XI. MARKET EFFICIENCY - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

XI. MARKET EFFICIENCY

Description:

XI. MARKET EFFICIENCY A. Introduction to Market Efficiency An Efficient Capital Market is a market where security prices reflect all available information. – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:88
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 30
Provided by: John4294
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: XI. MARKET EFFICIENCY


1
XI. MARKET EFFICIENCY
2
A. Introduction to Market Efficiency
  • An Efficient Capital Market is a market where
    security prices reflect all available
    information.
  • In an efficient market, the expected price of a
    tradable asset, given the information ? available
    to the market and the information ?k available to
    any investor k equals the expected price based on
    the information available to the market for all
    investors k
  •  
  • The price of the asset reflects the consensus
    evaluation of the market based on the information
    available to the market, regardless of private
    information held by investor k.
  • Individual k's information set ?k does not
    improve his estimate of expected price in an
    efficient market the market price already
    reflects all relevant information ? including
    investor ks special information ?k.
  • In a perfectly efficient market where security
    prices fully reflect all available information,
    all security transactions will have zero net
    present value.

3
B. Weak Form Efficiency
  • Weak form efficiency tests are concerned with
    whether an investor might consistently earn
    higher than normal returns based on knowledge of
    historical price sequences.
  • One can never prove weak form efficiency because
    there are an infinite number of ways to forecast
    future returns from past returns.
  • Cowles 1933 and Working 1934 studied the
    random movement of stock prices. Their results
    indicated that stock prices seemed to fluctuate
    randomly, without being influenced by their
    histories.
  • Another of the earlier weak form efficiency tests
    found a very slight, but statistically
    significant relationship between historical and
    current prices .057 of a given day's variation
    in the log of the price relative is explained by
    the prior day's change in the log of the price
    relative
  •  
  •  
  • The r-square value from one such regression was
    .00057, where represents price of stock i on a
    given day t, the price on the day immediately
    prior, b0 and b1 regression coefficients and
    the error terms in the regression.

4
Residuals Tests
  • Fama and MacBeth , after adjusting for risk,
    found no correlation in daily CAPM residuals
  •  
  •  
  •  
  • Error terms are regressed against their prior day
    values . A negative value for bi suggests mean
    reversion. Positive values for bi suggest
    momentum. Fama and MacBeth found very little
    evidence for either mean reversion or momentum in
    stock prices.

5
Runs Tests
  • It is important to note that correlation
    coefficients can be unduly influenced by extreme
    observations. One way to deal with such
    assumption violations is to construct a simple
    runs test.
  • Consider the following daily price sequence 50,
    51, 52, 53, 52, 50, 45, 49, 54 and 53. The price
    changes might be represented by the following
    (----), indicating four price runs. That is,
    there were four series of positive or negative
    price change runs. The expected number of runs in
    a runs test if price changes are random is (MAX
    MIN)/2, where MAX is the largest number of
    possible runs (equals the number of prices in the
    series) and MIN is the minimum number (1).
  • The number of runs consistent with random
    sequences in our example is 10 (91)/2. More
    runs suggests mean reversion and a smaller number
    suggests momentum.
  • The actual levels of returns are unimportant
    only the signs of returns are important, so that
    extreme observations will not unduly bias tests.
    In one test of daily price changes, Fama 1965
    expected 760 runs based on the assumption that
    price changes were randomly generated, but only
    found 735 runs. High transactions costs seem to
    be related to runs - investors are unable to
    exploit a series because of brokerage
    commissions.
  • 2 to 3 times as many reversals of price trends as
    continuations based on transaction-to-transaction
    price data. This might be because of unexecuted
    limit orders - for them to be executed the price
    has to reverse itself. For example, suppose that
    a market purchase order has just been executed at
    an uptick. All of the limit sell orders at this
    most recent execution price have to be executed
    for the price to increase again. This means that
    a purchase is more likely to be followed by a
    downtick (-) or no change at all (0) than an
    uptick ().

