Title: Price Discrimination
1Price Discrimination
- Kowloon Technical School
- Vincent Ng
- 6AT (22)
2Definition
- When an identical good is sold to different
customers at different prices at the same time
but not for different cost
3Necessary Conditions for Price Discrimination
- The seller is a price searcher, facing a downward
sloping demand curve
- The seller is able to prevent resale of the
commodity among buyer
4Perfect Price Discrimination or First Degree
Price Discrimination
1. Given an individual demand curve
P()
A
- If a single price is charged, e.g. P and the
customer is allowed to buy any quantities he
desires, then he buys Q. He pays 0PBQ and enjoys
PAB amount of consumer surplus.
B
P
D
0
Q
Quantity
5Perfect Price Discrimination or First Degree
Price Discrimination
- Under perfect price discrimination, the custome
is charged a price that equals to his MUV for
each unit sold. If he buys Q units, he has to pay
0ABQ and enjoys no consumer surplus. Only for the
last unit bought, i.e. the 0Q unit, he pays 0P
which equals his MUV for that unit.
P()
A
B
P
D
0
Q
Quantity
6Perfect Price Discrimination or First Degree
Price Discrimination
- For perfect price discrimination, the seller
charges the same customer different prices for
different quantities of goods sold. The customer
is charged the maximum amount he is willing to
pay. This will leave him indifferent between
buying and not buying. The seller is able to
extract all consumer surplus form the customer.
P()
A
B
P
D
0
Q
Quantity
7Perfect Price Discrimination or First Degree
Price Discrimination
2. The profit-maximizing equilibrium output for
a perfect price discriminator
a. Under perfect price discrimination, the
demand curve facing the monopolist measures the
marginal revenue from selling the product, i.e. P
MUV MR. It is because the seller lowers the
price on the marginal units but not on the
infra-marginal units. Thus, the price charged for
an unit also measures it marginal revenue. The
demand curve is therefore the marginal revenue
curve.
8Perfect Price Discrimination or First Degree
Price Discrimination
- Give the demand curve, D and the cost function
P()
MC
A
- The perfect price discriminator maximize its
profits by producing at Q where it marginal cost
of production equals its marginal revenue (MC
MR) and equals the price of the output unit sold
at point B. - Total revenue obtained is 0ABQ and equals the
customers total use value for 0Q amount of the
good. Consumer surplus is zero as the customers
total payment (TEV) equals his total use value
(TUV) for the good bought.
B
p
D MR
0
Quantity
Q
9Perfect Price Discrimination or First Degree
Price Discrimination
P()
MC
A
ii. For the last unit sold, the price charged is
P and the infra-marginal units, they are all sold
at prices higher than P.
B
p
- Production is efficient for a perfect price
discriminator because at Q, P ( MUV) MC. It
maximizes its profits and produces at an optimal
or efficient level of output.
D MR
0
Quantity
Q
10Some Comments On Perfect Price Discrimination
1. The above tells what perfect price
discrimination is. In the real world,
perfect price discrimination is rarely found. It
assumes the sellers knows the demand curves of it
customers and their own production and cost
functions perfectly well.
In practice, perfect price discrimination is
never prefect. Information is costly to
obtain. As demand curve is downward sloping, the
seller simply discriminates by charging a lower
price for successively more units sold to an
individual customer. The price charged for each
unit may not equal the maximum amount that the
customer is willing to pay (i.e. his marginal use
value). This will leave him some consumer
surplus, the seller may not be able to extract
all consumer surplus from the customer.
An imperfect way to extract consumer surplus is
sometimes called the second degree price
discrimination. Quantity discounts, declining
rates, group rates, and multi-part pricing are
examples.
11Some Comments On Perfect Price Discrimination
2. Comparing to a simple monopoly, perfect price
discriminator can produce and sell more without
lowering the price for the previous units sold,
It produces a MC P and its output level is
allocatively efficient.
a. To be consistent with the axiom of
maximization, we then ask the question why a real
world monopolist does not always adopt perfect
price discrimination. What stops it from doing
so? Transaction costs. We know that using price
discrimination is costly, Thus only when costs
allow, then price discrimination is profitable.
