Introduction%20to%20Macroeconomics%20%20MSc%20Induction%20%20Simon%20Hayley%20%20Simon.Hayley.1@city.ac.uk - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

Introduction%20to%20Macroeconomics%20%20MSc%20Induction%20%20Simon%20Hayley%20%20Simon.Hayley.1@city.ac.uk

Description:

Introduction to Macroeconomics MSc Induction Simon Hayley Simon.Hayley.1_at_city.ac.uk – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:324
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 72
Provided by: de444
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Introduction%20to%20Macroeconomics%20%20MSc%20Induction%20%20Simon%20Hayley%20%20Simon.Hayley.1@city.ac.uk


1
Introduction to Macroeconomics MSc
InductionSimon HayleySimon.Hayley.1_at_city.ac
.uk
2
  • What is Macroeconomics?
  • Macroeconomics looks at the economy as a whole.
    It studies aggregate effects, such as
  • Business cycles
  • Living standards (real incomes)
  • Inflation
  • Unemployment
  • The balance of payments.
  • It also asks how governments can use their
    monetary and fiscal policy instruments to help
    stabilise the economy.

3
  • Key Issues
  • Why analyse macroeconomics?
  • Measuring economic activity
  • Building a macroeconomic model
  • Macroeconomic problems and policy solutions

4
(No Transcript)
5
(No Transcript)
6
(No Transcript)
7
(No Transcript)
8
(No Transcript)
9
UK Inflation ( per annum)
10
  • How Can We Measure National Output?
  • Key concepts
  • Gross domestic product (GDP)
  • Gross national income (GNI - used to be called
    GNP)
  • in a closed economy GDP GNI
  • Aggregate supply and demand
  • Controlling inflation and unemployment
  • Fiscal and monetary policy

11
Avoiding Double Counting
  • To avoid double counting, when measuring national
    output via spending on goods, the goods that
    count as part of the economys output are called
    final goods all others are called intermediate
    goods.
  • Each firms contribution to total output is equal
    to its value added the gross value of the firms
    output minus the value of all intermediate goods
    and services (the outputs of other firms) that it
    uses.
  • The sum of all the values added produced in an
    economy is called gross value added at basic
    prices (the prices received by producers net of
    taxes on products, plus subsidies).

12
Three Routes to GDP
  • All output is owned by someone, and all output is
    bought by someone. Thus gross domestic product,
    GDP can be calculated in three different ways
  • As the sum of value added by all producers of
    both intermediate and final goods
  • As the income claims generated by the total
    production of goods and services
  • As the expenditure needed to purchase all final
    goods and services produced during the period.
  • These three methods reach the same total, so long
    as we add taxes on products minus subsidies to
    the first two in order to measure GDP at market
    prices.

13
The Circular Flow of Income, Output, and
Expenditure
Domestic households
Payments
services
for
factor
Saving
goods
Financial System
for
and
Investment
Abroad
paid
services
Government
Income
Total final spending
Total income generated
Domestic producers
14
An Example
  • Suppose an economy has two firms
  • Firm A mines ore it sell 300 worth to firm B,
    pays 200 to its workers, and makes 100 profit.
  • Firm B makes consumer goods it buys materials
    for 300 from firm A, pays 300 to its workers,
    sells it output for 800 and makes profit of
    200.
  • What is GDP?

15
  • Value of final goods sold 800
  • Value added of two firms Firm A 300, Firm B
    500 so total 800
  • Sum of incomes Wages 200 300 profits
    100 200 so total 800

16
Types of Final Expenditure
  • From the expenditure side of the national
    accounts
  • GDP C I G X - M.
  • C is private consumption expenditures.
  • I is investment in fixed capital including
    residential construction, inventories, and
    valuables.
  • G is government consumption.
  • (X -M) represents net exports, or exports minus
    imports it will be negative if imports exceed
    exports.also referred to as NX