6
Filter Rules and Market Over-reaction
  • A filter rule states that a transaction for a
    security should occur when its price has changed
    by a given percentage over a specified period of
    time.
  • Some early studies found that when filter rules
    did seem to work (however slightly), they were
    not able to cover transactions costs.
    Profitability of these rules seem to be related
    to daily correlations.
  • Such correlation and filter rules seemed to work
    slightly better in Norway, where stronger
    correlations tended to exist. However, these
    markets were less liquid and transactions costs
    were significantly higher in Norwegian markets
    than in American markets.
  • DeBondt and Thaler 1985 argued that buying
    stocks that performed poorly in a prior 3-5 year
    period and selling those that performed well
    would have generated abnormally high returns in
    subsequent 3-5 year periods.
  • On the other hand, Jegadeesh and Titman 1993
    found results that conflicted with DeBondt and
    Thaler based on shorter holding periods (3-12
    months). Their study suggested that the market is
    slow to react to firm-specific information.
  • The findings of both DeBondt Thaler and
    Jegadeesh Titman that seem to contradict weak
    form market efficiency are not universally
    accepted. For example, Richardson and Stock
    1988 argued that these momentum results of
    DeBondt and Thaler were due largely to their
    statistical methodology, as did Jegadeesh (1991)
    who argued that these mean reversion effects
    seemed to hold only in January.

7
Moving Averages
  • Moving average techniques consolidate shorter
    series of observations into longer series, and
    are used for smoothing data variability.
  • A simple q-period moving average is computed as
    follows
  •  
  •  
  • Trading strategies might be based on these moving
    averages. For example, if current prices rise
    above a falling moving average, they might be
    expected to drop back towards the moving average
    selling is suggested.
  • Moving averages can be computed for any number of
    price data points. For example, consider the
    following sequence of daily closing prices for a
    given stock over a period of time
  • 12 14 17 13 14
    19 22 17 11 18
    16 22
  • t1 t2 t3 t4 t5
    t6 t7 t8 t9 t10
    t11 t12
  • The following represents the sequence of simple
    three-day moving averages for the above price
    sequences
  •  
  • NA NA 14.3 14.7 14.7
    15.3 18.3 19.3 16.7 15.3
    15.0 18.7
  • t1 t2 t3 t4 t5
    t6 t7 t8 t9 t10
    t11 t12
  •  
  • Brock, Lakonishok and LeBaron 1992 demonstrated
    evidence suggesting that certain moving average
    rules and rules based on resistance levels
    produced higher than normal returns when applied
    to daily data for the Dow Jones Industrial
    Average from 1897 to 1986. However, Sullivan,
    Timmerman and White 1997 tested their findings
    on updated data and found that the best
    technical trading rule does not provide superior
    performance when used to trade in the subsequent
    10-year post-sample period.

8
The January Effect
  • Numerous studies have confirmed a "January
    Effect, where returns for the month of January
    tend to exceed returns for other months.
  • This January effect has a greater effect on the
    shares of smaller companies (which are frequently
    held by individual investors) than on shares of
    larger firms (frequently held by institutional
    investors).
  • Some studies suggest that much of the January
    effect can be explained by December transactions
    being seller initiated and execute at bids while
    January transactions are buyer initiated and
    execute at offers. However, the January effect is
    large enough that it would exist even if all
    transactions executed at bids.
  • The January Effect and Tax-driven Selling
  • Year-end tax selling - investors sell their
    "losers" at the end of the year to capture tax
    write-offs may force down prices at the end of
    the year. They recover early in the following
    year, most significantly during the first five
    trading days in January (and the last trading day
    in December).
  • Abnormally high trading volume exists in
    December.
  • Losers" outperform "winners" in January of the
    subsequent year
  • January effects exist for low grade corporate
    bonds and in shares of companies that issue these
    bonds. This effect does not seem to hold for high
    grade corporate bonds or for the shares of the
    companies that issue these bonds.
  • Contrasting tax explanations are studies
    demonstrating that this effect exists in markets
    whose tax years differ from the calendar year.
  • The January effect appears in Australia and other
    countries where the fiscal and calendar years
    differ. The January effect in Canada existed
    before the introduction of a capital gains tax.
  • U.S. markets might be sufficiently influential in
    world markets that year-end tax selling in the
    U.S. might simply drive prices in other markets.
  • On the other hand, there was a January effect in
    U.S. markets during 1877-1916, before U.S. income
    taxes. Again, a January effect with no tax-driven
    selling.
  • Furthermore, municipal bond issues, which are
    free from federal taxation, experience a
    significant January effect.

