Per-unit royalty vs fixed fee: the case of weak patents Rabah Amir, University of Arizona David Encaoua, Paris School of Economics, University Paris I Yassine Lefouili, Toulouse School of Economics - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

Per-unit royalty vs fixed fee: the case of weak patents Rabah Amir, University of Arizona David Encaoua, Paris School of Economics, University Paris I Yassine Lefouili, Toulouse School of Economics

Description:

... Kamien, Oren and Tauman, 1987, Muto,1993). Thus, the per-unit royalty scheme provides higher licensing revenues than the fixed fee scheme for a weak patent, ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:52
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 33
Provided by: DavidE130
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Per-unit royalty vs fixed fee: the case of weak patents Rabah Amir, University of Arizona David Encaoua, Paris School of Economics, University Paris I Yassine Lefouili, Toulouse School of Economics


1
Per-unit royalty vs fixed fee the case of weak
patents Rabah Amir, University of Arizona
David Encaoua, Paris School of Economics,
University Paris I Yassine Lefouili,
Toulouse School of Economics
  • Conference in honor of Claude dAspremont and
    Jean-François Mertens
  • CORE, 23-25 June 2011

2
How to sell a patent license?
  • Since Arrows contribution (1962), substantial
    literature comparing three contracts (upfront
    fee, auction and per-unit royalty) to sell a
    license to the members of an oligopoly.
  • Main conclusion the best licensing scheme
    (licensors view) is very sensitive in the
    context of analysis. It varies according to the
    nature of the licensor, the competition regime
    and the informational setting (Sen, 2005).
  • Illustration fixed fee and auction dominate
    per-unit royalty when the licensor is not active
    in the industry and licensees compete in
    quantities (Kamien Tauman 1984, 1986), whereas
    the comparison is reversed when the licensor is
    an insider (Sen Tauman, 2007)

3
But, patents are not certain property rights!
  • Common feature of all this literature patents
    are viewed as certain or ironclad rights, the
    validity of which is unquestionable. This
    clearly contradicts what we observe about half
    of the litigated patents in the US are
    invalidated (Allison Lemley, 1998).
  • A patent is not a perfectly enforceable right,
    as are other forms of property. Patents
    correspond much more to uncertain or
    probabilistic rights because they can be
    invalidated by a potential infringer (Ayres and
    Klemperer, 1999 Shapiro, 2003 Lemley and
    Shapiro, 2005).
  • Uncertainty over patents validity is even
    stronger than many applications are granted a
    patent protection, even though they do not meet
    one or several of the statutory requirements
    utility, novelty and non-obviousness or
    inventiveness.
  • Definition patents that have a very questionable
    validity, i.e. that have a high probability to
    be invalidated by a court if challenged, are
    qualified as weak patents (ex the patent
    sandwich of Mc Donald!)

4
Challenging patents validity
  • Even if challenging a patents validity is
    possible, it is nevertheless difficult. First,
    challenging may be directly prevented by the
    patent holder. Ex in Japan, Microsoft (MS)
    forced its licensed OEM suppliers to pledge not
    to file lawsuits on the grounds that Windows
    infringes a patent right (Matsushima et al.,
    2011).
  • Second, the US standard required to prove
    invalidity (clear and convincing evidence) is
    very demanding for the challenger, especially for
    new patentable subject matters (ex i4i vs.
    Microsoft).
  • Third, challenging has the dimension of a public
    good each competitor benefits from a successful
    challenge initiated by one of them, since they
    all get freely the new technology ? low
    individual incentives to challenge.
  • Main result on licensing a weak patent licensing
    revenues under the shadow of patent litigation
    are greater than the revenues the patent holder
    could expect if licensing was made posterior to
    the patents assessment. (Farrell Shapiro
    2008, Encaoua Lefouili 2009). This result
    raises serious diffusion antitrust concerns.

5
I4i v. Microsoft
  • The Canadian firm i4i (Infrastructures for
    Information Inc.) sued Microsoft (MS) for
    willful infringement of a patent about an XML
    markup language (words in boldface, centered,
    etc.) used in Word. At trial, MS contended that
    i4is patent was not valid because invention was
    already embodied in a software product sold in
    the market a year before the patent application.
    But the parties disagreed over whether the
    protected software in i4is patent was the same
    or was different from the earlier marketed
    software. The Court did not found clear and
    convincing evidence and condemned MS to pay 290
    million. In appeal, the US Federal Circuit (CAFC)
    didn't accept the preponderance of evidence
    proof made by MS.
  • The Supreme Court (SC) rejected recently (June
    2011) the contention made by MS that a burden of
    proof lower than the clear and convincing
    evidence should have been used.
  • This illustrates the difficulty for a challenger
    to invalidate a patent granted by a PO,
    especially in the US where the presumption of
    validity for a granted patent is very strong
    (282 of the Patent Act of 1952).

