Title: Choice Modelling
1Choice Modelling
2Overview
- Background
- Examples
- Survey instrument design
- Survey analysis
- Future direction of research
3Background
- The value of market goods is generally uncovered
in economic markets through the interaction of
supply and demand.
Price
Supply
CS for environmental good is total area under
demand curve
PM
Demand
Quantity
QM
4Background
- Generally, there is market failure for
environmental goods and services - Externalities
- Public good characteristics
- Lack of fully defined property rights
5Background
- Although there is market failure (and therefore
no market price) for environmental goods - people do attain utility (value) from
environmental goods. - It is important that we account for these values
when we make decisions about environmental
resources. - Environmental valuation aims to measure the
consumer surplus for environmental goods.
6Total Economic Value
7Environmental Valuation Techniques
- Revealed preference approaches.
- Observes actions within surrogate markets
(travel, house prices) taken in response to
environmental change. - Largely restricted to use values
- Examples Travel Cost Method, Hedonic Price
Method. - Stated preference approaches.
- Attempts to elicit preferences by experiments or
questionnaires - May estimate both use and passive use values
- Examples Contingent Valuation Method, Choice
experiments. - Combined approaches
- Draws on the benefits of the above approaches
- Examples Contingent behaviour
8Choice experiments overview
- Survey based approach
- Introductory material
- Environment good specific questions
- Descriptions of hypothetical for the
environmental good and method of provision - Choice tasks
- Socio-economic and attitudinal data
9CE choice task
- Respondents are required to consider a series of
choice tasks. - Each choice task comprises
- three choice options (including a status quo)
- each choice option is described in terms of
policy attributes and levels - One attribute is a payment vehicle (increase in
tax) - Attributes and levels assigned according to an
experimental design
10Choice experiment example Forest recreation.
11Choice task example Coastal defence amenity at
Borth.
Choice
12Borth example attributes and levels
- Visual timber groynes,
- rock groynes,
- Multi-purpose reef
- Wall SQ,
- raise height
- Surf SQ,
- improved surf
- Amenity SQ,
- calm waters
- Tax 5 levels
13Experimental design
- In the CE, we need to create a survey design that
allows us to compare all levels of all
attributes. - A full factorial design would require 32225
1080 comparisons practically challenging! - Therefore use of orthogonal main effects
fractional factorial design.
14Fractional factorial designs
- involve the selection of a particular subset
(e.g. fraction) of a complete factorial, so that
particular effects can be estimated as
efficiently as possible. - Fractional designs, however, involve
- a loss of statistical information.
- requires assumptions about the non-significance
of higher order effects, i.e. the interaction
between two or more attributes.
15Fractional factorial design (23)
16Fractional factorial designs
- Fraction 1 is the irregular fraction, i.e. ABC
-1 - A -BC
- B -AC
- C -AB
- Fraction 2 is the regular fraction, i.e. ABC
1 - A BC
- B AC
- C AB
- In the design of CE, we use the regular fraction.
- The fractional factorial design now only requires
4 treatments (instead of 8 in the full
factorial). - In the Borth example, factorial designs allow us
to reduce the number of treatments from 1080 to
24!
17Fractional factorial designs
- In the 23 CE example which has 4 treatments
- Our estimate of the main effect (A) could be the
estimate of A or the two-way interaction BC or
some other combination of A and BC. - Thus, we will only estimate A if and only if the
two-way interaction BC is not significant (equals
zero). - Thus, we need to avoid collinearity in our
attributes within the CE design, i.e. we need to
ensure that our attributes are not linked to each
other. - This assumption is known as the Independence of
Irrelevant Alternatives (IIA)
18Choice set design
- In designing a CE choice set, we have
- Status quo (described as existing levels of
attributes) - Choice A (described according to a fractional
factorial design) - Choice B (described according to a different
fractional factorial design)
19Choice set design (23)
Right is the 23 fractional factorial design.
Below is the design of 1 of the 4 choice sets.
20Choice set design
- Generally, respondents can cope with 8 choice
tasks within a single questionnaire. - In the Borth example, the 3123 51 design gave
rise to 24 choice sets. The choice tasks were
therefore split between 3 sub samples (each
receiving 8 choice tasks).
