Title: Late Informed Betting and the FavoriteLongshot Bias
1Late Informed Betting and the Favorite-Longshot
Bias
- http//www.london.edu/faculty/mottaviani/flb.pdf
Marco Ottaviani London Business School Peter
Norman Sorensen University of Copenhagen
2Talk Plan
- 1. Parimutuel betting markets
- 2. Empirical facts
- Favorite-longshot bias
- Informed betting at the end
- 3. Theoretical model
- Equilibrium with simultaneous betting
- Timing incentives
- 4. Implications for market designs
3Parimutuel Betting
- Betting format used at horse-racing tracks
worldwide - Bets on horses are placed over time
- Tote board shows current bets, regular updates
- Betting is closed and race run
- Pool of money bet (minus track take) is shared
among winning bettors, in proportion to bets - Variants used in other sports, lotto, hedging
markets
4Parimutuel vs. Fixed Odd Betting
- Parimutuel betting
- Return to a bet depends on other bets placed
- Bets are placed before knowing the payoff
- Fixed odd betting (not in our paper)
- Bookmakers accept bets at quoted (and possibly
changing) odds - Return is not affected by later bets
5From Market Odds to Probabilities
- If horse i wins, and ki out of N dollars were bet
on it, every dollar on that horse gets 1 ?i
where - ?i(N(1- t)ki)/ki
- is the market odds ratio for horse i
- Budget balance always pay out ki(1?i)(1- t)N
- Expected payoffs equalized across horses when win
probability is the implied market probability - ri(1- t)/(1?i)ki/N
6Talk Plan
- 1. Parimutuel betting markets
- 2. Empirical facts
- Favorite-longshot bias
- Informed betting at the end
- 3. Theoretical model
- Equilibrium with simultaneous betting
- Timing incentives
- 4. Implications for market designs
7Using Outcomes for Rationality Test
- Many horse races, each with several horses
- To each racing horse i associate corresponding
market probabilities ki/N in that race - Group horses with same market probability
- From outcomes of races compute groups empirical
winning probability - Compare market probability with empirical winning
probability
8Asch, Malkiel and Quandt (82) Data
empirical probability
market probability
9Favorite-Longshot Bias
- Market odds very correlated with empirical odds
- But too many bets on longshots, the horses
unlikely to win! - Sometimes an expected profit from favorite bets
- Anomaly, challenges orthodox economic theory
- Griffith (1949), Weitzman (1965), Rosett (1965),
Ali (1977), Thaler and Ziemba (1988)
10Ziemba and Hausch (1986)
Favorite-Longshot Bias Empirically
favorites
longshots
11Evidence on Timing
- Asch, Malkiel and Quandt (1982)
- Late odds changes predict the order of finish
very well, better than actual odds - Informally bettors who have inside information
would prefer to bet late in the period so as to
minimize the time that the signal is available to
the general public - Late informed betting
12Talk Plan
- 1. Parimutuel betting markets
- 2. Empirical facts
- Favorite-longshot bias
- Informed betting at the end
- 3. Theoretical model
- Equilibrium with simultaneous betting
- Timing incentives
- 4. Implications for market designs
13Our Theory Preview
- Partially informed bettors, wait till the end
- Simultaneous bets reveal information that is not
properly incorporated in the final odds - Many (few) bets placed on a horse indicate
private information for (against) this horse - If market were allowed to revise odds after last
minute bets, market odds would adjust against
longshots
14Other Theories
- Overestimation of low probabilities Griffith
(1949) - Risk (or skewness) loving behavior Weitzman
(1965), Ali (1977), Golec and Tamarkin (1998) - Monopoly power of insider Isaacs (1953)
- Limited arbitrage due to positive track take
Hurley and McDonough (1995) - Response of uninformed bookmaker to market with
some insiders Shin (1991, 1992) - Behavioral misunderstanding of the winners
curse Potters and Wit (1995)
15Talk Plan
- 1. Parimutuel betting markets
- 2. Empirical facts
- Favorite-longshot bias
- Informed betting at the end
- 3. Theoretical model
- Equilibrium with simultaneous betting
- Timing incentives
- 4. Implications for market designs
16Simplest Setting
- Two horses 1,1 prior win chance qPr(x1)
- No prior bets (a-1a10), no track take (t0)
- N risk-neutral bettors with private posterior
belief pi (that 1 wins), continuous cdf G(px) - All bettors must make unit bet simultaneously
- Derivation of equilibrium betting behavior
- Compare market odds to Bayesian empirical odds
17Equilibrium Betting Characterization
- Proposition 1 There exists a unique symmetric
equilibrium, where ppN bet on 1 pN solves - As N tends to infinity, pN tends to the unique
solution to - Example Fair prior and symmetric signal
G(px1) 1G(1px1), then pN 1/2.