17
Gross value added at current basic prices, by
sector, UK, 2005
Sector million of GDP
Agriculture, hunting, forestry and fisheries 10,241 0.8
Mining and quarrying 25,458 2.1
Manufacturing 148,097 12.2
Electricity, gas and water supply 24,953 2.0
Construction 65,923 5.4
Wholesale and retail trade 132,113 10.8
Hotels and restaurants 33,730 2.8
Transport and communications 81,059 6.6
Financial intermediation and real estate 266,485 21.8
Public administration and defence 54,935 4.5
Education 62,316 5.1
Health and social work 81,518 6.7
Other services 58,807 4.8
Gross value added at current basic prices Plus adjustment to current basic prices (taxes minus subsidies on products) 1,086,859 137,856 11.3
GDP at market prices 1,224,715 100
18
Expenditure-based GDP and its components, UK,
2005
Expenditure Categories million of GDP
Individual consumption Household final consumption 760,777 62
Final consumption of non-profit institutions serving households 30,525 2.5
Individual government final consumption 165,655 13.5
Total actual individual consumption 956,957 78.1
Collective government final consumption 101,875 8.3
Total final consumption 1,058,832 86.5
Gross fixed capital formation 205,843 16.8
Change in inventories 3,721 0.3
Acquisition less disposals of valuables -337 0
Total gross capital formation 209,187 17.1
Exports of goods and services 322,298 26.3
Less imports of goods and services -366,540 -29.9
External balance of goods and services (net exports) -44,242 -3.6
Statistical discrepancy Gross domestic product at market prices (money GDP) 938 1,224,715 100

19
GDP and GNI by Income type 2005
Income type million of GDP
Operating surplus, gross (profits) 312,026 25.5
Mixed incomes 76,112 6.2
Compensation of employees 684,618 55.9
Taxes on production and imports 162,267 13.2
Less subsidies -9,391 -0.8
Statistical discrepancy -917 0.0
GDP at market prices 1,224,715 100
Employees compensation Receipts from rest of world 1,211
Less payment to rest of world Total -1,137 74
Less taxes on production paid to rest of world Plus subsidies received from rest of world -4,243
Other subsidies on production 3,216
Property and entrepreneurial income Receipts from rest of world 185,826
Less payments to rest of world Total -156,029 29,797
Gross national income (GNI) at market prices 1,253,561
20
  • Real GDP is calculated to reflect changes in real
    volumes of output and real income. Nominal GDP
    reflects changes in both prices and quantities.
  • Thus growth in nominal GDP can be split into real
    GDP growth plus inflation.
  • Gross means that no allowance has been made for
    depreciation.
  • Personal disposable income is the amount actually
    available for individuals to spend or to save
    (after taxes).

21
Building a Macro Model
  • Assumptions used in building a macro model
  • Key relationships
  • consumption
  • investment
  • The determination of GDP
  • The multiplier
  • The big idea the Keynesian revolution

22
Key Assumptions
  • Economy assumed to be one big industry
  • Final spending is demand for output of this one
    industry
  • Government purchases, consumption, investment and
    exports are all demands for the same output.

Output of goods
Labour
Consumer spending
Investment
Government purchases
Exports- imports
23
More Assumptions
  • Temporary assumptions
  • Prices dont change, so all changes are in real
    (volume) terms
  • There is excess capacity in production so output
    is demand determined
  • Closed economy with no government
  • Focus first on
  • GDP C I G (X-M)
  • Use symbol Y for GDP
  • So first explain GDP using determinants of C and
    I.
  • C is an endogenous variable determined within the
    model
  • I is an exogenous variable determined outside the
    model

24
The Circular Flow of Income, Output, and
Expenditure
Domestic households
Payments
services
for
factor
Saving
goods
Financial System
for
and
Investment
Abroad
paid
services
Government
Income
Total final spending
Total income generated
Domestic producers
25
Consumption and Saving
  • If personal disposable income rises, households
    spend some of the increase and save the rest.
    This is measured by the marginal propensity to
    consume MPC and the marginal propensity to save
    MPS, which are both positive and sum to one.
  • Relation between consumption and income might be
  • C a bY
  • a is referred to as autonomous consumption.
    It is the amount that consumers spend when income
    is zero.
  • b is the marginal propensity to consume.
  • This implies a relation for saving
  • S -a (1-b)Y