9
The January Effect and Window-Dressing
  • Funds may "window dress" at year-end by buying
    winners (stocks that performed well earlier in
    the year) and by selling losers. These
    transactions occur at the end of the year so that
    their clientele can see from year-end financial
    statements that their funds held high-performing
    stocks and did not hold losers.
  • However, most institutions report their holdings
    to clients more than once per year . But, this
    effect does not appear in any other month.
    Furthermore, winners still realize higher January
    returns than in any other month just not as high
    as losers.
  • If the "window-dressing" hypothesis explains the
    January effect better than the tax-selling
    hypothesis, one should expect that shares held by
    institutions should outperform shares held by
    individuals during the month of January.
  • The January effect is more pronounced for smaller
    firms than for larger firms (smaller firms are
    more likely to be held by individual investors).
  • The January effect is more pronounced for
    companies with many individual shareholders than
    companies with more institutional investors.

10
The Small Firm and P/E Effects
  • The stock of smaller firms may outperform larger
    firms.
  • This effect may hold after adjusting for risk as
    measured by beta.
  • However, other measures of risk may be more
    appropriate for smaller firms that may not have
    well-established trading records.
  • Furthermore, transactions costs for many smaller
    firms may exceed those for larger firms,
    particularly when they are thinly traded.
  • The small firm effect seems most pronounced in
    January.
  • Although Fama and French 1992 find a
    significant size effect in their study of the
    CAPM over a fifty-year period, they do not find a
    size effect during the period between 1981 and
    1990. This might suggest that the size effect
    either no longer exists or was merely a
    statistical artifact prior to 1981.
  • Basu 1977 and Fama and French 1992 find that
    firms with low price to earnings ratios
    outperform firms with higher P/E ratios.
  • Fama and French find that the P/E ratio, combined
    with firm size predict security returns
    significantly better than the Capital Asset
    Pricing Model.

11
The IPO Anomaly
  •  The IPO anomaly refers to patterns associated
    with Initial Public offerings of equities
  •  
  • 1. Short-term IPO returns are abnormally
    high.
  • 2. IPOs seem to underperform the market in
    the long
  • run.
  • 3. IPO underperformance seems to be cyclical.
  •  

12
C. Testing Momentum and Mean Reversion Strategies
  • See spreadsheets.

13
Sports Betting Markets
  • Sports betting markets potentially have much in
    common with stock markets. There is some evidence
    of persistent inefficiencies in sports betting
    markets. For example, Thaler and Ziemba 1988
    note that favorites in horse races outperform
    long shots while Woodland and Woodland 1994
    find the opposite is true for baseball betting.
    Brown and Sauer 1993 find that several
    observable variables in addition to the spread
    can be used to improve the outcomes of
    professional basketball games. Gray and Gray
    1997, Golec and Tamarkin 1991 and Gandar et
    al. 1988 find evidence that certain strategies
    can be used to improve professional football
    betting.
  •  

14
Summary
  • Generally, statistical studies indicate that
    stock markets are efficient with respect to
    historical price sequences.
  • However, one must realize that an infinite number
    of possible sequences can be identified with any
    series of prices. Clearly, many of these series
    must be associated with higher than normal future
    returns.
  • However, when research finds a sequence that
    leads to higher than normal returns, one must
    question whether the abnormal return result is
    merely a statistical artifact due to data mining.
    William Schwert 2003 was quoted 
  • These research findings raise the possibility
    that anomalies are more apparent than real. The
    notoriety associated with the findings of unusual
    evidence tempts authors to further investigate
    puzzling anomalies and later try to explain them.
    But even if the anomalies existed in the sample
    period in which they were first identified, the
    activities of practitioners who implement
    strategies to take advantage of anomalous
    behavior can cause the anomalies to disappear (as
    research findings cause the market to become more
    efficient).
  • Richard Roll 1992, in a blunt comment, stated 
  • I have personally tried to invest money, my
    clients and my own, in every single anomaly and
    predictive result that academics have dreamed up.
    That includes the strategy of DeBondt and Thaler
    (that is, sell short individual stocks
    immediately after one-day increases of more than
    5), the reverse of DeBondt and Thaler which is
    Jegadeesh and Titman (buy individual stocks after
    they have decreased by 5), etc. I have attempted
    to exploit the so-called year-end anomalies and a
    whole variety of strategies supposedly documented
    by academic research. And I have yet to make a
    nickel on any of these supposed market
    inefficiencies.
  • Clearly, technical analysis has its share of
    critics. Warren Buffet was quoted saying I
    realized technical analysis didn't work when I
    turned the charts upside down and didn't get a
    different answer.
  • Most apparent incidences of mispricing seem
    eliminated by transactions costs. The primary
    exceptions to weak form market efficiency seem to
    be IPO effect, probably the January effect,
    perhaps the small firm effect, and perhaps the
    P/E effect.
  • There is little agreement as to why these effects
    persist or even if the latter two do exist they
    are anomalies.

