Eric Bartelsman, John Haltiwanger - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 29
About This Presentation
Title:

Eric Bartelsman, John Haltiwanger

Description:

Does churning of workers and firms boost productivity and output growth? ... Churning: There is a high pace of the reallocation of outputs and inputs across ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:47
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 30
Provided by: oecd96
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Eric Bartelsman, John Haltiwanger


1
How important is allocative efficiency for
productivity growth?A cross-country
cross-sectoral analysis
BDL/CAED Conference Cardiff, 7-9 September 2005
  • Eric Bartelsman, John Haltiwanger
  • and Stefano Scarpetta

2
Outline
  • Question Given heterogeneity of firms, large
    job-flows and firm dynamics
  • How important is firm and job churning for
    productivity
  • Distributed micro data analysis
  • Resource reallocation and productivity
  • Theory
  • Job flows
  • Static Allocation
  • Dynamic Allocation
  • Links between allocation and within-firm growth

3
Research questions
  • Does churning of workers and firms boost
    productivity and output growth?
  • What are the margins used for adjustment?
  • How does their use vary across countries/sectors?
  • To what extent do the various types of churn
    affect productivity directly?
  • Are there indirect effects of good resource
    allocation?

4
Distributed micro analysis
  • OECD sample
  • Demographics (entry/exit) for 10 countries
  • Productivity decompositions for 7 countries
  • Survival analysis 7 countries
  • World Bank sample
  • Same variables, 14 of Central and Eastern Europe,
    Latin America and South East Asia
  • EU Sample (10 countries), updates and a few new
    countries
  • Productivity decompositions
  • Sample Stats and correlations by quartile

5
Data sources
  • Business registers for firm demographics
  • Firm level, at least one employee, 2/3-digit
    industry
  • Production Stats, enterprise surveys for
    productivity analysis
  • Countries
  • 10 OECD
  • 5 Central and Eastern Europe
  • 6 Latin America
  • 3 East Asia
  • Data are disaggregated by
  • industry (2-3 digit)
  • size classes 1-9 10-19 20-49 50-99 100-249
    250-499 500 (for OECD sample the groups between
    1 and 20 and the groups between 100 and 500 are
    combined)
  • Time (late 1980s late 1990s)

6
Cross-country Comparisons
  • Harmonization
  • Sample frames Variable definitions
    Classifications Aggregation Methods
  • Make comparisons that take into account
    measurement problems
  • By exploiting the different dimensions of the
    data (size, industry, time)
  • By using difference in differences techniques
  • Even in absence of measurement error,
    interpretation of cross-country indicators
    requires careful analysis

7
Job Flows stylized facts
  • Magnitudes Large in excess of 10 percent
    annually for job creation and destruction
  • Between vs. Within Sector Most accounted for by
    within sector (about 10 percent accounted for by
    NAICS between sector reallocation)
  • Size, Age and Industry
  • Much larger flows for young and small businesses
  • Systematic variation across industries (e.g.,
    retail trade, construction have higher flows)
  • High pairwise correlations between U.S. industry
    flows and other countries
  • Entry and Exit Substantial fraction accounted
    for by entry and exit. More generally, flows
    dominated by large changes (employment growth
    distribution is kurtotic)
  • Business Cycles Manufacturing recessions in
    OECD characterized by sharp rise in destruction
    relative to fall in creation

8
Firm demographics stylized facts
  • Size and growth The probability of survival
    tends to increase with firm size but,
    conditional on survival, the proportional rate of
    growth of a firm is decreasing in size (see Evans
    1987a, 1987b Dunne et al. 1988, 1989).
  • The firm life cycle For any given size of firm,
    the proportional rate of growth is smaller the
    older the firm, but its survival probability is
    greater (see Foster et al. 2001 and
    International Journal of Industrial Organization,
    1995).
  • Shakeouts The number of producers in a given
    market tends first to rise to a peak, and later
    to fall to some lower level. (Klepper and Graddy,
    1990 Klepper and Simons, 1993 Geroski, 1995).
  • Churning There is a high pace of the
    reallocation of outputs and inputs across
    businesses (e.g. Geroski, 1995, Ahn, 2000 and
    Davis and Haltiwanger, 1999 for surveys of the
    literature).
  • Reallocation and Productivity In well-developed
    market economies, the evidence is overwhelming
    that the pattern of reallocation is productivity
    enhancing. (see e.g. Olley and Pakes, 1996,
    Griliches and Regev, 1995, and Foster,
    Haltiwanger and Krizan, 2001, 2002).

