Lecture 2 Auction Design

About This Presentation
Title:

Lecture 2 Auction Design

Description:

This lecture derives bidding rules for some auctions where there is incomplete ... Thus two congruent auctions are invariably revenue equivalent, but not all ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:325
Avg rating:3.0/5.0

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Lecture 2 Auction Design


1
Lecture 2Auction Design
This lecture derives bidding rules for some
auctions where there is incomplete information,
and discusses the the virtues and shortfalls of
alternative auction mechanisms. First we
explore the concept of revenue equivalence, which
is weaker than congruence, and applies to private
value auctions where the bidders are risk
neutral. Then we relax the conditions for
revenue equivalence to apply, seeking to show the
effects on bidding behavior and auction
revenue. Finally we discuss the role of
collusion and entry in auctions.
2
Review of Lecture 1 Congruence revisited
Using the concept of congruence we derived two
rules for bidding Rule 1 Pick the same
reservation price in a Dutch auction that you
would submit in a first price sealed bid
auction. Rule 2 In private value auctions, or
if there are only two bidders, choose the
reservation price for an English or a Japanese
auction, that you would submit in a second price
sealed bid auction.
3
Review of Lecture 1Second price auctions
  • We also proved that the bidding strategy in
    sealed bid second price auctions (and ascending
    auctions) is very straightforward if you know
    your own valuation.
  • Rule 3 In a second price sealed bid auction,
    bid your valuation if you know it.

4
Relaxing congruence
  • In congruent auctions, the revenue to the
    auctioneer and the payoffs to each bidder are
    identical for every game history generated by a
    solution strategy profile.
  • This is a very strong form of equivalence, and
    often not met. The bidders and the auctioneer may
    be indifferent between two auctions that are not
    congruent to each other.
  • For example, suppose the auctioneer and the
    bidders only care about their expected utility
    from respectively conducting and participating in
    an auction, and did not care about whether each
    individual game history has the same outcome.
  • Can we show that such players might be
    indifferent to certain non-congruent auctions
    (where there is incomplete information)?

5
Revenue Equivalence Defined
  • The concept of revenue equivalence provides a
    useful tool for exploring this question.
  • Two auction mechanisms are revenue equivalent if,
    given a set of players their valuations, and
    their information sets, the expected surplus to
    each bidder and the expected revenue to the
    auctioneer is the same.
  • Therefore revenue equivalence is a less stringent
    condition than congruence.
  • Thus two congruent auctions are invariably
    revenue equivalent, but not all revenue
    equivalent auctions are congruent.

6
Why study revenue equivalence ?
  • If the auctioneer and the bidders are risk
    neutral, studying revenue equivalence yields
    conditions under which the players are
    indifferent between auctions that are not
    necessarily congruent.
  • Exploiting the principle of revenue equivalence
    can sometimes give bidders a straightforward way
    of deriving their solution bid strategies.

7
Preferences and Expected Payoffs
Let U(vn) denote the expected value of the nth
bidder with valuation vn bidding according to
his equilibrium strategy when everyone else does
too. P(vn) denote the probability the nth
bidder will win the auction when all players bid
according to their equilibrium strategy. C(vn)
denote the expected costs (including any fees to
enter the auction, and payments in the case of
submitting a winning bid).
8
An Additivity Assumption
  • We suppose preferences are additive, symmetric
    and private, meaning
  • U(v) P(v) v - C(v)
  • So the expected value of participating in the
    auction is additive in the expected benefits of
    winning the auction and the expected costs
    incurred.