26
(No Transcript)
27
Consumption and Saving Relationships empirical
example
  • C 100 0.8Y
  • where C is consumer spending in a period, Y is
    personal disposable income (which in absence of
    taxes and retained profit GDP). Autonomous C
    100 Marginal propensity to consume 0.8.
  • S -100 0.2Y
  • Marginal propensity to save 0.2

28
Consumption and Saving Schedules Million
Disposable Income
Desired consumption
Desired saving
0
100
-100
100
180
-80
400
420
-20
500
500
0
1000
900
100
1500
1300
200
1750
1500
250
2000
1700
300
3000
2500
500
4000
3300
700
29
The Consumption and Saving Functions
450
2000
C
1500
500
S
1000
Desired Consumption Expenditure
250
500
0
Desired saving
-100
450
-500
500
1000
1500
2000
500
1000
1500
2000
Real Disposable Income
Real Disposable Income
(i). Consumption Function million
(ii). Saving Function million
30
Investment
  • Here we treat investment as an exogenous
    variable, that is, it is determined outside the
    model.
  • Later we can make investment depend on the
    interest rate.
  • In general investment will depend on expectations
    of future demand growth as well as interest
    rates.
  • For our numerical example investment is constant
    at 250.

31
The Aggregate Expenditure Function in a Closed
Economy With No Government Million
GDP National Income Y
Desired investment expenditure I 250
Desired aggregate expenditure AE C I
Desired consumption expenditure C 100 0.8Y
100
250
180
430
400
250
420
670
500
250
500
750
1000
250
900
1150
1500
250
1300
1550
250
1500
1750
1750
2000
250
1700
1950
3000
250
2500
2750
4000
250
3300
3550
32
Equilibrium GDP
  • At the equilibrium level of GDP, purchasers wish
    to buy exactly the amount of national output that
    is being produced.
  • At GDP above equilibrium, desired expenditure
    falls short of national output, and output will
    sooner or later be curtailed.
  • At GDP below equilibrium, desired expenditure
    exceeds national output, and output will sooner
    or later be increased.
  • In a closed economy with no government, desired
    saving equals desired investment at equilibrium
    GDP.
  • Equilibrium GDP is represented graphically by the
    point at which the aggregate expenditure curve
    cuts the 450 line, that is, where total desired
    expenditure equals total output.
  • This is the same level of GDP at which the saving
    function intersects the investment function.

33
The Determination of Equilibrium GDP
GDP National Income Y
Desired aggregate expenditure AE C I
100
430
Shortage of goods. Pressure on Y to rise
400
670
500
750
1000
1150
1500
1550
1750
Equilibrium Y
1750
2000
1950
3000
2750
Surplus production. Pressure on Y to fall
4000
3550

34
Equilibrium GDP
3000
450 AE Y
S
500
E0
2000
Desired aggregate expenditure (m)
I
250
Desired saving (m)
0
1000
-100
350
-500
450
0
Y0
2000
Y0
1000
3000
3000
2000
1000
Real National Income GDP m
Real National Income GDP m
ii. Saving FunctionS I
i. An Aggregate Expenditure FunctionAE Y
35
How Does the Equilibrium Come About?
  • For GDP to remain unchanged injections of
    spending and leakages must be just equal
    otherwise GDP would be changing
  • Imagine a bath with the tap running and no plug.
    For the water level to be stable the water
    flowing in and the water flowing out must be the
    same.