9
Assessing the role of firm dynamics on
productivity
  • Types of churn
  • Reallocation of resources (eg job flows, POS
    NEG) among incumbents
  • Firm exit and entry
  • Many hypotheses
  • Churn represents productive reallocation
  • On net, static allocation improves. NEG increases
    prod, POS increases prod (or at least does not
    offset impact from NEG)
  • Matching process at low end of productivity
    distribution
  • On net, churn does not affect productivity. NEG
    increases prod, POS decreases prod
  • Still could be long run net impact (churning at
    lower end may be part of experimentation)

10
Assessing the role of firm dynamics on
productivity (2)
  • Other hypotheses
  • General matching process
  • Unrelated to productivity. The flows may or may
    not be wasteful (matching process may be
    efficient, given search and other transactions
    costs)
  • Reallocation dynamics driven by demand/cost
    factors
  • Improper churn
  • Various market imperfections and bad policy cause
    sub-optimal decisions regarding factor adjustment
  • Technological sclerosis and/or unbalanced
    restructuring
  • No reallocation effect, by assumption
  • Representative agent model. All resources at
    representative firm, at productivity frontier.
  • Firms are heterogeneous, but no adjustment
    frictions and productivity growth can occur
    within firms. Allocation always is optimal, so
    all productivity growth is within-firm. (Petrin
    and Levinsohn, 2005).

11
Assessing the role of firm dynamics on
productivity (3)
  • Many Empirical issues
  • Static vs. Dynamic Allocative Efficiency
  • Static In a given industry/country, are
    resources allocated to more productive
    establishments?
  • Dynamic Over time, are resources reallocated
    towards more productive establishments?
  • Allocative efficiency effects may take time
  • Market experimentation
  • Learning and selection effects
  • More generally, adjustment costs may be
    internal so adverse impact on productivity in
    times of intense reallocation
  • No general prediction about correlation between
    pace of reallocation and productivity growth in
    country j, industry i, at time t
  • Natural experiments rare (transition
    economies/market reforms?)

12
The impact of reallocation and firm churning on
jobs
Manufacturing, 1989-2000, firms with 20
employees)
13
Aggregate productivity and allocation
  • Olley and Pakes (1996) static decomposition
  • where N of firms in a sector
  • The first term is the unweighted average of
    firm-level productivity,
  • The second term reflects allocation of resources
    do firms with higher productivity have greater
    market share.
  • Caution
  • Over time, both terms may reflect changes in
    allocative efficiency
  • E.g., If entering establishments more productive
    than exiting establishments, first term will
    increase over time

14
The cross-sectional efficiency of the allocation
of activity

15
The cross-sectional efficiency of the allocation
of activity

16
The decomposition of productivity growth
  • Foster, Haltiwanger and Krizan (FHK , 2001) in
    this decomposition, each term is weighted by the
    average (over 3/5 years) market shares as
    follows
  • The within-firm effect is within-firm
    productivity growth weighted by initial output
    shares.
  • The between-firm effect captures the gains in
    aggregate productivity coming from the expanding
    market of high productivity firms, or from
    low-productivity firms shrinking shares weighted
    by initial shares.
  • The cross effect reflects gains in productivity
    from high-productivity growth firms expanding
    shares or from low-productivity growth firms
    shrinking shares.
  • The entry effect is the sum of the differences
    between each entering firms productivity and
    initial productivity in the industry, weighted by
    its market share.
  • The exit effect is the sum of the differences
    between each exiting firms productivity and
    initial productivity in the industry, weighted by
    its market share.

17
Within-firm productivity growth makes the bulk of
overall productivity growth
18
Dynamic allocative efficiency the importance of
technology factors
We decompose our data for manufacturing into a
low technology group and a medium high tech
group ? Stronger contribution of entry to
productivity growth in medium high tech industries
Contribution of entry to labor productivity
growth, five year differencing, gross output
19
Net Entry effect, 3 vs 5 years

20
BG vs FHK decomp

21
Links between dynamic reallocation and within
growth
  • Wider productivity dispersion in newer, dynamic
    industries
  • Wider productivity dispersion in US than in EU
  • Why?
  • Incentives for firms to experiment to push out
    frontier if large potential gain in market

22
Labor Productivity Dispersion
Units Thousand US per worker
23
High productivity firms expand in some countries
but not in others
24
(No Transcript)
25
The indirect effect market contestability
26
The key features of firm churning
  • The magnitude of firm churning
  • The characteristics of entrants and exiting firms
  • The survival of new firms
  • The post-entry performance of successful entrants

27
Evidence of firm turnover
Total business sector, firms with at least 1
employee
  • No major differences across OECD countries,
    especially after controlling for sector and size
    effects
  • But large differences in size at entry
  • Large net entry in transition economies filling
    the gaps (?)

Total business sector, firms with at least 20
employees
28
Gross and net firm turnover in transition
economies
29
Post-entry employment growth varies more across
countries
Average firm size growth relative to entry, by
age
30
Concluding remarks and future work
  • Process of creative destruction in ALL countries
  • Differences in the nature of the process of
    creative destruction
  • Strong contribution of resource reallocation on
    productivity from both static and dynamic
    perspectives
  • Differences in the role of creative destruction
    on productivity growth across countries and
    technology groups
  • Differences in degree of firm heterogeneity
    across countries
  • We still need to explore how the process of
    creative destruction affect productivity and job
    creation in industries at different stages of
    maturity and technology
  • We need to explore more what drives post entry
    performance of firms
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com