Title: Managerial Economics Final Suggested answers
1Managerial Economics FinalSuggested answers
- MBS, Term 2, 2004
- Paul Kerin
21a) Pay-off matrix M
Joint optimum
-0.125, 2.375
1.75, 1.75
H Retailer A L
0.5, 0.5
2.375, -0.125
L H Retailer B
Nash equilibrium
31a) Pay-off matrix (cont)
- Pay-off calculationsLH -0.125
0.25(10-2.50) 2 2.375 1.75(5-2.50)
2HH 1.75 0.5(10-2.50) 2HL the
converse of LHLL 0.5 1(5-2.5) 2
OutcomesNash equilibrium LL, as L is the
dominant strategy of each player at LL, neither
player has an incentive to move, given, the other
players choiceCo-operative outcome HH, as
this is the joint optimum that is, the sum of
the players pay-offs (1.751.75 3.5) is
greater than that in any other cell
41a) Pay-off matrix (cont)
- Common mistakes
- Very few!
- Confusing Nash equilibrium with joint optimum
they are not the same thing - Calculation errors
51b) Price-matching policy M
Joint optimum
The only payoff changes vs. a)
1.125, 0.5
1.75, 1.75
H Retailer A L
0.5, 0.5
2.375, -0.125
Now there is no Nash equilibrium
L H Retailer B
Ignores things such as cost of advertising
good answers worked out the maximum advertising
cost for which the policy would still create
value
61b) Price-matching policy (cont)
- Pay-off calculations
- Only the LH pay-offs are affected
- 1.125 0.5(5-2.50) 0.25(10-2.50) 2
- 0.5 1(5-2.50) - 2
OutcomesNash equilibrium no longer
existsLikely outcome HHIf B believes that A
will always go high (ie, As commitment is
credible), then B will go H, as 1.75 gt
0.5 Should A introduce? YesAs pay-off will
increase by 1.25M (from 0.125 to 1.125). A will
be better-off as long as the advertising cost is
lt 1.25M
71b) Price matching policy (cont)
- Common mistakes
- Incorrect calculation of how the payoffs change
- Lack of logic in determining how the payoff
changes affect the likely outcome
82a) Maximum profit
- P 823 4QD MR 823 8QD (same
intercept, twice slope) - MR MC 823 8QD 15 QD
101 (check this is feasible, as
101 lt capacity (275) ) - P 823 4101 (plugging QD 101 into demand
curve) - P 419
- Profit QD (P MC) 101(419 15)
Maximum profit 40,804 - Explanation
- P/MC 419/15 27.9 a huge markup. Why?
Elasticity of demand at profit - maximising point is 1.037 eD (DQ/DP)P/Q
(-1/4)(419/101) -1.037 - As the elasticity is very close to 1, the
profit-maximising mark-up is very high (from
the inverse elasticity rule P/MC 1/(11/eD)
92a) Maximum profit (cont)
- Common mistakes
- Maximising revenue, rather than profit
- Forgetting to explain
102b) Competitor profits
- It is not clear from the question whether this is
Bertrand or Cournot fortunately, - it doesnt matter as the capacity constraint
becomes binding - If assume Cournot
- P 1,223 4QD
- MRDEF 1,223 8QDEF 4QGHI (same
intercept, twice slope on own
output, same
slope on competitor output) - As this is symmetrical (same MC), each firms
output (call it Q) will be the same, ie
QQDEFQGHI. Therefore, MRDEF simplifies
toMRDEF 1,223 12QMRDEF MC 1,223
12Q 15 Q 100.67, but this is gt
75 and therefore not feasible. While each firm
would like to produce 100.67 units, they each
face a 75 unit capacity constraint QDEF
QGHI 75 - P 1,223 8(7575) (plugging QDEF QGHI 75
into demand curve) - P 623
- QDEF profit QDEF(P MC) 75(623 15)
DEF profit 45,600 GHI profit
45,600 (by symmetry) total profit 91,200
(45,6002)
112b) Competitor profits (cont)
- If assume Bertrand
- P MC 15 but, from demand curve, at P15,
QD (1,223-15)/4 302, but this is gt 150 (
total capacity) - Therefore, capacity will determine quantity
produced and price will be given - by the demand curve at that quantity so we get
the same result as when we - assumed Cournot
-
122b) Competitor profits (cont)
- Explanation
- Total industry profits have more than doubled,
from 40,804 in a) to 91,200 in b). While a move
from monopoly to a Bertrand or Cournot situation
would normally reduce profits, this has been more
than offset by 2 factors- increased demand
(higher price at any quantity)- capacity
constraint, which reduces the supply increase