18Equilibrium Brief Derivation
- WN (bx) is expected payout to b-bet given x-win
- With p chance of any opponent winning
- Arbitrage condition for the marginal belief pN
- pNWN (b1x1)(1 pN)WN (b1x1), or
19Equilibrium Derivation for Large N
- Perfectly competitive limit, N8
- Indifferent bettor thinks 1 wins with chance p
- Horse 1 attracts bets from all bettors with
posterior above p, for the mass (1G(px1)) - 1 wins with chance 1p has G(px1) bets
- Indifference holds at
20Market, Bayesian and Empirical Odds
- Bayesian posterior odds Given the observed bets,
what is the posterior odds ratio for horse 1 - Bayesian odds are natural estimates of empirical
odds, as they incorporate the information
revealed in the bets and adjust for noise - We uncover a systematic relation between Bayesian
and market odds depending on noise and information
21Comparing Market Bayesian Odds
- Fair prior q1/2, symmetric signal, informative
G(1/2x1)/G(1/2x1)1 - Proposition 3 For any long market odds ratio
?1, if - (i) Informativeness G(1/2x-1)/G(1/2x1) is
large, - or (ii) there are many insiders N, so that
- then the Bayesian odds ratio is longer than the
markets
22Proof of Proposition 3
- Market odds ratio shorter than Bayesian odds if
- Taking logarithms and rearranging, we get
- Since ?1 and G(1/2x1)G(1/2x1), all terms
are positive. - Generalize to asymmetric prior q?1/2 (Prop. 2)
23Intuition
- The bet chance for every bettor is
- 1G(1/2x1) G(1/2x1) on winner horse x in
state x - G(1/2x1) 1 G(1/2x1) on loser horse -x
in state x - Market odds converge to G(1/2x1)/G(1/2x1) or
its reciprocal (depending on the state) as N is
large - Since G(1/2x1)i.i.d., by the LLN the bets reveal x for large N
- Bayesian odds tend to the extremes as N is large
- (Logic applies also to few well informed bettors)
24Verbal Intuition
- Consider case with large number of bettors
- Bayesian odds are extreme (close to 0 or
infinity) provided signals are informative - If less than 50 bet on a horse, it is most
likely to lose Bayesian odds are very long - Market odds are less extreme one would always
observe too many bets on longshot
25Interplay of Noise Information
- If the signals contain little information,
Bayesian odds are close to prior odds, even with
extreme market odds - Deviation of market odds from prior odds are then
mostly due to the noise contained in the signal - Reversed favorite-longshot bias when signals
contain little information Long market odds too
long! - As N increases, realized bets contain more
information and less noise so that Bayesian odds
are more accurate than market odds, resulting in
favorite-longshot bias
26Predicted Expected Payoff as Function of LogOdds
With q1/2, G(1/2x1)1/4, G(1/2x1)3/4, N4
informed bettors
27Bias and Rationality
- The market odds test of rationality assumes too
much information to bettors - As is they know the final bet distribution
which they do not with simultaneous betting - If betting were to reopen, market odds could
adjust to eliminate the puzzle - Theory predicts reverse bias with few poorly
informed bettors e.g. lotto (no private info)
28Talk Plan
- 1. Parimutuel betting markets
- 2. Empirical facts
- Favorite-longshot bias
- Informed betting at the end
- 3. Theoretical model
- Equilibrium with simultaneous betting
- Timing incentives
- Bet late to free-ride on others private
information - Bet early to pre-empt others bets on public
information - 4. Implications for market designs
29Timing Incentives
- There are two forces at play
- Bet late, to conceal private information and
maybe observe others (like open auction with