36
The Model Solution
  • The model is
  • Y C I
  • C a bY
  • Solve for Y by substituting for C in first
    equation
  • Y a bY I
  • so Y - bY a I
  • or Y (a I)/(1-b)
  • Numerical example C 100 0.8Y I 250
  • So Y 100 0.8Y 250
  • Or Y (100 250)/ (1- 0.8)
  • 350 x 5
  • 1750

37
Changes in GDP
  • Equilibrium GDP is increased by a rise in
    exogenous spending or injections or a fall in
    withdrawals.
  • Equilibrium GDP is decreased by a fall in
    injections or a rise in withdrawals.
  • The magnitude of the effect on GDP of shifts in
    autonomous expenditure is given by the
    multiplier. It is defined as K ?Y/?A, where ?A
    is the change in autonomous or exogenous
    expenditure.
  • It is equal to 1/(1 - z), where z is the marginal
    propensity to consume. Thus the larger z is, the
    larger is the multiplier. In the absence of taxes
    and foreign trade the multiplier is
  • 1/(1-b) where b is the marginal propensity to
    consume
  • If b 0.8 then the multiplier 5.

38
The Simple Multiplier
AE Y
AE0
Desired Expenditure
e0
E0
450
0
Y0
Real National Income GDP
39
The Simple Multiplier
AE Y
AE1
E1
e1
a
e1
AE0
?A
Desired Expenditure
e0
E0
?Y
450
0
Y0
Real National Income GDP
Y1
40
New solution when I rises from 250 to 350
  • Old level of GDP was 1750
  • Y C I
  • Y 100 0.8Y 350
  • Y - 0.8Y 450
  • Y 450 x 5
  • Y 2250
  • Increase in Y is change in I times the multiplier
  • Change in I is 100 and multiplier is 5
  • So change in Y is 500.
  • At new level of GDP S -100 (.2 x 2250)
  • 350

41
The Multiplier Intuition
  • If there is an increase of exogenous spending of
    100, this generates 100 of extra income and 80
    gets spent.
  • The 80 generates extra income of 80 and 0.8 of
    this gets spent---creating 64 of extra income.
    0.8 of this gets spent generating 51.20 of extra
    income.
  • Total income generated is
  • 100 80 64 51.2 40.96 32.768
    26.21 20.97 16.78 13.43 10.74 8.59
    6.87 5.5 4.4 3.52 2.82 2.25
    1.8 1.44 1.15 0.92 0.74 0.59
    0.47 0.38 0.3 0.24 0.19 0.15
    0.12 0.1 0.08 0.064
  • This sum converges to 500.

42
The Multiplier a Numerical Example
500
400
Cumulative spending total million
300
200
100
2
7
0
4
6
3
1
9
10
15
20
8
5
Spending round
43
Implications of the Multiplier
  • The multiplier comes about because consumer
    spending is a function of household incomes, but
    household incomes are themselves affected by
    consumer spending! (the circular flow of income)
  • The result is that a small change in one part of
    our model (eg. I, G, or the MPC) can have a large
    impact on GDP by the time the economy has reached
    a new equilibrium.

44
The Classical View of Unemployment
  • Economists used to regard the labour market as
    just like any other market. If there was an
    excess supply of labour, this must mean that the
    price (wages) is too high.
  • But this theory left economists unable to come up
    with a satisfactory explanation of the great
    depression...
  • ...let alone come up with any solutions!

45
The Classical View of Unemployment
S
D
Z
Z
Y
Y
X
X
Wages
W
W
V
V
U
U
Employment
46
The Big Idea Keynesian Revolution
  • Unemployment is mainly determined by aggregate
    spending. Thus the economy can get stuck in a
    vicious circle (low aggregate spending gt low GDP
    gt high unemployment gt low aggregate spending).
  • Cutting wages would make matters worse by further
    reducing consumer demand!
  • One solution is for government to use its own
    spending (and tax changes) to boost demand. The
    budget then became a tool for managing the
    economy (discretionary fiscal policy).