6
The cost-quality trade-off
  • Is it possible to avoid the unjustified licensing
    rents associated to bad quality patents? One
    evident solution should be to reinforce the
    review process at the PO in order to improve the
    quality of the granted patents.
  • However, Lemley (2001) raises a significant
    cost-quality trade-off improving the review
    process for each patent would be very expensive
    (monetary and non monetary costs such as
    increasing backlogs), with only small overall
    benefits, since many patents have no significant
    commercial value.
  • Lemley suggests that it should be rational and
    more efficient to maintain some ignorance at
    the POs level and to substitute a higher ex post
    opportunity to challenge a patents validity, to
    the ex ante improved quality goal. According to
    Lemley, allowing the challenge of a patents
    validity is sufficient to correct the
    unavoidable mistakes at the POs level.

7
How to sell a weak patent license?
  • Lemleys suggestion is not sufficient licensing
    a weak patent in the shadow of patent litigation
    does not avoid unjustified rents (Farrell
    Shapiro, 2008 Encaoua Lefouili, 2009). But
    which licensing scheme is better for the weak
    patents holder? Is the nature of the best scheme
    for a weak patent robust to the features that
    affect the licensing scheme choice when the
    patent is ironclad?
  • The paper investigates these questions.

8
Papers contribution
  • Weak patent holders decision charge a per-unit
    royalty or a fixed fee for licensing in the
    shadow of patent litigation? ? The paper extends
    two strands of literature
  • The (extensive) literature that focused on
    ironclad (perfect) patents.
  • The (burgeoning) literature on weak patents that
    focused on the inefficiencies stemming from the
    low private incentives to challenge patents
    validity
  • The paper gives a sufficient condition under
    which a weak patent holder prefers a per-unit
    royalty to a fixed fee the strategic effect of
    a cost increase on the aggregate profit is
    positive.
  • This condition is satisfied regardless of
    whether
  • The licensor is an outsider or an insider in the
    oligopoly,
  • The licensees compete à la Cournot or à la
    Bertrand with differentiated products (in general
    models of oligopoly).

9
Organization of the lecture
  • The model
  • The main result sufficient condition under which
    a per-unit royalty dominates a fixed fee
  • Extension 1 Insider
  • Extension 2 Litigation cost
  • Application 1 Cournot with homogenous products
  • Application 2 Bertrand with differentiated
    products
  • One exception Monopoly in the product market

10
The model
  • Patent owner P, not active in the industry, sells
    a license for a cost reduction technology unit
    cost reduction from c to c c - e. Buyers are
    members of an oligopoly n gt 1 identical
    risk-neutral firms producing initially at
    marginal cost c.
  • 3-stage game
  • 1st stage P offers a licensing contract to all
    firms, involving the payment of either a per-unit
    royalty r or a fixed fee F.
  • 2nd stage The n firms, independently and
    simultaneously, decide whether to purchase or not
    a license.
  • 3rd stage Competition occurs among the industry
    members, with the cost structure inherited from
    2nd stage c c - e for licensees and c for
    non-licensees.

11
Description of the 2nd stage
  • If a firm does not accept the license offer, it
    can challenge the patent's validity before a
    court. ? probability that the patent is
    challenged and its validity upheld by the court ?
    ? ?0,1 measures the patents quality. Low ? ?
    weak patent, while ? 1 ? ironclad patent.
  • If the patent is upheld by the court (?), it
    becomes an ironclad right ? a firm that does not
    purchase a license uses the old technology and
    produces at cost c, while those firms who accept
    the offer use the new technology and pay the
    royalty r or the fixed fee F.
  • If the patent is invalidated by the court (1 -
    ?), all firms, including those which accepted the
    license offer, use freely the new technology.

12
More on the 3rd stage
  • The type of competition between licensees and
    non-licensees is not specified except to assume
    the existence and uniqueness of Nash equilibrium
    and some properties that hold under various
    settings.
  • Notations p e (k, c) (resp. p i (k, c))
    equilibrium profit of an efficient (resp.
    inefficient) firm when k n efficient licensees
    produce at cost c lt c and n-k inefficient
    non-licensees produce at cost c.
  • qe(n, c) equilibrium output (with n licensees)
  • Assumptions A1 p e (k, c), p i (k, c) and
    qe(n, c) class C2 in c over 0, c.
  • A2 ? p i (k, c) / ? c gt 0.
  • A3 ? p e (k, c) / ? c lt 0.
  • A4 p j (k1, c) lt p j (k, c), for j e, i.
  • A5 p i (k, c) lt p e (k1, c).