fixed deadline) - Bet early, to capture a good market share of
profitable bets (as in Cournot oligopoly) - First force isolated with small bettors with
private information - Second force isolated with large bettors sharing
the same information
30Extreme Timing
- A With no market power, bettors wait till the
end in order to conceal information - B Large bettors with no private information bet
early to preempt competitors, but this is
incompatible with - favorite longshot bias if small bettors can bet
after them - informative last minute betting
31A Model with Small Private Info
- Pre-existing noise initial bets, a-1 and a1
- Size-N continuum of small bettors, individually
not affecting odds - Private beliefs, distributed G(px)
- Track takes proportion t of total amount bet
32Equilibrium in the Last Period
- Assume (i) belief distribution unbounded
(0 - Proposition 6 There is a unique symmetric BNE
All players use interior thresholds 0Bet on -1 when 0pp-1 and on 1 when p1p1. - Proposition 7 A greater prior q implies larger
thresholds p 1 and p1, weakly smaller W(11) and
weakly greater W(-1-1).
33Favorite-Longshot Bias Revisited
- With some bets on both horses, market odds are
not zero/infinite. But the continuum of bets
reveals the true state. Extreme form of bias. - Proposition 8 In symmetric case (q1/2 and
a1a-1a0), last-period equilibrium has
symmetric thresholds p-11p1. Fewer initial bets
a/N, or lower track take t, imply more extreme
market odds and so reduce the favorite-longshot
bias.
34Timing
- Proposition 9 Given above assumptions.
Postponing all bets to last period is a perfect
Bayesian equilibrium. - Proof After any history, 2 cases
- Belief distribution no longer unbounded the
state has been revealed, and all remaining
players bet on winning outcome are indifferent
regarding the timing might as well postpone. - Belief distribution still unbounded If player
deviates by betting now on 1, q goes weakly up,
W(11) weakly down (Prop 7), reducing deviators
payoff.
35B Competition Among Large Bettors
- N large bettors share the same (superior)
information - We review how bets affect odds and show
isomorphism with Cournot model - In equilibrium bets are placed early, contrary to
the empirical observation that late betting
contains lots of information
36How Betting Affects Odds
- Consider N1 bettor with superior information who
believes that horse 1 is very likely to win - The more this bettor bets on horse 1, the lower
the payout per dollar if that horse wins! - Standard monopoly tradeoff
- Last bet has payout above marginal cost
market odds not equal to posterior belief - Consider the case with N1 bettors who share the
same superior information
37- ax is pre-existing bets on x
- bx is the total amount bet by rational bettors on
x - If x wins, every dollar bet on outcome x receives
the payout - If the rational bettors bet only on x, this is a
Cournot model with unit production cost and
inverse demand curve -
38Endogenous Timing
- Hamilton and Slutsky (1990)
- A. Extended game with action commitment
- Player can only play early by selecting action to
which one is then committed - B. Extended game with observable delay (not here)
- First players announce at which time they wish to
choose action (and are committed to this choice) - After announcement, players select their actions
knowing when others make choice
39Large Bettors w/ Common Information
- Proposition 5 With N large bettors, there are 2
types of equilibrium. In the first, all move
early. In the second, all but one move early. - Proof Appeals directly to Matsumura (1999).