9
A revealed preference argument
  • Suppose the valuation of n is vn and the
    valuation of j is vj.
  • The surplus from n bidding as if his valuation
    is vj is U(vj), the value from participating if
    his valuation is vj, plus the difference in how
    he values the expected winnings compared to to a
    bidder with valuation vj, or (vn vj)P(vj).
  • In equilibrium the value of n following his
    solution strategy is at least as profitable as
    deviating from it by pretending his valuation is
    vj. Therefore
  • U(vn) gt U(vj) (vn vj)P(vj)

10
Revealed preference continued
  • For convenience, we rewrite the last slide on
    the previous page as
  • U(vn) - U(vj) gt (vn vj)P(vj)
  • Now viewing the problem from the jth bidders
    perspective we see that by symmetry
  • U(vj) gt U(vn) (vj vn)P(vn)
  • which can be expressed as
  • (vn vj)P(vn) gt U(vn) - U(vj)

11
A fundamental equality
  • Say vn gt vj.which then implies P(vn)gt P(vj).
  • Putting the two inequalities together, we
    obtain
  • (vn vj) P(vn)gt U(vn) - U(vj) gt (vn vj) P(vj)
  • Writing
  • vn vj dv
  • yields
  • which, upon integration, yields

12
Revenue equivalence
  • This equality shows that in private value
    auctions, the expected surplus to each bidder
    does not depend on the auction mechanism itself
    providing two conditions are satisfied
  • 1. In equilibrium the auction rules award the bid
    to the bidder with highest valuation.
  • 2. The expected value to the lowest possible
    valuation is the same (for example zero).
  • Note that if all the bidders obtain the same
    expected surplus, the auctioneer must obtain the
    same expected revenue.

13
A theorem
  • Assume each bidder
  • - is a risk-neutral demander for the auctioned
    object
  • - draws a signal independently from a common,
    strictly increasing, cumulative continuous
    distribution function.
  • Consider auction mechanisms where
  • - the buyer with the highest signal always wins
  • - the bidder with the lowest feasible signal
    expects zero surplus.
  • Then the same expected revenue will be
    generated by the auctions, and each bidder will
    make the same expected payment as a function of
    her signal.

14
First price sealed bid private value action for
wireless licenses
15
Second price sealed bid private value action for
wireless licenses
16
All pay private value auction
17
The Revenue from Private Value Auctions
Since any auction satisfying the conditions for
the theorem can be used to calculate the expected
revenue, we select the second price, or English
auction, to accomplish this task.
18
Steps for deriving expected revenue
  • The expected revenue from any auction satisfying
    the conditions of the theorem, is the expected
    value of the second highest bidder.
  • To obtain this quantity, we proceed in two
    steps
  • 1. derive and analyze the probability
    distribution of the highest valuation,
  • 2. and then derive the probability distribution
    of the second highest bidder.

19
The unconditional probability of winning
  • From the perspective of the auctioneer, or an
    outsider who does not know the valuation of any
    player, each player has an equal chance of
    winning the auction.
  • Given N bidders, each of whom has the same
    chance of winning, the probability of bidder n
    winning the auction is 1/N.
  • Each player knows his own valuation vn and
    consequently has more information than the
    auctioneer.
  • In the solution to a second price sealed bid
    auction, each bidder submits her own valuation to
    the auctioneer, and therefore the winning bidder
    is the player with the highest valuation.

20
The probability of winning an auction conditional
on your own valuation
  • That is the probability of winning an auction in
    equilibrium is just the probability of being
    endowed with the highest valuation.
  • If valuations are identically and independently
    distributed with cumulative probability
    distribution function F(v), the probability that
    v1, for example, is the highest of the N
    valuations equals
  • Pr(v2 ? v1) ? (v3? v1) ?. . . ? (vN ? v1)
  • Prv2 ? v1x Pr(v3? v1) x . . . x PrvN ? v1
  •   F (v1) x F (v1) x . . . x F (v1) (N-1
    times)
  • F (v1)N-1

21
The probability of the median valuation winning
an auction
  • Conditioning on your own valuation, as N
    increases the probability of winning the auction
    declines at a much faster rate than 1/N does.
  • For example if v1 is the median of the
    distribution, the probability of winning the
    auction when N2 is 0.5.
  • But the probability of winning the auction when
    N10 is
  • 0.59 1. 953110-3
  • which is orders of magnitude less than 1/10.

22
The probability of winning an auction with a
median valuation as a function of the number of
bidders
23
Expected revenue in a private value auction
  • The expected revenue to the auctioneer is the
    expected value of the second highest valuation.
    This can be calculated as
  • Hence the expected revenue for a private values
    auction satisfying the conditions of the theorem
    is this formula.