21Choice experiments theory
- Lancastrian theory of consumer choice
- The attributes of a good is important in consumer
purchase decisions. - Random utility theory
- Where
- U is respondents utility
- V is observable component of U
- ? is unobservable component of U
- ? is the coefficient of X
- X is a vector of attributes of alternatives
socio-economic and attitudinal characteristics of
respondents
22Choice experiments theory
- If Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives
(IIA) assumption holds, we can solve with
Conditional logit model
23Choice experiments theory
- IIA violations (Hausman test), use random
parameters logit (RPL) model - RPL utility function
- Where ?in ? f (?n?) is a random term with zero
mean and a general distribution, with a general
density function f and ? are fixed parameters of
the distribution (e.g. mean and variance).
24Choice experiments theory
- RPL model
- The RPL choice probabilities do not have a
mathematical closed form. Requires simulation to
solve.
25Choice experiments theory
26Data preparation
27NLOGIT coding
- nlogit
- Lhschoice
- Model
- U(c1) bvis1vis1 bvis2vis2
bwallwall bsurfsurf bamenityamenity
btaxtax bnsurfnosurfas - U(c2) bvis1vis1 bvis2vis2
bwallwall bsurfsurf bamenityamenity
btaxtax bnsurfnosurfas - U(SQ) B0 bvis1vis1 bvis2vis2 bwallwall
bsurfsurf bamenityamenity btaxtax
bnsurfnosurfas - Wald
- labels b1, b2, b3, b4, b5, b6, b7, b8, b9
?b7cost - start b
- var varb
- fn1 (b2b3) / b7 ? timber
- fn1 -(b2)/b7 ? rock
- fn1 -(b3)/b7 ? reef
- fn1 -(b4b8)/b7 ? wall
- fn1 -(b5 b9)/b7 ? surf
- fn1 -(b6)/b7 ? amenity
28NLOGIT output
- Normal exit from iterations. Exit status0.
- ---------------------------------------------
- Discrete choice (multinomial logit) model
- Maximum Likelihood Estimates
- Model estimated Jun 08, 2005 at 035211PM.
- Dependent variable Choice
- Weighting variable None
- Number of observations 960
- Iterations completed 5
- Log likelihood function -887.5745
- Log-L for Choice model -887.57452
- R21-LogL/LogL Log-L fncn R-sqrd RsqAdj
- Constants only -950.2473 .06595 .06254
- Response data are given as ind. choice.
- Number of obs. 960, skipped 0 bad obs.
- ---------------------------------------------
- ----------------------------------------------
---------- - Variable Coefficient Standard Error
b/St.Er.PZgtz - ----------------------------------------------
----------
29NLOGIT output RPL
- Random Parameters Logit Model
- ----------------------------------------------
---------- - Variable Coefficient Standard Error
b/St.Er.PZgtz - ----------------------------------------------
---------- - Random parameters in utility functions
- BWALL -.6746982765 .31024699
-2.175 .0297 - BSURF .1912226937 .22963670
.833 .4050 - Nonrandom parameters in utility
functions - B0 -1.243803846 .17339223
-7.173 .0000 - BVIS1 -.4642925510 .82626493E-01
-5.619 .0000 - BVIS2 .7506976836 .11040487
6.799 .0000 - BAMENITY .4226909308 .11772520
3.590 .0003 - BTAX -.1470164418E-01 .34102835E-02
-4.311 .0000 - Heterogeneity in mean,
ParameterVariable - BWALLOW 1.111014897 .36629910
3.033 .0024 - BWALSUR -.1622615622 .35474299
-.457 .6474 - BSURLOW -.2020528914 .26123642
-.773 .4393 - BSURSUR 1.030179784 .32694115
3.151 .0016
30Results Conditional logit model
31Results Implicit prices
32Key observations
- Visual timber groyne negative
- Visual rock groyne negative
- Visual reef positive
- Family amenity positive
33Key observations
- Model 1 seawall and improved surf were
insignificant - Model 2 (lower) and 3 (upper)
- Seawall now significant.
- Lower Borth want generally want sea wall
- Upper Borth dont.
- Model 4 (non-surfer) and 5 (surfer)
- Surf conditions now significant for surfers, who
want improved surf - Non-surfers still insignificant
34Amenity value associated with coastal protection
proposals at Borth
35Future directions of CE research
- Heterogeneity of preferences
- RPL
- Latent class analysis
- Benefits transfer
- Combining methods