47
The Circular Flow of Income, Output, and
Expenditure
Domestic households
Imports
Payments
services
for
factor
Saving
goods
Financial System
for
and
Investment
Abroad
paid
services
Government
Taxes
Spending on current production
income
Exports
After-tax
Total
Total income generated
Domestic producers
48
The Keynesian Revolution
AE Y
AE0
Desired Expenditure
e0
E0
450
0
Y0
Real National Income GDP
Y
49
Effect on GDP of change in exogenous spending
AE Y
AE1
E1
e1
a
e1
AE0
?A
Desired Expenditure
e0
E0
?Y
450
0
Y0
Real National Income GDP
Y1
50
Aggregate Demand and Supply
  • So far we have assumed that GDP is determined by
    demand. This is the case if there is excess
    capacity in the economy (no supply-side
    constraints).
  • Our model also has no role for prices, so it
    cannot explain inflation. So next we incorporate
    the price level and derive the aggregate demand
    curve.
  • We then add the aggregate supply curve, which
    enables us to determine both real GDP and the
    price level.

51
Aggregate Demand
  • What happens to AE as we change the price level?
  • A fall in the price level shifts the AE curve
    upwards
  • A rise in the price level shifts the AE curve
    downwards.
  • The reasons
  • A rise in the price level lowers exports because
    it raises the relative price of domestic goods
  • A rise in the price level lowers private
    consumption spending because it decreases the
    real value of consumers wealth.
  • Both of these changes lower equilibrium GDP and
    cause the aggregate demand curve to have a
    negative slope.
  • The AD curve plots the equilibrium level of GDP
    that corresponds to each possible price level. A
    change in equilibrium GDP following a change in
    the price level is shown by a movement along the
    AD curve.

52
The AD Curve and the AE Curve
AE Y
AE0
E0
AE1
E1
AE2
Desired Expenditure
E2
45o
0
Real National Income GDP
Y2
Y1
Y0
i. Aggregate expenditure
E2
P2
Price Level
E1
P1
E0
P0
AD
Real National Income (GDP)
Y2
Y1
Y0
0
ii. Aggregate Demand
53
AD Meaning and Shifts
  • The AD curve is drawn for given values of all
    exogenous expenditures and other parameters
  • Each point on AD shows, for each P, the level of
    real GDP that is consistent with
  • desired spending actual output
    (as determined by spending decisions)
  • injections withdrawals
  • When an exogenous variable changes, the AD curve
    shifts at each price level by the shift in
    spending times the multiplier.

54
Shifts in Aggregate Demand
  • The AD curve shifts when any element of exogenous
    expenditure changes.
  • The multiplier times the shift in exogenous
    spending measures the magnitude of the shift.
  • An increase in a, G, I, X, or a fall in T shift
    AD to the right.
  • A fall in a, G, I, X, or a rise in T shift AD to
    the left.

55
The Simple Multiplier and Shifts in the AD Curve
AE Y
AE1
E1
AE0
E0
Desired Expenditure
?A
i. Aggregate Expenditure
45o
Real GDP
0
Y1
Y0
Price Level
E0
E1
P0
?Y
AD1
AD0
ii. Aggregate Demand
Y0
Real GDP
Y1
0
56
Aggregate Supply
  • The short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve is
    drawn for given input prices, given technology
    and fixed capital stock.
  • It is positively sloped because unit costs rise
    with increasing output and because rising product
    prices make it profitable to increase output.
  • An increase in productivity or a decrease in
    input prices shifts the SRAS curve to the right.
  • A decrease in productivity or an increase in
    input prices shifts the SRAS curve to the left.

57
A Short-run Aggregate Supply Curve
SRAS
Price level
P1
P0
Y0
Y1
Real GDP
58
Macroeconomic Equilibrium
  • Macroeconomic equilibrium is where the AD and
    SRAS curves intersect.
  • Shifts in the AD and SRAS curves, called
    aggregate demand shocks and aggregate supply
    shocks, change the equilibrium values of real GDP
    and the price level.
  • When the SRAS curve is positively sloped, an
    aggregate demand shock causes the price level and
    real GDP to move in the same direction, the
    division between these effects depending on the
    shape of the SRAS curve.
  • The main effect is on real GDP when the SRAS
    curve is flat and on the price level when it is
    steep.