24
Bidding Rules for Private Value Auctions
Armed with the formula on the previous slide, we
can also derive the solution bidding strategies
for auctions that are revenue equivalent to the
second price sealed bid auction.
25
Bidding function in a first price sealed bid
auction
  • Consider, for example a first price sealed bid
    auctions with independent and identically
    distributed valuations.
  • In a symmetric equilibrium to first price sealed
    bid auction, we can show that a bidder with
    valuation vn bids

26
An example the uniform distribution
  • Valuations are uniformly distributed within the
    closed interval . In this case
  • which implies

27
Bidding function with the uniform distribution
  • Thus in the case of the uniform distribution the
    equilibrium bid of the player with valuation v is
    to bid a weighted average of the lowest possible
    valuation and his own, where the weights are
    respectively 1/N and (N-1)/N

28
Comparison of bidding strategies
  • The bidding strategies in the first and second
    price auctions markedly differ.
  • In a second price auction bidders should submit
    their valuation regardless of the number of
    players bidding on the object.
  • In the first price auction bidders should shave
    their valuations, by an amount depending on the
    number of bidders.

29
All pay sealed bid auction with private values
  • The revenue equivalence theorem implies that the
    amount bidders expect to pay in an all-pay
    auction as in all other auctions satisfying the
    conditions of the theorem.
  • In contrast to a first or second price sealed
    bid auctions where only the winner bidder pays
    his bid or the second highest bid in an all pay
    auction losers also pays their bids.
  • The amount paid by the nth bidder is certain,
    and not paid with the probability of winning the
    auction, that is F(vn)N-1.
  • By the revenue equivalence theorem the amount
    each bidder expect to pay in the first two
    auctions, upon seeing their valuation, equals the
    amount the bidder actually does pay in all pay
    auction.

30
Expected revenue in all pay auction
  • In an all pay auction the expected revenue from
    a bidder with vn bids F(vn)N-1 multiplied by the
    amount he would bid in a first price auction.
  • This is

31
When does Revenue Equivalence Fail?
  • Bidders might be risk averse, not risk neutral.
  • The private valuations of bidders might be drawn
    from the probability distribution that are not
    identical.
  • The theorem does not apply when bidders receive
    signals about the value of the object to them
    that are correlated with each other.
  • Collusion and entry deterrence are also
    considerations that auctioneers should account
    for.

32
Attitudes towards risk in second price sealed bid
auctions with private values
  • It remains a weakly dominant strategy for each
    player to bid his or her valuation.
  • The optimal bidding strategy for the second
    price sealed bid auction (and also the Japanese
    and English auctions) is independent of a
    bidder's attitude towards risk and uncertainty
    when private values are drawn from a common
    probability distribution.

33
Attitudes towards risk in first price sealed bid
auctions with private values
  • A strategy of bidding your valuation guarantees
    exactly zero surplus.
  • If you place a lower bid than your valuation
    your expected surplus initially increases until
    it reaches the maximum for a risk neutral bidder,
    and then falls, but the variance of the surplus
    increases as well.
  • A risk averse gambler is willing to trade a
    lower expected value to reduce the amount of
    uncertainty, he accordingly bids higher than a
    risk neutral bidder.

34
Comparing first and second price sealed bid
auctions
  • Revenue generated by a second price auction is
    independent of the bidders' preferences over
    uncertainty, since bidding is unaffected.
  • The revenue generated by the first price auction
    is the same as the revenue generated by a second
    price auction when bidders are risk neutral.
  • Therefore risk averse bidders generate more
    revenue in a first price auction than they would
    in a second price auction, and they generate more
    revenue in a first price auction than do risk
    neutral bidders.

35
Asymmetric valuations
  • In many auctions where there are private
    valuations, the bidders have different uses for
    the auctioned object, and this may be common
    knowledge to all the bidders.
  • Bidder knows the probability distributions that
    each of the other valuations are drawn from, he
    will typically use that information when making
    his own bid.
  • This affects the revenue equivalence theorem,
    and also the auctioneer's preferences towards
    different types of auctions.