13
Results on the 2nd stage equilibria
  • Lemma 1. With a royalty r, two types of
    equilibria are possible
  • 1. all the n firms buy a license (no litigation)
  • 2. only n-1 firms buy a license and one firm
    litigates.
  • Lemma 2. With a fixed fee F, many equilibria are
    possible according to the value of F (demand
    function of licenses)
  • - n licensees iff F F(?) ?pe(n,
    c-e)-pi(n-1,c-e)
  • .
  • - k licensees (where 0 k lt n) iff F k1 F
    F k where
  • F k pe(k, c-e)-pi(k-1,c-e).
  • For both licensing schemes, we focus on
    equilibria involving all the n firms as licensees
    (i.e. equilibria in which litigation is
    deterred).

14
Optimal per-unit royalty deterring litigation
  • Definition The optimal per-unit royalty that is
    accepted by all firms is the solution of the
    program max r n r q e (n, c- e r)
  • u.c. p e (n, c-e r) ? p I (n-1, c- e
    r)(1-?) p e(n, c-e).
  • Proposition 1 The optimal per-unit royalty that
    deters any litigation is the unique value r(?)
    that binds the constraint. It satisfies the
    following properties, for low ?
  • r(0)0, r(0) gt 0
  • if r r(?), kn is the only 2nd stage
    equilibrium
  • If r gt r(?), kn-1 and one firm challenges is the
    only 2nd stage equilibrium
  • Pr(?) nr(?)qen, c- e r(?) gt ?
    Pr(1)(1-?)Pr(0) ? Pr(1), i.e. the revenues
    when licensing occurs prior to the patents
    assessment are higher than the revenues the
    patent holder would expect if the validity issue
    were resolved before licensing.

15
Optimal fixed fee deterring litigation
  • Proposition 2 The value F(?) ?pe(n,
    c-e)-pi(n-1,c-e) is the optimal fixed fee
    accepted by all the n firms. If ? is sufficiently
    small, it is the only second stage equilibrium
  • Note Since F(?) is proportional to ? (i.e. F(?)
    ?F(1)), where F(1) is the fee corresponding to an
    ironclad patent, fixed fee licensing revenues per
    license are the same whether licensing occurs
    prior or posterior to the patents validity
    assessment
  • PF(?) F(?) ?F(1) ?PF(1)(1-?)PF(0) ?PF(1)
  • Remark Since Pr(?) gt ? Pr(1) and PF(?)
    ?PF(1), there is a presumption that a per-unit
    royalty should be preferred to a fixed fee. We
    show that this presumption is correct under some
    condition.

16
Royalty dominates fixed fee A SUFFICIENT
CONDITION
  • Proposition 3 For low ?, if ?p e (n, c) / ?c gt
    - q e(n, c) (1)
  • the optimal per-unit royalty r(?) deterring
    litigation provides higher licensing revenues for
    an outsider than the optimal fixed fee F(?)
    deterring litigation.
  • Interpretation condition (1) strategic effect
    of an increase in the marginal cost on a firms'
    equilibrium profits is positive

17
Novelty of condition (1)
  • Condition (1) means that the positive price
    effect qe (n, c) ?p e (n, c) / ?c of a
    cost increase outweighs the negative quantity
    effect (pe (n, c) - c) ?qe(n, c) / ?c.
  • Literature on oligopoly focused on the overall
    effect (direct strategic effect) of a cost
    change on profits, and showed that it could be
    positive (Kimmel, 1992, Février and Linnemer
    2004). But what matters in our setting is the
    sign of the strategic effect.
  • Conclusion even in a setting where a patent
    holder would have used the fixed fee licensing
    scheme if the patent was certain (?1), it could
    prefer the per-unit royalty scheme when the
    patent is weak (? low), if the strategic effect
    of a common cost variation on the profits in the
    product market is positive (condition (1)).

18
Extension 1 the insider case
  • Suppose now that P is active in the industry and
    has at least two competitors (n gt 2). Cost
    structure following the licensing stage subgame
  • one firm - the patent holder P - that produces at
    unit cost c - e
  • a number k lt n of firms - the licensees indexed
    by l - that produce at a unit cost c c - e
    r (where c ?c - e, c)
  • and the remaining n-k-1 firms - the non-licensees
    indexed by n - that produce at unit cost c .
  • Optimal r(?) deterring litigation
  • p l (n -1c - e r(?)) ? p n(n -2c - e
    r(?)) (1-? ) p l(n -1 c - e)
  • Pr (?) p p(n -1 c - e r(?) ) (n -1) r
    (?) ql(n -1 c - e r(?))
  • Optimal fixed fee F(?) deterring litigation
  • F(?) ?p l(n -1 c - e) - p n(n -2 c - e
    )
  • PF (?) p p(n -1 c - e ) (n- 1) F (?)