59
Macroeconomic Equilibrium
AD
SRAS
Price Level
E0
P0
Y0
0
Real GDP
60
Supply Shocks
  • An aggregate supply shock moves equilibrium real
    GDP along the AD curve, causing the price level
    and output to move in opposite directions.
  • A leftward shift in the SRAS curve causes
    stagflation rising prices and falling output.
  • A rightward shift causes an increase in real GDP
    and a fall in the price level.
  • The division of the effects of a shift in SRAS
    between a change in real GDP and a change in the
    price level depends on the shape of the AD curve.

61
Aggregate Supply Shift
AD
SRAS
Price Level
E0
P0
P1
Y0
0
Y1
Real GDP
62
  • Starting from AD SRAS there can be two types of
    shock
  • Aggregate demand shock involves a change in some
    exogenous spending category a, I, G (or T) and
    X.
  • An increase in a, I, G, or X shifts AD left or
    right by size of change times the multiplier.
  • Price level then changes and makes multiplier
    smaller, but P and Y respond to AD shock in same
    direction.
  • When there is an aggregate supply shock, P and Y
    move in opposite directions.
  • There are some special cases.

63
Keynesian SRAS Curve
AD
Price Level
SRAS
E0
P0
Y0
0
Real GDP
64
Classical or Monetarist SRAS
AD
SRAS
Price Level
P0
Y0
0
Real GDP
65
General Case
AD
SRAS
Price Level
P0
Y0
0
Real GDP
66
Lessons of the 1970s and 1980s
  • Inflation is persistent
  • Expected inflation rises, so workers demand
    higher wage increases (wage-price spiral).
  • If inflation is high, employees demand high wage
    rises. Firms then raise prices to maintain
    margins.
  • Inflation expectations are important.
  • Unemployment is persistent
  • The long-term unemployed become less attractive
    to employers.
  • Hence wage inflation tends to increase even when
    unemployment relatively high.

67
What About The Money Supply?
  • Monetarists argued that inflation is always and
    everywhere a monetary phenomenon, so if you can
    control the money supply, you can control
    inflation.
  • But although money is involved in every
    transaction, it is seldom the cause of the
    transaction. The relationship between money and
    inflation is not stable, so it is not a reliable
    means of controlling inflation.
  • Furthermore, in a modern economy, the money
    supply (largely in the form of bank accounts) is
    hard to control, or even measure.

68
Evolution of macro-economic policymaking
  • Classical (1776 - 1930s)
  • Free markets with no government interference
  • Keynesian (1930s 1970s)
  • Discretionary demand management used to regulate
    economy
  • Monetarist (1970s 1980s)
  • Control money supply to control inflation
  • Supply-side measures to help markets move to
    equilibrium
  • Markets should then clear to achieve full
    employment
  • Instead the economy entered deep recession in
    early 1980s. Monetarist theory discredited.
  • Current pragmatic system
  • Inflation expectations are important, so
    objectives must be clear and credible
  • Independent central bank avoids political motives

69
Stabilisation Policies
  • Fiscal policy
  • Budget deficit boosts demand
  • But cyclical adjustment is needed to be sure
  • Substantial lags obtaining data, implementation
    and impact of policy shift. Hence net effect
    could be destabilising.
  • Monetary policy
  • Interest rates affect investment and consumer
    spending
  • Governments now generally set fiscal policy and
    leave the central bank to use monetary policy to
    stabilise the economy.

70
Macroeconomics summary
  • Measuring GDP
  • Value added
  • Income
  • Expenditure
  • Circular flow of income
  • Keynesianism overthrows classical view of
    unemployment
  • Model building
  • Multiplier
  • Supply and demand shocks
  • Different view of aggregate supply
  • Macroeconomic policy
  • Classical
  • Keynesianism
  • Monetarism
  • Pragmatic view. Independent central banks

71
Reading
  • Lipsey Chrystal Economics Eleventh Edition,
    Oxford University Press, 2007.
  • This is the source of most of the material
    presented in these lectures.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com