Title: Asset prices in the representativeagent economy with background risk
1Asset prices in the representative-agent economy
with background risk
- Andrei Semenov (York University)
2Introduction
- The standard consumption CAPM
- Problems
- a) The equity premium puzzle
- b) The risk-free rate puzzle
3- Generalizations
- a) Preference modifications
- b) State-dependent parameters
- c) Psychological models of preferences
- d) Incomplete consumption insurance
- Brav et al. (2002), Balduzzi and Yao (2007), and
Kocherlakota and Pistaferri (2009)
4Outline
- Consumption-Based Model with Background Risk
- The stochastic discount factor (SDF)
- Risk vulnerability and the asset pricing puzzles
- Risk aversion and the EIS under background risk
- Empirical Investigation
- The data
- The estimation procedure (conditional HJ
volatility bounds) - Estimation results
- Concluding Remarks
51. A Consumption-based asset pricing model with
background risk
- 1.1 The Stochastic Discount Factor (SDF)
- The representative agent faces (Franke et al.
(1998) and Poon and Stapleton (2005)) - The financial risk
- An independent, non-hedgeable, adverse
background risk (the losses from domestic
political turmoil, the inflation risk, an
uncertain income tax rate, the risk from natural
disasters, etc.)
6- In the presence of background risk, the
representative agent maximizes - is the representative-agents hedgeable
consumption in period . The
non-hedgeable consumption is
independent of both optimal consumption and the
risky payoff and has a non-positive expected
value.
7- One of the first-order conditions
- or
- This is the consumption CAPM with background
risk. The SDF - In the absence of background risk,
8- 1.2 The precautionary premium
- Following Kimball (1990)
- where is an
equivalent precautionary premium. - Assume , then
9- We can write the SDF as
- Assume that the utility function is CRRA
- The precautionary premium for the agent with
CRRA utility is hence
10- This implies that, with CRRA utility, for any t
- Where is the normalized variance of
- We need for marginal
utility to be well-defined. - The SDF is then
11- 1.3 Risk vulnerability and the asset pricing
puzzles - As introduced by Kihlstrom et al. (1981) and
Nachman (1982), define the following indirect
utility function - Gollier (2001) argues that, in the case of the
background risk with a non-positive mean
preferences exhibit risk vulnerability if and
only if the indirect utility function is more
concave than the original utility function, i.e.,
12- As shown by Gollier (2001), this inequality holds
if at least one of the following two conditions
is satisfied - (i) ARA is decreasing and convex and
- (ii) both ARA and AP are positive and decreasing
in wealth (standard risk aversion (Kimball
(1993)).
13- Risk vulnerability and the equity premium puzzle
- The consumption CAPM with background risk in
terms of - Assume
- Then
- If , then is less concave
than utility - and hence .
14- Risk vulnerability and the risk-free rate puzzle
- In the presence of background risk,
- Since and , then
- Because the agent is risk averse (i.e., utility
is concave), from this it immediately follows
that in each state the ratio of marginal
utilities at t1 and t under background risk
exceeds that in the no background risk case. As
this is true in each state, this is true in
expectation as well.
15- 1.4 Risk aversion and the EIS under background
risk - Suppose that at time t the agent faces the
background risk and a lottery with an uncertain
payoff . - For any distribution functions and
- Since and are independent, then
16- A Taylor series expansion of
around - and hence
- It then follows that
- implying
17- The RRA coefficient of the agent with utility
is then - Since is independent of ,
- and hence
18- Denote as the risk premium we would observe
if the utility curvature parameter were . - The proportion of the risk premium due to the
background risk in the total risk premium the
representative agent is ready to pay to avoid the
financial risk is then
19- Kimball (1992) defines the temperance premium
by the following condition - By analogy with the risk premium,
- The conditions and
(the necessary conditions for risk
vulnerability) imply that .
20- We have
- With power utility
- and therefore
21(No Transcript)
22- The EIS in the model with an independent
non-hedgeable background risk - Since the representative agent with utility
facing background risk has the same optimal
consumption plan as the representative agent with
utility in the no background risk
environment, we can suppose that - where and
- The model with background risk enables us to
disentangle the coefficient of pure RRA and
the EIS in the expected utility framework.
232. Empirical investigation
- 2.1 The data
- The consumption data
- Quarterly consumption data (consumption of
nondurables and services (NDS)) from the CEX (the
US Bureau of Labor Statistics) from 1980Q1 to
2003Q4. - We drop households
- a) that do not report or report a zero value of
consumption of food, consumption of nondurables
and services, or total consumption,
24- b) nonurban households, households residing in
student housing, households with incomplete
income responses, households that do not have a
fifth interview, and households whose head is
under 19 or over 75 years of age. - We consider four sets of households based on the
reported amount of asset holdings at the
beginning of a 12-month recall period in constant
2005 dollars - a) all households,
- b) households with total asset holdings gt 0,
- c) households with total asset holdings
1000, - d) households with total asset holdings 5000.
25- The returns data
- a) The nominal quarterly value-weighted market
capitalization-based decile index returns
(capital gain plus all dividends) on all stocks
listed on the NYSE, AMEX, and Nasdaq are from the
CRSP. -
- b) The nominal quarterly value-weighted returns
on the five and ten NYSE, AMEX, and Nasdaq
industry portfolios are from Kenneth R. French's
web page. - c) The nominal quarterly risk-free rate is the
3-month US Treasury Bill secondary market rate
from the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. - d) The real quarterly returns are calculated as
the quarterly nominal returns divided by the
3-month inflation rate based on the deflator
defined for NDS.
26(No Transcript)
27(No Transcript)
28(No Transcript)
29- 2.2 The estimation procedure
- We use HJ (1991) volatility bounds to assess the
empirical performance of three SDFs - 1. Standard SDF
- 2. The SDF in Brav et al. (2002)
- where is the household i's consumption
growth rate and
30- 3. The SDF in the consumption CAPM with
background risk - When estimating and
for all t
31- For each of the above SDFs, we test the
conditional Euler equations for the excess
returns on risky assets - and the risk-free rate
- Denote the error terms in the Euler equations as
- Thus, at the true parameter vector,
- where is a variable in the agent's time t
information set.
32- A lower volatility bound for admissible SDFs
, which have unconditional mean m and
satisfy - where is the unconditional variance-covariance
matrix of . - We look for the values of the SDF parameters, at
which a considered SDF satisfies the volatility
bound, i.e., - where
33- Denote as the utility curvature parameter
in . - The optimal value of the estimate of the
curvature parameter is - Denote as the instrument , for which
- Since
- or equivalently
- we estimate the subjective time discount factor
as
34- In the model with background risk, the effective
RRA coefficient differs from the utility
curvature parameter (the coefficient of pure
RRA) and is - We follow Kimball (1993) and Franke et al. (1998)
and assume that the background risk is
actuarially neutral, i.e., - Under this assumption, the estimate of the
effective RRA is
35(No Transcript)
36Concluding remarks
- Empirical evidence that, in contrast to the
previously proposed incomplete consumption
insurance models, the asset-pricing model with
the SDF calculated as the discounted ratio of
expectations of marginal utilities over the
non-hedgeable consumption states at two
consecutive dates jointly explains the
cross-section of risky asset excess returns and
the risk-free rate with economically plausible
values of the pure RRA coefficient and the
subjective time discount factor. - The results are robust across different sets of
stock-returns and threshold values in the
definition of asset holders.
37- Since the important components of the pricing
kernel are the first two unconditional moments of
the distribution of the non-hedgeable
consumption, this supports the hypothesis that
the independent non-hedgeable adverse background
risk can account for the market premium and the
return on the risk-free asset.