Optimization - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 25
About This Presentation
Title:

Optimization

Description:

How does the value of an optimization problem change to changes in the severity ... 2: Maximum value and comparative statics. Now we have max f(x,c) subject to g(x,c) ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:67
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 26
Provided by: ster8
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Optimization


1
Optimization
  • Lecture 7
  • The Maximum Value Function

2
Maximum value function
  • How does the value of an optimization problem
    change to changes in the severity of the
    constraints?
  • Idem for parameters in the objective function.
  • Idem for the addition of several new constraints
    important application envelope theorem

3
1 Sensitivity in standard constrained
optimization
  • Max f(x) subject to g(x)?b, where x, g and b are
    vectors and ?j is the Lagrange multiplier
    associated with the jth restriction
  • How does the value of the problem depend on the
    parameters?
  • Suppose we have a more general set A where a is
    an element of and is free to range for all values
    of b g(x)?b
  • We have V(a) as the value of the problem it is
    the maximum value function for V(b)

4
Maximum value functions
  • V(a) is non-decreasing in each aj
  • If f is concave and each gj is convex, V(a) is
    concave (and can so easily be optimized)
  • Handy result. Let ? be the Lagrange multipliers.
    The j-th ? is ?jVj(b) dV/daj (at ab), so we
    can use the maximum value function and substitute
    for b!

5
Example exercise 6.1.5
  • Max x2ln(x1)
  • Subject to p1x1p2x2 m x2?a and mltp2
  • Lagrangean L x2ln(x1)-?1(p1x1p2x2-m)?2(x2a)
  • For x1 1/x1-?1p1 0
  • For x2 1- ?1p2 ?2 0
  • ?2?0, x2?-a and ?2(x2a) 0

6
Example exercise 6.1.5
  • Suppose x2gt-a in that case ?2 0, ?1 1/p2 and
    x1 p2/p1. Using the budget constraint x2
    (m-p2)/p2. This holds if (m-p2)/p2gt-a. or
    agt(p2-m)/p2. We get V(m,a)(m-p2)/p2ln(p2/p1)
  • If x2 -a then x1 (map2)/p1 , so we get
    V(m,a) -aln(map2)/p1
  • Now we can use the theorem to see that
    ?1 V1(m,0) 1/m and ?2 V2(m,0) 0

7
2 Maximum value and comparative statics
  • Now we have max f(x,c) subject to g(x,c)?0
  • Lagrangean L(?,x) f(x,c)- ?g(x,c)
  • Let xx(c) be the solution. The maximum value
    function is V(c) f x(c),c
  • V(c) is concave if f is concave and g is convex
    in general
  • For g(x) 0 we get ?V/?cj ?f/?cj

8
Exercise 6.2.6
  • Max x1ax2b st p1x1p2x2 m
  • Lagrangean L x1ax2b- ?(p1x1-p2x2-m)
  • For x1 ax1a-1x2b- ?p1 0
  • For x2 bx1ax2b-1- ?p2 0
  • With the budget constraint we get x1 (a/(ab))
    m/p1 and x2 (b/(ab))m/p2
  • So V (a/p1)a (b/p2)b m/(ab)ab
  • Next we can analyze the properties of V

9
3 Addition of new constraints
  • Suppose we have a standard problem max
    f(x,c) st g(x,c)?0 and we want to add more
    constraints in g. How does this affect the
    optimum?
  • Let V(c) be the value function. x x(c0) is the
    optimum. If constraints are added that satisfy
    this optimum condition, the V(c) will remain the
    same in the optimum

10
Example
V
V1
V2
c
c0
11
Envelope property
  • The more restricted V(c)s are more concave (a
    greater curvature at c0) but the same tangent at
    c0.
  • This problem is said to have the envelope
    property. This property has various handy
    consequences
  • Interesting is the case where we max f(x,c) st
    g(x,c)?0 and keep some of the xi fixed

12
What do we learn from this?
  • Suppose we are in the optimum. We can maximize
    either V(c) or V(c) as long as c c0! This is
    the envelope theorem
  • This can be handy in static and dynamic
    optimization
  • So adding constraints that satisfy the optimum
    conditions do not change the optimum solution but
    does change the maximum value function

