Applied and Theoretical Issues in Income Redistribution - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 32
About This Presentation
Title:

Applied and Theoretical Issues in Income Redistribution

Description:

A reminder of the basic optimal (labor) income redistribution model (OIRM) ... Reminder of the OIRM (cont'd) 3) The case of quasi-linear preferences (Diamond, ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:43
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 33
Provided by: Fbourg
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Applied and Theoretical Issues in Income Redistribution


1
Applied and Theoretical Issues in Income
Redistribution
  • Mallorca summer course (June 2001)
  • F. Bourguignon

2
II . Optimal income redistribution in practice
  • A reminder of the basic optimal (labor) income
    redistribution model (OIRM)
  • Trying to implement empirically the OIRM
  • Adequacy of the OIRM for redistribution analysis
    in developed and developing countries

3
A) A reminder of the basic optimal (labor) income
redistribution model (OIRM)
  • Original model due to Mirrlees (1971). More
    accessible statements may be found in various
    texts (Atkinson-Stiglitz, Stiglitz, Tuomala,
    Myles, )
  • Purpose here is to recall the structure of the
    model, the first order conditions and their
    interpretation, and then to reflect on the ways
    to apply them to actual data, something which was
    not done until recently, most of the applied OIRM
    literature bearing on hypothetical distributions.

4
Reminder of the OIRM (cont'd)
  • Statement of the model
  • Individuals in population are heterogeneous with
    respect to their productivity, w.
  • Redistribution authority does not observe w but
    only labor income w.L.
  • But it knows what are the (identical) individual
    preferences, U(c, L), over consumption,c and
    labor, L.
  • It also knows the statistical distribution of w
    in the population. f() is the corresponding
    density function.

5
Reminder of the OIRM (cont'd)
6
Reminder of the OIRM (cont'd)
  • 2) Indications on the solution of the general
    model
  • Original variables and functions
  • T(wL), Lw, T(), y wL - T(wL), V(w, T( )
    )
  • New variables z wL, c z T(z), u U(c,
    w/w)
  • Question what is the optimal correspondence
    between w and (z, c, u), or the optimal functions
    z(w), c(w), u(w) ?
  • Redistribution function T( ) may then be
    recovered from the implied relationship between c
    and z.

7
Reminder of the OIRM (cont'd)
  • This leads to the optimal control problem (state
    variable u, control variables c, z)

8
Reminder of the OIRM (cont'd)
  • Preceding problem has a solution as long as the
    'agent monotonicity' property holds.
  • This property requires that optimal consumption
    is an increasing function of productivity, w, in
    the absence of taxation. In other words,
    consumption gives a truthful information on
    (unobserved) productivity.
  • Sufficient that consumption is not an inferior
    good for the preceding property to be satisfied.

9
Reminder of the OIRM (cont'd)
  • Some general properties of the optimal
    redistribution schedule and the need for
    simulation
  • Optimal T' lies between 0 and 1
  • T' 0 at the lowest and highest level of
    productivity but this may of little practical
    relevance
  • It may be optimal to have the agents with the
    lowest productivity not working
  • Pre-tax income and consumption are increasing
    functions of productivity

10
Reminder of the OIRM (cont'd)
  • Properties obtained by numerical simulation
  • G(u) u1- ?/(1-??) with the limit Rawlsian case
    of ????
  • U(y , L) CES with varying substitution
    elasticities
  • f( ) Pareto, Log-normal
  • marginal tax rates my be declining, increasing or
    constant w.r.t. productivity
  • High marginal tax rates do not necessarily
    require a Rawlsian social welfare function
  • Intermediate values for ? and for the CES
    elasticity of substitution lead to approximately
    constant T' () linear redistribution system.

11
Reminder of the OIRM (cont'd)
  • 3) The case of quasi-linear preferences (Diamond,
    Atkinson, ..)
  • leading to optimal tax rates solution of
  • Where t(w) marginal tax rate at w , S(w)
    average marginal social welfare G'() of agents
    with productivity greater than w and F( )
    cumulative of f( ) .

12
Reminder of the OIRM (cont'd)
  • Intuitive proof of optimal tax formula
  • Increase the marginal tax rate at the
    productivity level w by ?t.
  • All people with productivity greater than w pay
    the tax. Total receipt 1 F(w) ?t
  • People concerned by the marginal tax rate change
    modify their labor supply L by ?L ?.L.?t
    /w(1-t). The corresponding change in tax
    payment then is t.w ?L t.w.?.L.?t /w(1-t)
  • Density of people concerned by marginal tax rate
    change density of z wL at productivity level
    w. From z B.w1??(1-t)?, it may be shown that
    this density is given by f(w)/(1 ?).L
  • People in a) loose on average a social welfare
    S(w), people in b) have no loss of welfare.
    Additional tax receipt distributed as an equal
    lump sum to all individuals, with an average
    welfare gain equal to S(w0).

13
Reminder of the OIRM (cont'd)
  • Intuitive proof of optimal tax formula
  • Collecting all preceding terms together and
    noticing that the change in social welfare cannot
    differ from zero at the optimum leads to
  • And then

14
Reminder of the OIRM (cont'd)
  • Analysis of this optimal redistribution system
    easy if social welfare function reasonably simple
  • Full tax system obtained by integrating t(w)
    along z.
  • Government budget constraint satisfied by
    modifying the constant of integration, T(0).
  • - T(0) guaranteed disposable income at 0 income
    from labor

15
II) Trying to implement empirically the OIRM
  •   1) Motivation
  • Various recent attempts at identifying features
    of optimal redistribution schedules based on
    'true' data i.e. true f(w). See Diamond
    (1998), Salanié (1998), Saez (2000), Bourguignon
    and Spadaro (2000)
  • Should the optimal marginal tax rate curve be
    U-shaped, increasing, decreasing, flat ?
  • What follows summarizes problems and results
    obtained by Bourguignon and Spadaro (2000)

16
Trying to implement empirically the OIRM
  •   2) Methodological issues
  • a) Choosing a labor supply elasticity
  •   - hours of work and labor supply
  •   - heterogeneity of ? across various types of
    individuals
  •   - 'household' productivity and labor-supply
    elasticity
  •  
  • b) Estimating the distribution of productivities
    f(w)
  • - use observed wage rates 
  • - Choose elasticity parameter, ?, and 'invert'
    observed EMTR and gross labor income, z, to get
    w for the household z B.w1??(1-t)? .  

