Title: Corporate Governance in Latin America
1Corporate Governance in Latin America
- Fernando Lefort
- Business School
- PUC, Chile
2Literature
- Non specific papers LLSV (1998a, 1998b, 1999..)
- Regional papers ?
- Country specific papers
- Argentina few, poor data
- Brazil several, empirical
- Chile several, empirical
- Colombia ?
- Mexico some, relatively poor data
3Issues
- General corporate governance mechanisms
- Ownership identity and structure
- Board practices
- Disclosure practices
- Institutional investors
- Market for control
4Issues
- Latin American specific issues
- Conglomerates
- Financial market development
- Macroeconomic and political instability
- Legal reform
5Ownership identity and structure
- High ownership concentration
- Conglomerates
- Pyramid structures
- Dual class shares
- Foreign ownership
6Ownership identity and structure
- Argentina
- Apreda (2001), de Michele (2002)
- Incomplete data
- Among 20 largest listed companies controlling
shareholders hold 65 of equity. - Considering 40 largest companies
- 25 foreign
- 14 local
- 1 State owned
- Non voting shares and pyramids are used. No data
available.
7Ownership identity and structure
- Brazil
- Leal et al. (2002), Leal and Oliveira (2002),
Siffert (2002) - Five largest shareholders hold 84 of voting
capital and 58 of total capital. - Considering the 100 largest non financial firms
- Disperse ownership 2.2 family (local group)
28.9 foreign 37.2 government 31.8 - 1/3 of voting shares to 2/3 of non voting. It
has ghanged to 50. - Pyramid structures are uncommon.
- Controllers hold more equity than strictly needed
for control.
8Ownership identity and structure
- Chile
- Lefort and Walker (2000), Agosín and Pastén
(2000), Majluf et al. (1998) - Three largest shareholders hold 73.6. Five
largest hold 88.6 - 91 of listed assets controlled by conglomerates.
Half of them are foreign - 57 of consolidated equity directly or indirectly
owned by controllers - Control mechanisms
- Conglomerates use simple pyramid structures 1/3
of listed companies are second tier or higher - Only 7.5 of listed firms have dual class shares
- Cross-holdings are forbidden
9Ownership identity and structure
- Mexico
- Babatz (1997), Castañeda (2000), Husted and
Serrano (2001) - Deficiencies in data make impossible to get
detailed information on ownership. - Related stockholders hold, on average, 65.5 of
shares. For firms with ADRs in the NYSE this
figure is 49. - 18 of 150 largest companies are foreign
controlled. - Most traded stocks have limits regarding voting
rights - Usually, class A gives full voting rights to
family owners. - Other classes provide only limited voting rights
for minority interest.
10Board practices and composition
- Boards have mainly advisory character.
- Very few independent board members.
- Few committees
- Interlocking of boards
11Board practices and composition
- Brazil
- Ventura (2000), Leal and Oliveira (2002), Spencer
Stuart (1999), Outra and Saito (2001) - Boards have mainly advisory character
- 49 of board members represent directly to
controlling shareholders - CEO tend to be related to controllers
- Less than 20 of directors could classify as
independent - Only 17 of companies have permanent committees.
12Board practices and composition
- Chile
- Lefort and Walker (2000), Iglesias (1999), Majluf
et al. (1998), Spencer Stuart-PUC (2000) - Only 55 of directors have no direct family or
work relationship with the company or related
companies. - 10 of board members in companies where pension
funds own shares are elected by pension funds. - 71 of listed companies have no comittees.
- Board interlocking
- In conglomerates 1.6 seats/director 72/1530 sit
on at least 2 groups. - 5 largest groups control 121/141 board members.
13Board practices and composition
- Mexico
- Babatz (1997), Husted and Serrano (2001), LLS
(1999) - Appointing directors in Mexico is largely a
family matter. - 53 of directors are either top executives of the
firm, of other firms of the group, or relatives
of such executives. - The lack of independence is probably worse
because political, compadrazgo, or other kinds
of dependence.
