    public will find it easier to take action against
    unlawful aid, particularly before the national
    courts.

65
  • Shared responsibility between the Commission and
    Member States However, the rules and procedures
    on state aid cannot be improved without the
    active support of the Member States, which must
    undertake to notify all planned aid and to
    respect the rules on state aid.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com