36
An example of asymmetry
  • Instead of assuming that all bidders appear the
    same to the seller and to each other, suppose
    that bidders fall into two recognizably different
    classes.
  • Instead of there being a single distribution
    F(v) from which the bidders draw their
    valuations, there are two cumulative
    distributions, F1(v) and F2(v).
  • Bidders of type i?1,2 draw their valuations
    independently from the distribution Fi(v).
  • Let fi(x) denote the probability density
    function of Fi(x).

37
Asymmetry in a first price auction with only two
bidders
  • The private valuation of the first bidder is
    drawn from a probability distribution F1(v) that
    stochastically dominates the probability
    distribution for the other probability
    distribution F2(v).
  • In fact we make a stronger assumption, that for
    all v
  • Then b1(v)lt b2(v). The intuition is to bid
    aggressively from weakness and vice versa.

38
Asymmetric first price sealed bid auction
39
Base experiment for asymmetry with only one type
of players
40
Incomplete information about the type of the
bidder
  • Suppose each bidder sees his valuation, but does
    not immediately learn whether he comes from the
    high or low probability distribution.
  • At that point the bidding strategy cannot depend
    on which probability distribution the valuation
    comes from.
  • Then each bidder is told which probability
    distribution his bid is drawn from.
  • How should he revise his bid? The second (first)
    bidder learns that the first (second) bidder is
    more likely to draw a higher (lower) valuation
    than himself, realizes the probability of winning
    falls (rises), so adjusts his upwards
    (downwards).

41
Auction Design
In this part of the lecture we relax the
independence assumption for revenue equivalence
to apply, discuss the winners curse, and show
the effects on bidding behavior and auction
revenue. Finally we discuss the role of collusion
and entry in auctions.
42
Relaxing independence
  • The revenue equivalence theorem applies to
    situations in which the valuation of each is
    bidder is independently distributed, and this is
    is what we have been focusing on in the first
    part of this lecture.
  • This is not always a useful assumption, because
    in many situations a bidder would be informed if
    he had information about the object on the
    auction block that another bidder had, and would
    use the information in a similar way.
  • What happens when the signals that bidders get
    about the value of the auctioned item are
    positively correlated?

43
Symmetric Valuations
  • What happens when the signals that bidders get
    about the value of the auctioned item are
    positively correlated?
  • We relax independence and consider the class of
    symmetric valuations, which have two defining
    features
  • 1. All bidders have the same utility function.
  • 2. Each bidder only cares about the collection
    of signals received by the other bidders, not
    who received them.
  • Thus we may write the valuation of bidder n as

44
An example Value of the object not known to
bidders
  • Suppose the value of the object to each bidder
    is the same, but this value is unknown to each
    bidder. The nth bidder receives a signal sn which
    is distributed about the common value v, and
    write
  • sn v ?n where ?n ? EvInformation of n
    v
  • where ?n is independently distributed.
  • More generally, each bidder might place more
    significance on their own draw, but still attach
    some value to the assessments of others.

45
Summary so far
  • When comparing two (or more) auctions, we should
    consider the following questions
  • Are the auctions congruent, or if not, revenue
    equivalent?
  • Are the bidders risk neutral?
  • In private valuation auctions, are bidders
    drawing from the same probability distribution?
  • In common valuation auctions, are bidders drawing
    from the same distribution of signals?

46
English auction with common value
47
Dutch auction with common value
48
The winner's curse
  • When other bidders have information that you
    lack about the value of the object for sale,
    winning the auction may cause you to decrease
    your conditionally expected value of the object.
  • Failure to take into account the bad news about
    others' signals that comes with any victory is
    called the winner's curse.
  • The winner's curse describes the fact that
    winning an auction may convey new and unfavorable
    information about the item.
  • Because all other bids are less than the winning
    bid, the expected value of the item to the
    winning bidder might fall when the outcome of the
    auction is announced.