15
D. Semi-Strong Form Efficiency
  • Semi-strong form efficiency tests are concerned
    with whether security prices reflect all publicly
    available information.
  • For example, how much time is required for a
    given type of information to be reflected in
    security prices? What types of publicly available
    information might an investor use to generate
    higher than normal returns?
  • The vast majority of studies of semi-strong form
    market efficiency suggest that the tested
    publicly available information and announcements
    cannot be used by the typical investor to secure
    significantly higher than normal returns.  

16
Early Tests
  • Cox 1930 found no evidence that professional
    stock analysts could outperform the market.
  • Cowles 1933 performed several tests of what was
    later to be known as the efficient market
    hypothesis (EMH). He examined the forecasting
    abilities of forty-five professional securities
    analysis agencies, comparing the returns that
    might have been generated by professionals'
    recommendations to actual returns on the market
    over the same period.
  • Average returns generated by professionals were
    less than those generated by the market over the
    same periods.
  • The best performing fund did not exhibit
    unusually high performance at a statistically
    significant level.
  • Cowles also tested whether analyst picks were
    more profitable than random picks.
  • Cowles examined the abilities of analysts to
    predict the direction of the market as opposed to
    selecting individual stocks.
  • A buy and hold strategy was no less profitable
    than following advice of professionals as to when
    to long or short the market.
  • He performed a simulation study using a deck of
    cards. Based on reports of analyst
    recommendations, he computed the average number
    of times analysts change their recommendations
    over a year. He then randomly selected dates,
    using cards numbered 1-229 (the number of weeks
    the study covered) to make simulated random
    recommendations. Draws were taken from a second
    set of randomly selected cards numbered 1 to 9,
    each with a certain recommendation (long, short,
    half stock and half cash, etc.) for a given date.
    Cowles then compared the results distribution of
    the 33 recommendations based on randomly
    generated advice to the advice provided by the
    actual advisors. He found that the professionals
    generated the same return distributions as did
    the random recommendations.
  • Cowles also examined 255 editorials by William
    Peter Hamilton, the fourth editor of the Wall
    Street Journal who had a reputation for
    successful forecasting. Between 1902 until his
    death 1929, Hamilton forecast 90 changes in the
    market 45 were correct and 45 were incorrect.
  • If experts are unable to distinguish between
    strong and weak stock market performers, and
    investors are well aware of this lack of ability,
    why do market forecasters still exist and
    investors still purchase and follow their advice?
  • One possible explanation for reliance on
    unreliable expert forecasters is that investors
    are less interested in accuracy than in avoiding
    responsibility for their selections.
  • Investors who rely on advice from experts seek to
    avoid blame when the forecasts are inaccurate.
  • Avoidance of responsibility in another field is
    illustrated Cocozza and Steadman 1978 in their
    study of New York psychiatrists who were asked to
    predict whether mental patients were dangerous
    and required involuntary confinement.