40Timing Incentives Summary
- A Late betting with small bettors possessing
private information, due to incentive to conceal
private information from the other bettors and
maybe observe others - B Early betting with large bettors sharing
common information, due to incentive to capture
market share of profitable bets
41Talk Plan
- 1. Parimutuel betting markets
- 2. Empirical facts
- Favorite-longshot bias
- Informed betting at the end
- 3. Theoretical model
- Equilibrium with simultaneous betting
- Timing incentives
- 4. Implications for market designs
42Information Aggregation and Market
Micro-Structure
- In parimutuel betting
- all trades are executed at the same final price
- so small traders have an incentive to postpone
trade to the last minute - In regular financial markets (Kyle (1985))
- competition among traders drive them to trade
early, so information is revealed early (Holden
and Subrahmanyam (1992)) - subsequent arbitrage trading would eliminate
favorite-longshot bias
43Parimutuel Market Structure
- Advantage Intermediary bears no risk
- Disadvantage Poor information aggregation
- Peculiar Feature If you buy an asset, you
dislike being followed by more buyers
44Shins Explanation with Fixed Odds
- Monopolist bookmaker in fixed odds betting
- Some bettors are uninformed and others informed
- Bookmaker with no private information sets odds
- Odd on each horse set according to inverse
elasticity rule - Demand for longshots is more inelastic because it
is made up by relatively more uninformed bettors - Bookmaker chooses shorter odds on longshots
- Favorite-longshot bias results from the
bookmaker's market power
45Our Explanation Summary
- Some partially informed bettors, wait till the
end - Late simultaneous bets reveal information that is
not properly incorporated in the final odds - Many (few) bets placed on a horse indicate
private information for (against) this horse - Horses obtaining lots (few) of late bets are more
(less) likely to win than according to final
market odds, as posterior odds are more extreme
46F-L Bias and Market Structure
- Persistent cross countries differences in the
observed biases could be attributed to - different patterns in the coexistence of parallel
(fixed odd and parimutuel) betting schemes - amount of randomness in the closing time in
parimutuel markets. - Bettors might have different incentives to place
their bets on the parimutuel system rather than
with the bookmakers depending on the quality of
their information.
47Conclusion
- The final bet distribution reflects equilibrium
betting and so differs from the posterior beliefs - We can explain both bias and timing with simple
model with - initial bets from uninformed bettors
- late bets from small (liquidity constrained)
profit maximizing privately informed bettors
48(No Transcript)
49NCAA Basketball
- Metrick (1999) finds too much betting on the
favorites in NCAA sweeps - With little private information and some noise on
the distribution of bets, our theory predicts the
reverse favorite-longshot bias - If bettors do not know the distribution of bets,
they tend to bet too much on the some outcomes
50Experimental Evidence
- Plott, Wit and Yang (2003)
- Consider setting with limited budget, private
information, and random termination - Find two puzzles (i) favorite-longshot bias and
(ii) not all profitable bets are made - Argue against individual decision biases because
subjects were explained Bayes' rule - Random termination time gives an additional
incentive to the bettors to move early in order
to reduce the termination risk, so we can explain
both favorite-longshot bias bettors taking risk
by waiting to place their bets later
51Market Manipulation
- Field experiment by Camerer (1998)
- Bets moved odds visibly and had slight tendency
to draw money toward the horse that was
temporarily bet - Net effect close to zero and statistically
insignificant - Some bettors inferred information from bets and
others did not their reaction roughly cancelled
out.
52Horse Races v. Lotteries
- In lotto, typically
- outcomes are equally likely
- punters do not know the distribution of other
bets (no tote board!) - no private information!
- Observe too many bets on lucky numbers
- Rarely possible to make money betting on
unpopular numbers because of large take
53Hotelling Location Games
- Competitors (politicians) take positions
- Objective to maximize market (vote) share
- Incentive to be close to consumers (voters) but
far from competitors - Parimutuel betting and forecasting contests are
Hotelling location games with private information - This work is also relevant for many other
applications of Hotelling location game
54Equilibrium Example f(sx1)2s
f(sx-1)2(1-s) with s in 0,1
cutoff s
N1
N2
N8
Prior q
For N1, optimal to bet according to posterior
s1-q For N1, bet more on ex-ante longshot
because of winners curse