49
The expected value of the item upon winning the
auction
  • If the nth bidder wins the auction, he will
    realize his signal exceeded the signals of
    everybody else, that is
  • sn maxs1,,sN
  • so he will condition the expected value of the
    item on this new information.
  • His expected value is now the expected value of
    vn conditional upon observing the maximum signal
  • Evn sn maxs1,,sN
  • This is the value that the bidder should use in
    the auction, not Evnsn, because he should
    recognize that unless his signal is the maximum
    he will receive a payoff of zero.

50
Defining the Winners Curse
  • The winner's curse can be defined as
  • W(sn) Evnsn - Evn sn maxs1,,sN
  • Since the max operator is a convex increasing
    function of its arguments
  • it follows that W(sn) is a negative function.
  • Although bidders should take the winner's curse
    into account, there is widespread evidence that
    novice bidders do not take this extra information
    into account when placing a bid.

51
Revenue Comparisons forSymmetric Auctions
  • We can rank the expected revenue generated in
    symmetric equilibrium for auctions where
    valuations are also symmetric.
  • There are two basic results. In a symmetric
    auction
  • 1. The expected revenue from a Japanese auction
    is higher than what an English auction yields.
  • 2. The expected revenue from an English auction
    exceeds a first price sealed bid auction.

52
Differential information
  • We have discussed several types of information
    structures in auctions
  • - perfect foresight
  • - independently distributed private valuations
  • - symmetric valuations.
  • But one important case we have not touched yet,
    when some bidders know more about the common
    value of the object than other bidders do.

53
Bidding with differential information
  • An extreme form of dependent signals occurs when
    one bidder know the signal and the others do not.
  • How should an informed player bid?
  • What about an uninformed player?

54
An English common value auction experiment on
asymmetrically informed bidders
55
A sealed bid common value auction on
asymmetrically informed bidders
56
Perspective of the less informed bidder
  • Suppose the uninformed bidder always makes the
    same positive bid, denoted b. This is an example
    of a pure strategy.
  • Is this pure strategy part of a Nash
    equilibrium?
  • The best response of the informed bidder is to
    bid a little more than b when the value of the
    object vi is worth more than b, and less than b
    otherwise.
  • Therefore the uninformed bidder makes an
    expected loss by playing a pure strategy in this
    auction. A better strategy would be to bid
    nothing.

57
A theorem
  • The argument in the previous slide shows that
    the uninformed bidder plays a mixed strategy in
    this game.
  • One can show that in equilibrium the informed
    bidder bids according to the strategy
  • ?(x) EVV ? x
  • and that the uninformed bidder chooses a bid at
    random from the interval 0, EV according to
    the probability distribution H defined by
  • H(b) Prob?(V) ? b

58
The field of bidders
  • The last part of this lecture discusses two
    issues outside the bidding process itself that
    nevertheless may affect the outcome of the
    auction.
  • They are
  • Collusion amongst bidders
  • Determining the number of bidders
  • The degree of collusion and entry deterrence may
    affect how the auctioneer and the bidders rank
    different types of auctions that are revenue
    equivalent, or even strategically equivalent.

59
Collusion
  • First we discuss the scope for collusive
    behavior under different auction mechanisms.
  • Collusion between bidders is only possible if
    there is a mechanism for determining within a
    designated bidding ring which bidder has the
    highest valuation, and then ensuring members of
    the ring do not break the collusive agreement in
    the bidding.
  • We focus on the second point. Sometimes
    determining which member has the highest
    valuation is trivial (for example in common value
    auctions), and sometimes it can be resolved
    through an auction within the ring for the right
    to present the only serious bid to the
    auctioneer.

60
Evidence about collusion in auctions
  • Section 1 of the Sherman Act pertains to trusts
    and illegal constraints to trade.
  • Over three quarters of the criminal cases filed
    in the 1980s under its provisions were in
    auctions markets.
  • Given the difficulty in finding sufficient
    grounds to prosecute this illegal activity, one
    can safely conclude that collusive behavior in
    auctions is often a serious concern for the
    seller.