17
FFJR, Stock Splits and Event Studies
  • FFJR examined the effects of stock splits on
    stock prices
  • This paper was the first to use the now classic
    event study methodology.
  • Although stock prices did change significantly
    before announcements of stock splits (and
    afterwards as well), Fama et al. argued that
    splits were related to more fundamental factors
    (such as dividends), and that it was actually
    these fundamental factors that affected stock
    prices. The splits themselves were unimportant
    with respect to subsequent returns.
  • Fama et al. identified the month in which a
    particular stock split occurred, calling that
    month time zero for that stock. Thus, each stock
    had associated with it a particular month zero
    (t0), and months subsequent to the split were
    assigned positive values.
  • They estimated expected returns for each month t
    for the stocks in their sample with single index
    model ri,t a birm,t ei,t where the
    expected residual (ei,t) value was zero.
  • They examined residuals (ei,t) for each security
    i for each month t then averaged the residuals
    (ARt) for each month across securities.
  • Afterwards, they calculated cumulative average
    residuals (CARt) starting 30 months before splits
    (t -30).
  • FFJR provided the framework for future event
    studies and semi-strong efficiency tests.
  • Consider the following general notes regarding
    testing the semi-strong form efficiency
    hypothesis 
  • Use daily price and returns data since
    information is incorporated into prices within
    days (or much shorter periods).
  • Announcements are usually more important than
    events themselves
  • Base security performance on estimated expected
    returns.
  • When using Standard Single Index Model, we
    estimate slopes from historical data. Normally,
    we find them biased forecasters for future
    values, so we may adjust them towards one.
  • One way to deal with slope measurement error is
    to use moving windows
  • An alternative to CARs is buy and hold abnormal
    residuals as follows BHARt ?(1 et) - 1.

18
Corporate Merger Announcements, Annual Reports
and Other Financial Statements
  • Firth considered market efficiency when an
    announcement is made for purchase of more than
    10 of a firm.
  • Presumably, an announcement indicates a potential
    merger.
  • Firth calculated CAR starting 30 days prior to
    announcements the bulk of CAR is realized
    between last trade before and first trade after
    announcements, though it still increases slightly
    after an announcement.
  • Thus, a large block purchaser can still make
    excess returns.
  • An insider obviously can make excess returns one
    without inside information cannot (except for the
    first trader after the announcement).
  • Since returns change almost immediately, Firth
    suggested that there is semi-strong efficiency
    with respect to merger announcements.
  • Ball and Brown 1968 study the usefulness of
    the information content of annual reports.
  • With a primary focus on EPS, they find that
    security prices already reflect 85 - 90 of
    information contained in annual reports
  • Security prices show no consistent reactions to
    annual report releases.

19
Information Contained in Publications and Analyst
Reports
  • Davies and Canes 1978 considered information
    analysts sell to clients then publish in the
    "Heard on the Street" column in The Wall Street
    Journal. Prices seem to rise significantly after
    information is sold to clients, then even more
    when it is published in the Wall Street Journal.
  • Other studies have been performed on the ability
    to use information provided by Value Line
    Investment Surveys to generate profits.
  • More general studies on the value of analyst
    reports are somewhat mixed.
  • The earlier study by Cowles 1933 found no
    evidence of value in analyst reports.
  • Green 2005 found that short-term profit
    opportunities persist for two hours following the
    pre-market release of new recommendations.
  • Womack 1996 found that analysts' mean
    post-event drift averages 2.4 on buy
    recommendations and is short lived. However, sell
    recommendations result in average losses of 9.1
    that are longer lived. These price reactions seem
    more significant for small-capitalization firms
    than for larger capitalization firms. Also,
    consider that sell recommendations may be
    particularly costly to brokerage firms,
    potentially damaging investment banking
    relationships and curtailing access to
    information in the future. Clearly, buy
    recommendations far outnumber sell
    recommendations and an incorrect sell
    recommendation may be particularly damaging to an
    analyst's reputation.

