Title: International Finance
1International Finance
Academy of Economic Studies Faculty of
International Business and Economics
- Lecture V
- Elasticity and Absorption Approaches to the
Balance of Payments
Lect. Cristian PAUN Email cpaun_at_ase.ro URL
http//www.finint.ase.ro
2Introduction
- Current account and trade account balance are
very important for general equilibrium of an
economy - There are two models that investigate the impact
of exchange-rate changes on the current account
position of a country these are popularly known
as the elasticity approach and the absorption
approach - The two theories try to answer to a very
important question will a devaluation (or
depreciation) of the exchange rate lead to a
reduction of a current account deficit? - The answer to this question is of crucial
importance because if an exchange-rate change
cannot be relied upon to ensure adjustment of the
current account, then policy-makers will have to
rely on other instruments to improve the position.
3The Elasticity Approach to the Balance of Payments
- This approach provides an analysis of what
happens to the current account balance when the
country devalues its currency. - The analysis was pioneered by Alfred Marshall,
Abba Lerner and later extended by Joan Robinson
(1937) and Fritz Machlup (1955). - Assumptions
- The theory focuses on demand conditions
- The theory assumes that the supply elasticities
for the domestic export good and foreign import
good are perfectly elastic, so that changes in
demand volumes have no effect on prices - These assumptions mean that domestic and foreign
prices are fixed so that any changes in relative
prices are caused only by changes in the nominal
exchange rate.
4The model of Elasticity Approach
- The current account balance (CA) when expressed
in terms of the domestic currency is given by - where P is the domestic price level, Xv is the
volume of domestic exports, S is the exchange
rate (domestic currency units per unit of foreign
currency), P is the foreign price level and Mv
is the volume of imports. - We shall set the domestic and foreign price
levels at unity, the value of domestic exports
(PXy) is given by X, while the foreign currency
value of imports (PMV) is given by M
5The model of Elasticity Approach
At this point we introduce two definitions the
price elasticity of demand for exports ?x, is
defined as the percentage change in exports over
the percentage change in price as represented by
the percentage change in the exchange rate this
gives
6The model of Elasticity Approach
- If the price elasticity of demand for imports ?m
is defined as the percentage change in imports
over the percentage change in their price as
represented by the percentage change in the
exchange rate
Substituting we obtain
7The model of Elasticity Approach
Assuming that we initially have balanced trade
X/SM 1, and rearranging yields
This equation is known as the MarshallLerner
condition and says that starting from a position
of equilibrium in the current account, a
devaluation will improve the current account
that is, dCA/dS gt 0, only if the sum of the
foreign elasticity of demand for exports and the
home country elasticity of demand for imports is
greater than unity, that is, ?x ?m gt 1. If the
sum of these two elasticities is less than unity
then a devaluation will lead to a deterioration
of the current account.
8Example
- Before devaluation the sterling-dollar exchange
rate is 0.50/1 (2/1), whereas after
devaluation the sterling-dollar exchange rate is
0.666/1 (1.50/1), a 33 per cent devaluation. - The price of one unit of UK exports is 1, and
the price of one unit of US exports is 5. - The volume of UK exports is 100 units and UK
Imports 40 units
9Example
- Case 1 Devaluation leads to a CA deficit
- Case 2 Devaluation leads to a CA deficit
10Example
- Case 3 Devaluation leads to a CA surplus
11The price and volume effect on BoP
- The price effect exports become cheaper
measured in foreign currency a UK export earns
only 1.50 post-devaluation compared to 2 prior
to devaluation. Imports become more expensive
measured in the home currency, each unit of
imports cost 2.50 prior to the devaluation but
costs 3.33 post-devaluation. The price effect
clearly contributes to a worsening of the UK
current account. - The volume effect the fact that exports become
cheaper should encourage an increased volume of
exports, and the fact that imports become more
expensive should lead to a decreased volume
of imports. The volume effect clearly contributes
to improving the current account. - The net effect depends upon whether the price or
volume effect dominates (see examples for the net
effect).
12Stern Condition
- A more complicated formula can be derived which
allows for supply elasticities of exports and
imports of less than infinity (is not perfectly
elastic). - Given the assumption of less than infinite supply
elasticity conditions and assuming initially
balanced trade, Stern (1973) has shown that a
more complicated condition needs to be satisfied
namely, the balance of payments will improve
following a devaluation if
where ex is the domestic supply elasticity of the
export good and em is the foreign supply
elasticity for its export good (the domestic
country's imports).