19
Best licensing for an insider
  • Proposition 4 For an insider firm holding a weak
    patent, who has to choose a licensing scheme
    deterring litigation, the optimal per-unit
    royalty r(?) provides higher revenues than the
    optimal fixed fee F(?), if the strategic effect
    of an individual increase of the unit cost on
    the aggregate profit of the industry is positive
    (condition 2)
  • ? p (c,, c)/ ?ci gt - qi (c,, c), for
    i1,,n (2)
  • p is the aggregate profit of the industry.
  • Condition (2) for the insider case generalizes
    condition (1) for the outsider case.
  • Interpretation of (2) From an equally efficient
    cost structure, the strategic effect of an
    increase in one firms unit cost on the aggregate
    profit is positive.

20
First robustness result
  • Under condition (2) stating that the strategic
    effect of an increase in one firms unit cost on
    the aggregate profit is positive, a per-unit
    royalty dominates a fixed fee for a weak patent,
    regardless of whether the patent holder is an
    outsider or an insider in the industry
  • ? p (c,, c)/ ?ci gt - qi (c,, c), i1,,n
    (2)

21
Extension 2 litigation cost
  • Introduce a litigation cost C gt 0 supported by a
    firm that challenges a patents validity before a
    court. The higher is C, the lower are the
    incentives to challenge the patents validity,
    and the higher are the licensing revenues (under
    both schemes) that the patent holder can extract
    without triggering litigation.
  • Proposition 5 Under condition (2), the dominance
    of the per-unit scheme over the fixed fee scheme
    remains true when the model is extended to
    include (small) legal costs incurred by a
    challenger.

22
A question
  • Are the assumptions made on the profit functions
    and the sufficient condition (2) under which a
    per-unit royalty dominates a fixed fee for
    licensing a weak patent, satisfied in standard
    oligopoly models?
  • Cournot oligopoly with homogenous goods and
    Bertrand oligopoly with differentiated goods,
    both with general demand functions, the main
    restrictions being those needed to ensure
    existence and uniqueness of a Nash equilibrium in
    pure strategies.

23
Cournot competition with homogenous goods.
  • Oligopoly composed by n gt 1 firms competing à la
    Cournot. Cost structure marginal costs c1,cn.
    The game is said to be symmetric if c1cn c.
  • Inverse demand function P() satisfying the
    following assumptions
  • C1 P() is twice continuously differentiable
    and P'()lt0 whenever P()gt0.
  • C2 P(0)gt ci gtP(Q) for Q sufficiently high,
    i1,,n
  • C3 P'(Q)QP''(Q)lt0 for all Q 0 with P() gt 0
    (ensures existence equilibrium, Novshek 1985 )

24
Cournot competition with homogenous products
  • Proposition 4 Under Assumptions C1-C3,
  • a/ There exists a unique Cournot equilibrium.
    Furthermore, if the game is symmetric, the
    equilibrium is symmetric, and the functions q(c)
    and p(c) decrease in c.
  • b/ Assumptions A1-A5 (or A1-A5 if P is
    insider) on the equilibrium profit functions are
    satisfied.
  • c/ Condition (2) holds ?p (c,,c) / ?ci gt -
    qi(c,..,c), i1,,n
  • Conclusion Under Cournot competition, the holder
    of a weak patent prefers the use of a per-unit
    royalty rather than a fixed fee, regardless
    whether the patent holder is active or not in the
    market. Recall that the reverse holds for an
    outsider holding an unquestionable patent (i.e.
    ?1, Kamien, 1992).

25
A caveat on proposition 4
  • Proposition 4 asserts that the profit p(c)
    decreases in c when the game is symmetric. While
    intuitive, this result does not hold for a
    sufficiently convex demand function in a
    symmetric Cournot model.
  • Counter-example n2, c1c2c and P(Q)Q-1/b with
    ½ltblt1. In this case P'(Q)QP''(Q) gt 0, i.e.
    assumption C3 is not satisfied. Profit
    p(c)(2b-1)/cb-1 /bb 21b increases in c.
    Moreover, no more uniqueness of Cournot
    equilibrium (two equilibria, one of which has
    each firm producing zero output).
  • By imposing assumption C3 to guarantee existence
    and uniqueness of Cournot equilibrium, one also
    obtains that the counter-intuitive result on the
    positive effect of a cost increase does not hold.