that would normally occur in moving from
monopoly to Bertrand or Cournot and therefore
stops price declining - Common mistakes
- Ignoring the capacity constraint
- Assuming it is definitely Cournot or definitely
Bertrand (we dont know so we need test what
happens under each) - Plugging only one competitors quantity (rather
than total quantity) into the demand curve to
determine price - Forgetting to explain
132c) Tough price competition
- It is now Bertrand, so PMC P 15
- P 423 4QD QD (423-P)/4
(423-15)/4 102 - Total QD 102, which is feasible as it is lt
total capacity of 150 - So each produces 51 units (102/2)
- Each firms profit is zero, as PMC
- Common mistake assuming Cournot, rather than
Bertrand (tough price - competition Bertrand)
-
142d) Acquisition WTP P
- DEF has 2 options buy GHI or dont buy it (DEF
could also be bought by GHI but, given - symmetry, GHIs WTP for DEF will be the same as
DEFs WTP for GHI) - If DEF doesnt buy GHI, its profits (BATNA) will
be zero (from d) - If DEF does buy GHI, it will act as a
monopolistP 423 4QD MR 423
8QD (same intercept, twice the slope)MR MC
423 8QD 15 QD 51 - P 423 451 (plugging QD 51 into the demand
curve) P 219DEF profit QD (P
MC) 51(219 15) 10,404 - Therefore, DEFs WTP for GHI 10,404 ( the
profit difference between the 2 options) - GHIs WTS 0 ( profit it earns if doesnt sell)
- Expected price (when they split the surplus
50/50) 5,202 (10,404/2)
Ignoring a possible further gain could sell
one of the plants, as QD is now lt the capacity of
one plant
152d) Acquisition WTP P (cont)
- Common mistakes
- Using the wrong model to calculate profit if no
acquisition is made - Using the wrong model to calculate profit if the
acquisition is made - Assuming that DEF will have to pay all of its WTP
or only GHIs WTS, without explanation (rather
than a 50/50 split of the surplus)
163a) 3b) Minimum sell prices
- Minimum sell price WTS
- 3a) For EG /Mwh
- MC of electricity (if no breakdown) 20.00
- Breakdown cost (1.61M/1M) 1.60
- Total expected cost 21.60
- Therefore, WTS 21.60/Mwh
- 3b) For each of the competitors /Mwh
- MC of electricity (if no breakdown) 20.00
- Breakdown cost (3.71M/1M) 3.70
- Total expected cost 23.70
- Therefore, WTS 23.70/Mwh
- So competitors would be willing to provide a
guarantee, but only for Pgt23.70/Mwh - Common mistake ignoring breakdown cost
173c) Which bids?
Bid Competitor Calculation profit if win
M (Q(P-MC)) A 0 1(20-20) B
0.6 1(20.60-20) C -3.1 1(20.6-23.70
) D -0.1 1(23.60-23.70)
Only bids A and B would not lose money, but only
B would make a positive economic profit
183c) Which bids? (cont)
Bid EG profit Calculation if win
M (Q(P-MC)) A 0 1(20-20) B
0.6 1(20.60-20) C -1.0 1(20.60-21.6
0) D 2.0 1(23.60-21.60)
193c) Which bids? (cont)
- EG should not bid C (as it would lose money) and
there is no point in bidding A, as it wouldnt
make any money so we are left with B and D - If EG can only submit one bid, it should choose
bid D - D is more profitable than B - His competitors cannot afford to submit bid D,
because they would lose money so they will bid
B. - AS prefers bid D to bid B, because they expect
their costs to be 23.6 million instead of 24.30
million, so he will win if he bids D.
203d) Revise bid?
Bid GI profit Calculation if win
M (Q(P-MC)) A -0.5 1(20-20)
0.5 B 0.1 1(20.60-20) 0.5 C
-1.4 1(20.6-21.50) 0.5 D
1.6 1(23.60-21.50) 0.5
In contrast to in 3c) GI is now much more likely
to submit bid D, as it is now very profitable
21.50 20 (1.51M/1M)
213d) Revise bid? (cont)
Payoff calculations You can write down a game
table and find the Nash equilibrium (when there
are two choices consideredbid B and bid D). But
its pretty clear that both have a dominant
strategy of bidding D its preferred by the
customer, and its more profitable for them. So
they each bid D, and each wins with 50
probability. You should not revise your bid.
223d) Revise bid? pay-off matrixM
EG B D
0.3, 0.3
0, 2.0
B GI D
1.6, 0
0.8, 1.0
dominantstrategy for both is bid D