12Some Comments On Perfect Price Discrimination
b. This , it is argued that a simple monopolist
may not be inefficient. There, the accusation
that a simple monopolist produces at P gt MC and
is inefficient may not be right.
A maximizing seller adopts single pricing and
leads to a dead-weight welfare loss may not be
inefficient if we consider the transaction costs
involved in using other alternative pricing
arrangements, The welfare loss associated with
single pricing may bit be a loss if we consider
the savings in transaction costs in adopting
other pricing arrangements
13Some Comments On Perfect Price Discrimination
- Perfect price discrimination may be a necessary
pricing arrangement for a firm to cover costs and
survive. There are two such possible situation.
14Some Comments On Perfect Price Discrimination
- The average cost curve is everywhere above the
market demand curve. If a single price is
charged, the seller always suffer loss and
therefore will soon be out of business.
P()
AC
b
d
c
If it practises price discrimination, it
willcover its costs of production. The total
cost of producing 0Q is 0cbQ and the total
revenue under perfect price discrimination is
0deQ. As long as its total revenue is greater
than it total cost, i.e. TR gt TC, the firm can
survive and remain in business.
a
e
D MR
Quantity
0
Q
15Some Comments On Perfect Price Discrimination
- In the case of natural monopoly, perfect price
discrimination will result in efficient
production and the firm can cover costs and
survive without demanding subsidies from the
government.
P()
d
b
AC
c
a
MC
e
D MR
If the natural monopolist produces at 0Q,
charging a single price 0c, then it suffers a per
unit loss of be in this figure. If it practises
perfect price discrimination, it obtains a
revenue of 0deQ and is able to cover its total
cost of production 0cbQ.
Quantity
0
Q
16Third Degree Price Discrimination
- The third degree price discriminator charges
different prices in different markets for the
same good.
- The seller must be able to separate its customers
into groups with different price elasticities
of demand and keep the m separate at low cost.
The differences in price elasticities among
customers must be identfiable at low enough cost
to make third degree discrimination profitable. - A high price is charged in the market with
less elastic demand and a low price is charged in
the market with more elastic demand.
- It may discriminates according to age, income,
location or sex.
17Third Degree Price Discrimination
- The profit-maximizing equilibrium output for a
third degree price discriminator
Price
- The equi-marginal revenue principle If a seller
is able to sell its output in different markets,
then it should distribute and sell its output in
each market in such a way that their marginal
revenues are the same in all markets
30
D2
20
D1
MR2
MR1
Q
Q
25
100
0
- Suppose there are two markets of different demand
curves with correspondingly different marginal
revenue curves.
Market II
Market I
18Third Degree Price Discrimination
ii. Initially the seller produces 125 units and
it sells 25 units in Market II and 100 units in
Market I. The marginal revenue obtained for the
last unit in Market II is 30. The marginal
revenue obtained for the last unit in Market I is
20.
Price
30
D2
20
D1
- Since the marginal revenues in the two market
differ, the seller can raise its total revenue by
switching the sale of output from the market of
low marginal revenue to the one of high revenue -
MR2
MR1
Q
Q
25
100
0
Market II
Market I
The one-hundredth unit from Market I will be
transferred to Market II. Total output remains at
125 units but there is an increase in revenue of
about 10. Revenue falls by 20 in Market I but
rises by 30 in Market II.
19Third Degree Price Discrimination
- Suppose there are 2 different markets of
different price elasticities of demand, ?1 and
?2. The costs in identifying the two market are
low enough for the seller to practise third
degree price discrimination.
- According to the equi-marginal revenue principle,
the necessary condition for profit-maximization
is
1
1
MR1 P1 (1 - )
MR2 P2 (1 - )
?1
?2
1
1
MR1 MR2
P1 (1 - ) P2 (1 - )
?1
?2
1
P1
(1 - )
?2
1
P2
(1 - )
?1
20Third Degree Price Discrimination
- To simply, assume a constant cost function and D1
is more elastic than D2
Price
P2
- To maximize profits, the profit maximizing output
for each market is given by the respective
intersection of the marginal revenue curves with
the common marginal cost curve.