20
Analyst Reports and Conflicts of Interest
  • Michaely and Womack 1999 attempted to discern
    whether analysts working for firms underwriting
    the IPOs provided buy recommendations that were
    superior to those of investment institutions not
    participating in the underwriting efforts.
  • Results suggest that if the analyst worked for an
    institution that did not participate in the
    underwriting, they were more likely to recommend
    a stock that had performed well in the recent
    past and would continue its strong performance.
  • However, if the analyst worked for a firm that
    participated in bringing the IPO to the market,
    it was more likely to have recorded poor
    performance both before and after the analyst's
    recommendation.
  • This evidence suggests that analysts working for
    investment banks are likely to attempt to prop up
    the prices of their underwritten securities with
    their recommendations.
  • In response to these apparently biased and
    unethical analyst recommendations, the Securities
    and Exchange Commission (SEC) announced in 2003
    the Global Research Analyst Settlement with 10 of
    the industrys largest investment banks. The
    settlement required the ten investment banks to
    pay 875 million in penalties and profit
    disgorgement, 80 million for investor education
    and 432.5 million to fund independent research.
    In addition to these payments, the investment
    banks were required to separate their investment
    banking and research departments and add certain
    disclosures to their research reports.
  • Nevertheless, Barber, Lehavy and Trueman 2007
    find that investment bank buy opinions still
    underperform those of independent analysts,
    despite their other recommendations outperforming
    those of their independent competitors.

21
DCF Analysis and Price Multiples
  • In their study of 51 highly leveraged
    transactions (management buyouts and leveraged
    recapitalizations), Kaplan and Ruback 1995
    found that DCF analysis provided better estimates
    of value than did price-based multiples.
  • Kaplan and Ruback found that between 95 and 97
    of firm value was explained by (as indicated by
    r-square) DCF and slightly less was explained by
    price-based multiples.
  • The price-based multiples did add useful
    information to the valuation process. 

22
Political Intelligence Units
  • Investors with money at stake have obvious
    incentives to access and quickly exploit
    information.
  • Many investors and institutions are able to
    access and exploit important information before
    it can be gathered and disseminated by the news
    agencies.
  • Consider the case of USG Corporation, whose
    shares increased by 5.4 over two days prior to
    November 16, 2005 when Senate Republican Majority
    Leader Bill Frist announced that there would be a
    full Senate vote on a bill to create a 140
    billion public trust for asbestos liability
    claims.
  • This fund would pay medical expenses and resolve
    lawsuits involving thousands of cancer victims
    who blamed USG, W.R.Grace and Crown for their
    illnesses.
  • Share prices of all these firms increased over
    the two days prior to November 16.
  • Returns for these firms over the 2-day period
    exceeded those of the market.
  • In addition, returns experienced by these
    particular firms far exceeded returns of their
    peer firms that were not involved in asbestos
    litigation.
  • On the date that the actual announcement was
    finally made, these three firms showed no
    substantial reaction.
  • The S.E.C. initiated an informal investigation
    to determine whether and how information might
    have been leaked to investors prior to its
    announcement.
  • While staff members for Senator Frist claim to
    have been careful not to leak information prior
    to the announcement, the bills authors, Senators
    Spector and Leahy had held extensive discussions
    with lobbyists.
  • Several law firms, including Sonnenschein Nath
    Rosenthal, LLP and DLA Piper have operated
    political intelligence units enabling their
    clients to obtain public policy information from
    lobbyists operating in Washington. These firms
    and political intelligence units include hedge
    funds as clients.
  • Several hedge funds holding substantial stakes in
    affected companies belonged to the Financial
    Institutions for Asbestos Reform, an industry
    advocacy group, giving them additional
    opportunities to access information provided by
    lobbyists.
  • While it is not clear whether any laws were have
    been broken, it does appear that hedge funds may
    have successfully gained an information edge in
    their trading.

23
Market Volatility
  • If security price changes are purely a function
    of information arrival, then security price
    volatility should be the same when markets are
    closed as when they are open.
  • For example, stock return variances should be
    three times as high over a weekend as over a
    24-hour period during weekdays.
  • However, Fama 1965 and French 1980 found
    that return variances were only around 20 higher
    during weekends.
  • On the other hand, one might argue that the
    arrival of new information over weekends is
    slower.
  • Another study by French and Roll 1986 found
    that agricultural commodity futures prices
    (orange juice concentrate) were substantially
    more volatile during trading days than during
    weekends.
  • Agricultural commodity futures prices are
    primarily a function of weather, news about which
    occurs over the weekend just as efficiently as
    during trading days.