26
Bertrand competition with differentiated products
  • Industry composed by n single product firms
    competing à la Bertrand with marginal costs
    c1,,cn and imperfect substitutes products.
  • Di (p1, p2,...,pn) demand function for good i
    satisfying the following assumptions B1 - B4
  • B1 Di is twice continuously differentiable on
    the subspace where Di(p1, p2,...,pn) gt 0.
  • B2 (i)(?Di/?pi)lt0, (ii)(?Di/?pj )gt0,
  • (iii) ?k (?Di/(?pk) lt0, i1,,n own price
    effect dominates cross-price effects( demand
    level).

27
Assumptions
  • B3 Di(?²Di)/(?pj?pi)-(?Di/?pj)(?Di/?pi)gt0, j ? i
    the price elasticity of demand increases in any
    rivals price (Amir, 2005).
  • B4 ?k(?²logDi/?pi ?pk))lt0, i1,..n along the
    diagonal, own effects of price changes dominate
    cross effects, for the slope of demand. B4
    guarantees the uniqueness of Bertrand equilibrium
    (Milgrom and Roberts, 1990, Vives, 1999).
  • Bertrand oligopoly model is said to be symmetric
    if the demand functions are symmetric and c1
    cnc

28
Bertrand competition with differentiated products
  • Proposition 5 Under Assumptions B1-B4, the
    Bertrand game is log-supermodular and has a
    unique equilibrium which is symmetric if the
    oligopoly game is symmetric.
  • Firm is equilibrium profit pi is decreasing in
    ci and, if Bertrand oligopoly is symmetric, the
    per-firm equilibrium profit p is decreasing in
    c.
  • The assumptions on the equilibrium profit
    functions are satisfied.
  • - In symmetric Bertrand oligopoly, two
    properties hold
  • c? p(c) is increasing, with a slope 1
  • Condition (2) is satisfied ?p (c) / ?ci gt
    - qi(c), i1,,n

29
Sum-up
  • Under Bertrand competition with differentiated
    products, the per-unit royalty scheme provides
    higher licensing revenues than the fixed fee
    scheme for a weak patent, whereas for an
    unquestionable patent, this result holds only
    when the products are close substitutes or when
    the size of the cost-reduction is small (Kamien
    and Tauman, 1986, Kamien, Oren and Tauman, 1987,
    Muto,1993).
  • Thus, the per-unit royalty scheme provides higher
    licensing revenues than the fixed fee scheme for
    a weak patent, regardless whether the downward
    competition is of the Cournot type or of the
    Bertrand type with differentiated products.

30
One exception the monopoly case
  • Suppose now there exists only one potential
    licensee (n1)
  • Proposition 6 If dqM (c)/dc lt 0 (3), the weak
    patent holder obtains higher licensing revenues
    from a fixed fee than from a per-unit royalty.
  • Application Under usual assumptions on the
    demand function leading to the existence and
    uniqueness of the monopoly solution, condition
    (3) is fulfilled. Therefore, when the seller of
    a weak patent is confronted to only one potential
    licensee, charging a fixed fee rather than a
    per-unit royalty is better. The main reason is
    that the incentive to challenge a weak patent is
    high in the monopoly case .

31
Conclusion
  • We have obtained a clear-cut result on the
    comparison of a weak patent holder's profits
    under two schemes the per-unit licensing scheme
    dominates the fixed fee licensing scheme for a
    weak patent and the weak patent holder is able to
    capture some unjustified rents by using the
    former. This result is independent of the type of
    downstream competition, of the degree of product
    differentiation and whether the patent holder is
    active or not in the downstream market
  • Recall that varying any of these features can
    overturn the outcome of the comparison when
    ironclad patents are considered.

32
A proposal
  • Facilitating the challenge of a patents validity
    improves certainly the effective functioning of
    the patent system. But, it is not sufficient.
    Even if the stringent standard of proof to
    invalidate a patent is relaxed, licensing a weak
    patent through a per unit royalty under the
    shadow of patent litigation still involves
    unjustified revenues.
  • A promising avenue to reduce the harmful impact
    of very questionable patents should be to
    replace the ex post reexamination procedure by
    an ex ante opposition procedure in which each
    third party could justify its opposition to the
    patent grant. Licensing would occur after such an
    opposition. The existence of such procedure in
    Europe may explain why the EPO has a higher
    reputation than the USPTO in terms of quality of
    the granted patents.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com