P1
MC AC
D2
D1
MR2
MR1
Q
Q
0
Q2
Q1
Market II
Market I
21Third Degree Price Discrimination
ii. The third degree price discriminator will
produce Q1 for Market I and Q2 for Market II.
Price
P2
iii. It sells the same product to consumers with
a less elastic demand at a higher price than that
charged to the consumers with a more elastic
demand.
P1
MC AC
D2
D1
MR2
MR1
Q
Q
0
Q2
Q1
Market II
Market I
22Third Degree Price Discrimination
- Compared to a simple monopolist a third degree
price discriminator will produce more output and
supply goods to weak markets.
Price
P2
Since a third degree price discriminator can sell
the same good at different prices in markets of
different price elasticities, it supplies goods
in both the strong market and the weak
market. A simple monopolist will only sell in the
strong market. Charging a single price, P2,
result in zero quantity demanded in the weak
market.
P1
MC AC
D2
D1
MR2
MR1
Q
Q
0
Q2
Q1
Strong Market
Weak Market
23Price Discrimination and Information Costs
- The differences in prices between goods sold in
the tourist and the non-tourist areas can be
explained by difference in information costs
between tourist and non-tourists.
- Tourists are outsiders and do not know the place.
They face a higher information cost in purchases
than local people. Tourists find it more costly
to search sellers, check quality and compare
prices. Thus, they are likely to be prepared to
pay a higher price for a good than local people
in the tourist areas.
- You might argue that their price elasticities of
demand are low because it is costly for tourists
to find substitutes available in the non-tourist
areas. This is a case of third degree price
discrimination. - Or you may argue that the higher price paid
is the result of difference in information costs.
For a tourist, the full price or cost he pays
is higher than the local residents owing to his
higher information costs.
24Price Differentials VS Price Discrimination
- Price differentials of the same good may not
imply price discrimination, they may reflect the
difference in costs or the associated services
and attributes that come with a commodity.
25Price Differentials VS Price Discrimination
- Sometimes, a good sold at the same price may
mean price discrimination! - When China began her four modernization
programmes, foreigners travelling in China had to
use the Foreign Exchange Certificate which
officially is equivalent to Renminbi. The FEC is
convertible into foreign currencies at officially
controlled exchange rates the RMB is not
similarly convertible. As a result, although the
FEC and the RMB have the same nominal value,
dollar for dollar the FEC is worth significantly
more than the RMB in the black or free
market.
26Price Differentials VS Price Discrimination
a. If both the foreigners and local Chinese are
asked to pay the same nominal price for a good,
then the seller is practising price
discrimination, The foreigners pay a higher price
than the local Chinese for the same good.
- Ironically, if the foreigners are paying in FEC
for a good, then the local Chinese who are paying
in RMB have to add a premium. Actually, they pay
the same price for the same good and there is no
price discrimination. The price differential may
simply reflect the higher value of FEC in the
black exchange rate market. - For instance, if the black market price of
one dollar FEC is RMB 1.5, then a lemonade sold
for five dollars FEC will be worth RMB 7.5. That
is , a premium of RMB 2.5 is added if one pays
in RMB.
27Price Differentials VS Price Discrimination
- It is found that the same type of products are
sold at different labels as economy, standard and
deluxe and at different prices. - It is argued that the seller practises third
degree price discrimination based on different
income classes rich people buy the deluxe model
and the poor people buy the economy model. The
argument is wrong because (i) the products are
not the same and (ii) the market is not
separated as a poor consumer may buy the deluxe
model while a rich consumer may buy the economy
model. - Do not confuse the argument with the type of
price discrimination practised by the medical
doctors. Patients from different income groups
are charged differently for the same treatment.
Third degree price discrimination may exist
unless the seller can separate its customers into
different income groups and sell the deluxe model
to the rich only. And those who buy the economy
models at a lower price must not be able to
resell the goods to the rich.
28The END