13
History of the envelope theorem
  • Early 1930s Jacob Viner analyzes the behaviour
    of firms in the short and long run. In the short
    run capital is fixed, while labour variable
  • Viner posited a series of short-run cost curves,
    whose minimum points first fall and then rise. If
    both production factors were variable, long-run
    average cost would always be less than or equal
    to the corresponding short-run costs the envelope

14
Short- and long-run costs
C(y)
SRAC1
LRAC
SRAC2
y
15
The Puzzle
  • It is impossible to draw an envelope that passes
    the minimum value of the short-run cost curves
  • The tangency to the short-run curves and the
    envelope is identical for a fixed capital stock
    so costs are falling at the same rate no matter
    whether we look at the short or long run

16
Envelope property example
  • Suppose we have a firm that minimizes costs rKwL
    subject to a technology QF(K,L). Suppose capital
    is fixed in the short run KK0. K0 is optimal if
    QQ0. We can then simply minimize over L (see the
    plot hereafter).

17
Envelope Theorem
V
VrKwL
V(KK1)
V(KK0)
Q
18
The envelope theorem
  • Let f(x,c) and gj(x,c) be real-valued
    continuously differential functions on Rn1
  • Choose x for a given c so as to
  • Max f(x,c) subject to gj(x,c)?0, x ?0,
    j 2,,m

19
Envelope theorem (2)
  • fx(x,c)?gx(x,c)?0 with
    fx(x,c) ?gx(x,c).x 0
  • ?g(x,c) 0, g(x,c)?0
  • x ? 0 and ? ? 0
  • How does c affect x and ? ?
  • Suppose we have an interior solution
    fx(x,c)?gx(x,c) 0, and g(x,c) 0

20
Maximum value function
  • Define F(c) f x(c),c MVF
  • B(c) f x(c),c?(c).gx(c),c
  • C(x, ?, c) f(x,c) ?.g(x,c) is the Lagrangean
  • If F and B are continuously differentiable, all
    partial derivatives of F(c), B(c),
    C(x, ?, c) with respect to c are identical across
    the various functions

21
Example simple static model
  • The firm maximizes profits P(p,w)
    max pf(x)-wx with respect to x
  • Let x be the optimal choice
  • The envelope theorem says that the derivative of
    P with respect to p is simply f(x) evaluated at x
    x, so f(x(p,w))
  • For w it is ?P/?w -x(p,w)

22
Example consumer theory
  • Max u(x) st p.x?m. Let x(p,m) be the optimum and
    the maximum value function V(p,m) ux(p,m) (
    indirect utility function)
  • We can rewrite the problem into min p.x st u(x)?u
    with the minimum value function
    Ep,u p.x(p,u) expenditure function
  • Duality implies Vp,E(p,u) u and Ep,V(p,m)
    m holds for all m and u

23
Example consumer theory (2)
  • xk(p,u)?E/?pk Hicksian demand for good k is
    the slope in the pk-direction of the expenditure
    function Shephards lemma!
  • ?V/?m ? and ?E/?u ? and ? 1/?
  • ?V/?pk - ? xk(p,m)
  • xk(p,m) - (?V/?pk)/(?V/?m) Roys identity

24
Applications of the envelope theorem
  • Suppose we have a consumer who optimizes utility
    Ut ?st??s-t u(Cs) subject to Bs1
    (1r)BsYs-Cs, s?t, and a so-called non-Ponzi
    game condition
  • Some intertemporal adding up gives Wt1
    (1r)(Wt-St)
  • We formulate a value function
  • J(Wt) max u(Ct)?J(Wt1)

25
Application (2)
  • FOC u(Ct) (1r) ?J(Wt1)
  • Now we use the envelope theorem to say something
    more on the marginal utility of wealth. An
    increment to wealth on any date has the same
    effect on lifetime utility regardless of the use
    wealth is put
  • So we can write J(W) u(C )which leads to the
    famous Euler equation u(Ct) (1r) ?u(Ct1)
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com