17
Trying to implement empirically the OIRM
  •   c) Choosing and calibrating a social welfare
    function
  • Probably the simplest social welfare function
    G(u) to use is piecewise linear. This facilitates
    the computation of the mean marginal social
    welfare S(w). 
  • The function being used here is of the following
    charitable conservative type
  • G(u) u if F(w) ? q
  • G(u) bu if F(w) gt q with blt1
  • This function has the usual properties of being
    increasing and concave

18
Trying to implement empirically the OIRM
  •  
  • How to calibrate the social welfare function ?
  • G(u) u if F(w) ? q
  • G(u) bu if F(w) gt q with blt1
  • b 1 ? Utilitarian
  • b 0 ? Rawlsian
  • Preferred choice b such that relative poverty
    would optimally be eliminated if the labor-supply
    elasticity were 'small'. This is equivalent to
    imposing T(0) - .5mean income.

19
Trying to implement empirically the OIRM
  •   d) Some complications
  •  (i) Continuity and differentiability
  • (ii) Household size
  • (iii) Households with zero income and households
    with apparently 'irrational' behavior
  • - 100 per cent marginal tax rate at minimum
    income - Less than 100 per cent marginal tax
    rate at minimum income
  •  Drawing measurements errors to eliminate
    anomalies extrapolating productivity
    distribution for non-working individuals
  • (iv) Lack of observations at the top of the
    distribution (approximation by a Pareto)

20
Trying to implement empirically the OIRM
  •   3) Results for 4 EU countries
  • Data base Household surveys used in Euromod
    project
  • Euromod tax-benefit software to compute marginal
    tax rates
  •  

21
(No Transcript)
22
(No Transcript)
23
(No Transcript)
24
Trying to implement empirically the OIRM
  • Main Findings
  • Optimal systems based on 'actual' data and
    reasonable assumptions are far from actual
    redistribution systems.
  • Systematically declining marginal tax rates
    only way to have U-shaped curve is to have
    decreasing social marginal welfare at the top of
    the distribution.
  • Related conclusion relatively low marginal tax
    rate at the top of the distribution
  • Rapidly declining marginal tax rates at the
    bottom of the distribution (a shape that differs
    from what is implied by strict means-tested
    transfers).

25
Trying to implement empirically the OIRM
  • Preceding exercise is probably the limit of what
    can be done empirically to implement in a
    reasonable way the OIRM.
  • Is it really conclusive ?
  • After all, two main conclusions may be linked to
    assumptions made on unobserved or badly observed
    part of the distribution of productivities.

26
Trying to implement empirically the OIRM
  • 4) Revealing social preferences
  • Instead of comparing the optimal system linked to
    'observed' f(w), arbitrary ?? and arbitrary
    social welfare function, G( ), one may go the
    other way.
  • 'Inverse optimal problem' (Kurz)
  • Observing the actual redistribution system
    through the marginal tax rates associated to
    productivity levels, w, is it possible to infer
    the social welfare function that would make that
    system 'optimal' ?

27
Trying to implement empirically the OIRM
  • Inverse optimal problem work in progress (BS)
  • Results encouraging in the sense that actual
    redistribution systems observed f(w)
    assumptions for unobserved parts of f( )
    reasonable values for ? lead to
    'non-contradictory' shapes of G'(u).
  • Revealed values of G'( ) decreasing with w, at an
    accelerated rate for highest values of w
  • However, provisos with assumptions about
    unobserved partd of f( ) still apply.

28
C) Adequacy of the OIRM for redistribution
analysis in developed and developing countries
  • Overall, results are somewhat disappointing
    because they rely on rather stringent
    assumptions, which are more or less all open to
    debate.
  • Lets' consider four kinds of issues
  • Representation of the whole economy and
    functioning of the labor market.
  • In particular, are all households on their
    labor-supply curve? Things would clearly be
    different if non-workers were constrained on the
    demand side of the market.

29
Adequacy of the OIRM for redistribution analysis
in developed and developing countries
  • b) Other sources of heterogeneity among
    households capital income, household size,
    gender issues within the household, etc
  • To what extent actual systems reflect
    redistribution along these other dimensions?
  • Unfortunately, it is hopelessly difficult to
    generalize OIRM to more than one dimension

30
Adequacy of the OIRM for redistribution analysis
in developed and developing countries
  • c) Concept of a social welfare function. What
    would happen if G( ) were to reflect the views of
    some decisive voter, or the outcome of some kind
    of political economy equilibrium?

31
Adequacy of the OIRM for redistribution analysis
in developed and developing countries
  • d) Static model, whereas actual systems may take
    into account dynamic features of individual
    welfare as well as uncertainty aspects.
  • The insurance part of redistribution schemes.

32
Conclusion
  • OIRM was an extremely promising framework.
    Probably the best representation of the old
    efficiency-equity trade-off
  • Yet it may be too simple for being of much
    practical use, beyond theoretical economic
    reasoning.
  • Workfield still open. Most likely that modern
    computation techniques should permit to solve
    some of the technical problems listed previously.
  • Remains true that good understanding of the
    actual functioning of economies remain a priority.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com