24
Event Study Illustration
  • See Spreadsheet Illustration

25
F. Strong Form Efficiency and Insider Trading
  • Strong Form market efficiency tests are concerned
    with whether any information, publicly available
    or private can be used to generate abnormal
    returns.
  • We generally take it for granted that insiders
    are capable of generating higher than normal
    returns on their transactions.
  • There is even some evidence that insiders are
    able to generate abnormal returns on apparently
    legal transactions that are duly registered with
    the S.E.C.
  • Jaffee examined SEC insider transaction filings
    and determined that stock performance relative to
    the market after months when insider purchases
    exceed insider sales. When insiders sell, shares
    that they sold are outperformed by the market.
  • Why do insiders appear to outperform the market
    on their duly registered insider transactions?
    Are insiders trading on the basis of their
    private information or do they actually have
    superior trading ability?
  • Givoly and Palmon 1985 suggest that
    transactions generating these superior returns
    are not related to subsequent corporate events or
    announcements.
  • They found that insider superior returns were
    not explained by the published announcements.
  • This may suggest that these insiders may either
    simply have superior investing ability or may
    generate higher returns for themselves on the
    basis of information that is not later announced.
  • On the other hand, perhaps insiders are trading
    on the basis of insider information that is not
    subsequently released on a specific date.
  • Managers are not obliged to announce most types
    of inside information according to any particular
    schedule. In addition, many insiders participate
    in plans to regularly buy (without liability, as
    per S.E.C. Rule 10b5-1) or sell shares.
  • Managers can obtain 10b5-1 protection for trades
    if they create the plan at a time when they dont
    have non-public information and they announce
    their transactions schedule in advance.
  • For example, Kenneth Lay was said to have
    protected 100 million in his own wealth by
    selling shares of Enron stock through a 10b5-1
    plan.
  • In addition, insiders always have the right to
    abstain from trading on the basis of inside
    information. Thus, it is not illegal to not buy
    shares on the basis of inside information. How
    would investigators determine whether one
    declined to trade solely on the basis of inside
    information?
  • Jagolinzer 2005 found that insider trading
    within the 10b5-1 plans outperforms the market by
    5.6 over six-month periods.

26
G. Anomalous Efficiency and Prediction Markets
  • The Challenger Space Shuttle Disaster
  • On January 28, 1986, at 1138 AM Eastern Standard
    Time, the space shuttle Challenger was launched
    in Florida and exploded 74 seconds later ten
    miles above ground.
  • The stock market reacted within minutes of the
    event, with investors dumping shares the four
    major contractors contributing to building and
    launching the Challenger Rockwell International,
    builder of the shuttle and its main engines,
    Lockheed, manager of the ground support, Martin
    Marietta, manufacturer of the vessel's external
    fuel tank and Morton Thiokol, builder of the
    solid-fuel booster rocket.
  • Less than a half-hour after the disaster,
    Rockwells stock price had declined 6, Lockheed
    5, Martin Marietta 3, and Morton Thiokol had
    stopped trading because of the flood of sell
    orders.
  • By the end of trading for the day, the first
    three companies share prices closed down 3 from
    their open prices, representing a slight recovery
    from their initial reactions. However, Morton
    Thiokol stock resumed trading and continued to
    decline, finishing the day almost 12 down from
    its open price.
  • Many months after the disaster, Richard Feynman
    demonstrated that brittle O-rings caused the
    explosion. Morton had used the O-rings in its
    construction of the booster rockets, which failed
    and leaked explosive fumes when the launch
    temperatures were less than could be tolerated by
    the O-rings.
  • Yet, there were no announcements of such failures
    on the dates of the disaster or even within weeks
    of the explosion. Nonetheless, the market had
    reacted within minutes of the disaster as though
    Morton Thiokol would be held responsible.
  • In their study of this event, Maloney and
    Mulherin 2003 found no evidence that Morton
    Thiokol corporate officers and other insiders
    sold shares on the date of the disaster.