61
What are the gains from collusive behavior?
  • Consider a bidding ring of R members out of a
    total of N bidders.
  • The goal of the ring is to internally solve
    which of the players have the highest valuation,
    and then make one (serious) bid instead of R
    bids.
  • With fewer effective bidders in the auction,
    the expected price of the object is lower.
  • If all the bidders are able to collude, meaning
    N R, the auction reduces to a game of bilateral
    bargaining between the auctioneer and the single
    bidder.

62
Bidding rings in second price sealed bid auctions
  • For example, suppose the player with the
    highest valuation in the ring bids it, the other
    bidders in the ring submit the auctioneers
    reservation price, and the bidders outside the
    ring respond optimally but individually by
    bidding their true valuations.
  • Then the ring benefits from colluding if
  • 1. The high bid from the ring wins the auction
  • 2. The second highest valuation of bidders in
    the ring exceeds the highest valuation of all
    the bidders outside the ring.

63
Enforcing collusion in first and second price
sealed bid auctions
  • One reason why second price auctions are rarely
    used in practice is because they are more
    susceptible to collusion.
  • In a first price sealed bid auction, a member
    of the bidding ring must submit a bid over the
    rings low price to win the auction. Providing
    his valuation exceeds the rings bid, there is an
    opportunity to make profits by deviating from the
    rings decision. This makes collusive bidding
    harder to enforce.
  • Contrast this with a second price auction. In
    order to win the auction a bidder in the ring who
    breaks the collusive agreement must pay the
    reported value of the ring. The agreement by the
    ring is self enforcing!

64
Ascending auctions encourage communication
amongst the bidders
  • A key issue for firms attempting to collude is
    agreeing how to share the spoils.
  • In a multiunit ascending auction, bidders can
    use the early stages when prices are still low to
    signal their views about who should win which
    object, and then when consensus has been reached,
    tacitly agree to stop pushing prices up.
  • By contrast, bidders cannot easily achieve the
    same coordination in simultaneous sealed-bid or
    descending auctions, in which each player
    simultaneously makes at most a single best and
    final offer to each object.

65
Low reservation prices encourage collusion
  • Reducing the reserve price increase the
    potential gains from joint-bidding or colluding,
    because the gains from colluding are greater.
  • Therefore the auctioneer should set a
    reservation price that is higher than the
    opportunity cost of failing to sell the auctioned
    item if it reduces the probability that bidders
    will collude.

66
Entry and the provision of information about the
auctioned object
  • Should the auctioneer encourage more players to
    enter the auction?
  • Potential bidders could, for example, be
    encouraged to bid in an auction, by providing
    them with services that help them to value the
    object for sale.
  • Note that simply paying people to participate in
    the auction would not achieve any useful purpose,
    because anyone could accept the payment and then
    make a very low bid.

67
Encouraging entry in private valuation auctions
  • If another bidder enters a private valuation
    auction, the the level of the highest or the
    second highest valuation might increase.
  • In either case, the revenue from the auction
    would increase.
  • Therefore the expected revenue from holding a
    private valuation auction increases with the
    number of bidders.

68
Encouraging entry in common value auctions
  • The argument for encouraging participation is
    less definitive.
  • In an example discussed earlier we found that
    the auctioneer gains from having a (second)
    uninformed bidder enter the auction even though
    the uninformed bidder is indifferent between
    bidding or not.
  • However one can construct examples of common
    value auctions in which the winning bid falls as
    the number of bidders increases.

69
Encouraging entry to avoid collusion
  • The lower the number of bidders, the easier it
    is for them to reach a collusive agreement.
  • Thus another reason to encourage entry is to
    reduce the probability for facing a bidding
    cartel.

70
Summary and Synthesis
  • When comparing two (or more) auctions, we should
    consider the following questions
  • Are the auctions congruent, or if not, revenue
    equivalent?
  • Are the bidders risk neutral?
  • In private valuation auctions, are bidders
    drawing from the same probability distribution?
  • In common valuation auctions, are bidders drawing
    from the same distribution of signals?
  • Are the auctions symmetric?
  • Is collusion between bidders a possibility?
  • Should information about the auction be given to
    bidders?
  • Not all these questions have easy answers, but
    that is where the value of experiments is
    especially evident.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)