13Interpretation for Stern Condition
- The effect of less than infinite supply
elasticities is to make the required demand
elasticities less stringent in the sense that the
current account may improve even if the sum of
the demand elasticities is less than unity. - If the supply elasticities of exports and imports
are less than infinite, an increase in demand for
exports will lead to some rise in the domestic
price of exports which will give an additional
boost to export revenues. - The fall in the demand for foreign imports will
have the effect of reducing the foreign currency
price of imports so lowering import expenditure.
14Empirical evidences on elasticity
Source Gylfason (1987), European Economic
Review, vol. 31, p. 377.
15Empirical evidences on elasticity
Source Gylfason (1987), European Economic
Review, vol. 31, p. 377.
16Empirical evidences on elasticities
- The possibility that a devaluation may lead to a
worsening rather than improvement in the balance
of payments led to much research into empirical
estimates of the elasticity of demand for exports
and imports. - Economists divided up into two camps popularly
known as 'elasticity optimists' who believed that
the sum of these two elasticities tended to
exceed unity, and 'elasticity pessimists' who
believed that these elasticities tended to less
than unity. - It was argued that a devaluation may work better
for industrialized countries than for developing
countries - Many developing countries are heavily dependent
upon imports so that their price elasticity of
demand for imports is likely to be very low. - For industrialized countries that have to face
competitive export markets, the price elasticity
of demand for their exports may be quite elastic.
17Empirical evidences on elasticities
- The implication of the Marshall-Lerner condition
is that devaluation may be a cure for some
countries balance-of-payments deficits but not
for others. - A summary by Gylfason (1987) of ten econometric
studies undertaken between 1969 and 1981 has
shown that the MarshallLerner condition is
fulfilled for all of the 15 industrial and nine
developing countries surveyed, and the results
are shown in the next slide - Another study made by Artus and Knight (1984) has
shown that up to a period of six months,
estimated price elasticities are invariably so
low that the MarshallLerner conditions are not
fulfilled. - Krugman (1991) in an analysis of the effects of a
sharp depreciation of the US dollar during 19857
found a J-curve effect for the US current account
(the deficit initially rose in both absolute
terms and as a percentage of US gross national
product, but after a lag of approximately two
years it improved with long-run elasticities for
imports and exports summing to 1.9 in excess of
that required by the Marshall-Lerner condition.)
18J-Curve
- A general consensus accepted by most economists
is that elasticities are lower in the short run
than in the long run, in which case the
Marshall-Lerner conditions may only hold in the
medium to long run. - Goldstein and Kahn (1985), in an excellent survey
of the empirical literature, conclude that in
general long-run elasticities (greater than two
years) are approximately twice as much as
short-run elasticities (06 months). - Further, the short-run elasticities generally
fail to sum to unity while the long-run
elasticities almost always sum to greater than
unity. - The possibility that in the short run the
MarshallLerner condition may not be fulfilled
although it generally holds over the longer run
leads to the phenomenon of what is popularly
known as the J-curve effect
19J-Curve Effect
20Explanations for J-Curve Time Lag for Consumers
- A time lag in consumer responses
- It takes time for consumers in both the devaluing
country and the rest of the world to respond to
the changed competitive situation. - Domestic consumers will be worried about issues
other than the price change such as the
reliability and reputation of domestic produced
goods as compared to the foreign imports - Foreign consumers may be reluctant to switch away
from domestically produced goods towards the
exports of the devaluing country.