14Institutional investors
- Fund suppliers
- Pension reform triggers capital market reform
- Role as minority shareholders
15Institutional investors
- Walker and Lefort (2000), Husted and Serrano
(2001), Siffert (2000) - By the year 2000 pension funds holdings of
corporate bonds and stocks accounted for - 15.9 in Chile 24.8 in Argentina 32.1 in
Perú. - In Mexico small presence (yet) of institutional
investors. - In Brazil increase in companies displaying
shared control, with institutional investors
(domestic and foreign) as the principal
stockholders.
16Market for corporate control
- High concentration implies absence of hostil
takeovers - Large control premium
- Foreign companies
- Tender offer requirements
17Market for corporate control
- Argentina
- Apreda (2000)
- US30 billion in MA during the nineties.
- No data on premia.
- Brazil
- Valadares (1998)
- Control premium up to 150 in changes of control
transactions - Chile
- Lefort and Walker (2001), Parisi et al. (2001)
- Around 20 large acquisitions since 1998.
- Average control premium 70, average stake traded
40, average abnormal return 4.
18Conglomerates and economic performance
- Benefits of internal capital markets
- Conglomerate premium or discount?
- Financial policies
19Conglomerates and economic performance
- Brazil
- Sronr (2002)
- Firms with better CG (less separation between
ownership and control) respond better to crisis
and economic downturns. - Mexico
- Castañeda (2002), de Gortari (2000)
- Firms affiliated to conglomerates have better
access to external finance. - Fixed investment of affiliated firms is less
sensitive to own retained earnings.
20Conglomerates and economic performance
- Chile
- Gálvez and Tybout (1985), Medina and Valdés
(1998), Khanna and Palepu (1999), Lefort and
Walker (2000, 2002), Claessens et al. (2000) - During the debt crises groups outperformed non
affiliated firms. - Discounts (Tobins q) on affiliated firms. Less
separation between ownership and control raises
q. - Betas of affiliated firms are lower.
- Affiliation mitigates companys financial
constraints. Affiliated firms have more access
to long term bank and bond financing, while non
affiliated (smaller) firms rely heavily on
suppliers credit.
21CG and capital market development
- Degree of financial liberalization and importance
of foreign capital flows - Importance of domestic financial markets as fund
providers versus migration or internal capital
markets - Relationship with CG
- Adequate CG fosters capital market development,
- Financial liberalization and development makes CG
more important
22CG and capital market development
- Argentina
- de Michele (2002)
- During the nineties Argentina pursued financial
liberalization, pension reform and
privatizations. Outcome - Timid participation of pension funds in
corporations - Huge transfer of property from the government and
families to foreigners - Small effect on domestic capital markets
23CG and capital market development
- Brazil
- Siffert (2002), Srour (2002), Gledson (2002)
- Issuing ADR level II and migration to Novo
Mercado with higher CG requirements increased
price, volume and liquidity. - Chile
- Saenz (1999), Parisi et al. (2001), Lefort and
Eyzaguirre (2000), Lefort and Walker (2002) - Important development of Chilean capital markets
during the nineties. Deepening financial reform.
Banks play almost no role on CG. - Positive abnormal returns when issuing ADRs.
24CG and capital market development
- Mexico
- Castañeda (2000), Husted and Serrano (2001)
- Stock market is relatively small, low traded
volumes, low participation of pension funds. High
concentration. - Almost 60 of BMV index market capitalization
rests on the value of 5 companies. - Banks play little role on CG.
- Important role of internal capital markets in
explaining financial crisis recovery.
25Legal framework
- French origin
- Capital Markets and Corporations Laws recently
reformed under IFC advice - Incomplete disclosure
- Poor enforcement
- Poor judiciary long and cumbersome procedures.
Uncertain outcomes. - Political opposition to reform
26Legal framework
- Argentina
- Brazil
- Novo mercado, code of best practices, opposition
to reform - Chile
- Recent reform (transitory clause)
- Mexico
- Code of best practices, reform
- Colombia
- Code of best practices, reform
27Macroeconomic and political instability
- LA is very sensitive to external shocks.
- Domestic capital markets are not well developed
to provide funding during crisis. - Risk premia increase makes very expensive to
raise capital - CG tends to exit the political and economic
agenda during crisis