27
Prediction Markets
  • Price discovery is one of the most important
    functions of trading, particularly in more
    transparent markets such as the NYSE.
  • Consider the 1988 to 2008 presidential elections,
    where an increasing number of online betting
    markets offered tradable securities on election
    outcomes.
  • The most visible of these markets have been
    www.intrade.com and www.biz.uiowa.edu/iem/index.c
    fm
  • They trade contracts that pay 1 if a given
    candidate is elected, which prices less than 1.
    Thus, if a contract sells for .50, one might
    guess that the market believes that the candidate
    has a 50 chance of getting elected.
  • Security markets are excellent aggregators of
    information.
  • Security prices have been used for many years to
    estimate a variety of types of probability
    distributions.
  • Currency traders have used futures prices to
    estimate future currency exchange rates.
  • Commodity traders have used commodity futures
    prices to predict commodity prices.
  • Call options are used to estimate implied
    volatilities for underlying stocks.
  • Implied correlations between two underlying
    variables such as exchange rates using derivative
    contracts written on each underlying currency as
    well as contracts written on both currencies.
  • Prediction markets, even with respect to
    political wagering did not originate with Intrade
    and the Iowa Electronic Markets. The Curb
    Exchange (the precursor to the American Stock
    Exchange) operated wagering markets for
    presidential markets during much of the late 19th
    century.
  • Such wagering frequently involved large sums of
    money, with daily volume that often exceeded
    presidential campaign budgets.
  • More recent prediction markets have been quite
    successful, including the North American
    Derivatives Exchange (Nadex), a CFTC-registered
    futures exchange that got its start as
    HedgeStreet prediction market.

28
Science, the Government and Prediction Markets
  • Is the information provided by markets of use to
    decision-making entities in business and
    government?
  • Consider an example from the 1990s where, CERN,
    the European laboratory for particle physics,
    needed to estimate whether the probability of
    discovering the Higgs boson was sufficiently high
    to justify extending the operation of its
    collider. Traders at the Foresight Exchange Web
    site (http//www.ideosphere.com/) took positions
    on whether the Higgs boson would be discovered by
    2005, setting a contract price of 0.77 as of
    2001.
  • We close this section with a few rhetorical
    questions Should markets provide information
    aggregation services to the public? If so, at
    what cost to traders? Consider the following
    excerpt from Looney 2003 
  • The Defense Advanced Research Projects Agency
    (DARPA) was born in the uncertain days after the
    Soviets launched Sputnik in 1958. Its mission was
    to become an engine of technological change that
    would bridge the gap between fundamental
    discoveries and their military use (Bray, 2003).
    Over the last five decades, the Agency has
    efficiently gone about its business in relative
    obscurity, in many cases not getting as much
    credit as it deserved. The Agency first developed
    the model for the internet as well as stealth
    technology. More recently, DARPA innovations have
    spanned a wide array of technologies. To name a
    couple computers that correct a user's mistakes
    or fix themselves when they malfunction and new
    stimulants to keep soldiers awake and alert for
    seven consecutive days
  • Then, in late July, the Agency backed off a plan
    to set up a kind of futures market (Policy
    Analysis Market or PAM) that would allow
    investors to earn profits by betting on the
    likelihood of such events as regime changes in
    the Middle East. Critics, mainly politicians and
    op-ed writers, attacked the futures project on
    the grounds that it was unethical and in bad
    taste to accept wagers on the fate of foreign
    leaders and the likelihood of terrorist attacks.
    The project was canceled a day after it was
    announced. Its head, retired Admiral John
    Poindexter, has resigned.
  • Poindexters resignation followed the creation of
    a contract by Tradesports.com that would pay 100
    if he resigned.
  • Can markets trading terrorism-based contracts aid
    in the prediction of terrorism strikes and
    dealing with the effects of such strikes? If so,
    should such contracts be traded?

29
H. Epilogue
  • In his presidential address to the American
    Finance Association, Richard Roll 1988
    discussed the ability of academics to explain
    financial phenomena
  • The maturity of a science is often gauged by its
    success in predicting important phenomena.
    Astronomy, the oldest science, is able to predict
    the positions of planets and the reappearance of
    comets with a high degree of accuracy... The
    immaturity of our science finance is
    illustrated by the conspicuous lack of predictive
    content about some of its most intensely
    interesting phenomena, particularly changes in
    asset prices. General stock price movements are
    notoriously unpredictable and financial
    economists have even developed a coherent theory
    (the theory of efficient markets) to explain why
    they should be unpredictable.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com