21Explanations for J-Curve A Time Lag for
Producers
- A time lag in producer responses
- Even though a devaluation improves the
competitive position of exports it will take time
for domestic producers to expand production of
exportables. - Orders for imports are normally made well in
advance and such contracts are not readily
cancelled in the short run. - Producers will be reluctant to cancel orders for
vital inputs and raw materials. (the waiting list
for a Boeing aeroplane can be over five years,
and it is most unlikely that a British airline
will cancel the order just because the pound has
been devalued) - The hedging opportunities for payments
22Explanations for J-Curve - Imperfect competition
- A time lag due to imperfect competition
- Building up a share of foreign markets can be a
time-consuming and costly business. - foreign exporters may be very reluctant to lose
their market share in the devaluing country and
might respond to the loss in their
competitiveness by reducing their export prices - foreign import competing industries may react to
the threat of increased exports by the devaluing
country by reducing prices in their home markets,
limiting the amount of additional exports by the
devaluing country. - Many imports are used as inputs for exporting
industries, and the increased price of imports
may lead to higher wage costs as workers seek
compensation for higher import prices
23The Absorption Approach to the Balance of Payments
- One of the major defects of the elasticity
approach is that it is based upon the assumption
that all other things are equal. - Any changes in export and import volumes will by
definition have implications for national income
and consequently income effects need to be
incorporated in a more comprehensive analysis of
the effects of a devaluation (example with a
economic exposure vs transaction exposure). - National Income is
24The Absorption Approach to the Balance of Payments
- Previous equation says that the current account
(CA) represents the difference between domestic
output and domestic absorption. - A current account surplus means that domestic
output exceeds domestic spending, while a current
account deficit means that domestic output is
less than domestic spending. - Transforming equation into difference form yields
- This equation means that the effects of a
devaluation on the current account will depend
upon how it affects national income relative to
domestic absorption.
If a devaluation raises domestic income relative
to domestic absorption, the current account
improves. If, however, devaluation raises
domestic absorption relative to domestic income
the current account deteriorates.
25The Absorption Approach to the Balance of Payments
- Absorption can be divided into two parts
- A rise in income will lead to an increase in
absorption which is determined by the marginal
propensity to absorb, a. - There will also be a 'direct effect' on
absorption which is all the other effects on
absorption resulting from devaluation denoted by
Ad.
26The Absorption Approach to the Balance of Payments
- This equation reveals that there are three
factors that need to be examined when considering
the impact of devaluation - (i) Is the marginal propensity to absorb greater
or less than unity? - (ii) Does devaluation raise or lower national
income? - (iii) Does devaluation raise or lower direct
absorption? - The condition for a devaluation to improve the
current account in case of this approach is -
- (1 a)dY gt dAd
27Conclusions
- Exchange rate volatility can influence the
current account balance - There are two main approaches in this matter
elasticity approach and absorption approach - The approach based on elasticities measure the
effect of FX rate volatility based on demand (and
supply elasticities) - Empirical evidences on elasticity approach showed
a clear difference between short term and long
term approach (J-Curve) - Initially, it was believed that the absorption
approach was an alternative to the elasticities
approach - The latter, elasticity approaches concentrated on
price effects while the absorption approach
concentrated on income effects.
28- Authors such as Tsiang (1961) and Alexander
(1959) showed that the two models are not
substitutes, but rather are complementary. - We have seen that the absorption approach, like
the elasticity approach, does not provide an
unambiguous answer to the question of whether a
devaluation leads to an improvement in the
current account - Although the two models are comparatively static
in nature, they both point to the importance of
dynamic forces and a time dimension to the
eventual outcome. - Despite their simplistic assumptions, ambiguous
conclusions and deficiencies the two approaches
have remained influential because they contain
clear and useful messages for policy-makers. - A devaluation is more likely to succeed when
elasticities of demand for imports and exports
are high and when it is accompanied by measures
such as fiscal and monetary restraint that boost
income relative to domestic absorption.
29- Possible additional readings
- Alexander, S. (1952) Effects of a Devaluation on
a Trade Balance, IMF Staff Papers, pp. 263-78. - Arms, J. R. and Knight, M. D. (1984), Issues in
the Assessment of the Exchange Rates of
Industrial Countries, IMF Occasional Paper, No.
29 - Johnson, H. G. (1976) Elasticity, Absorption,
Keynesian Multiplier, Keynesian Policy and
Monetary Approaches to Devaluation Theory A
Simple Geometric Exposition, American Economic
Review - Machlup, F. (1955) Relative Prices and Aggregate
Spending in the Analysis of Devaluation,
American Economic Review, June 1955 - Robinson, J. (1937) The Foreign Exchanges, J.
Robinson (ed.), Essays in the Theory of
Employment (Oxford Basil Blackwell). - Ster, R. M. (1973) The Balance of Payments
Theory and Economic Policy, London Macmillan - Tsiang, S. C. (1961) The Role of Money in Trade
Balance Stability Synthesis of the Elasticity
and Absorption Approaches, American Economic
Review, vol. 51, pp. 912-36.