Title: Ruthen, Run the Numbers:
1Ruthen,Run the Numbers
- Longitudinal Microsimulation for Individuals
- Rick Morrison
- richard.morrison3_at_sympatico.ca
2Goals Paper a first step toward
- Substantially increasing the pool of longitudinal
microsimulation practitioners - Improving, the effectiveness and sophistication
of personal financial planning, particularly as
regards the treatment of uncertainty - Making some of you rich
- Providing governments with another tool in
support of intelligent tax policies
3Weaknesses in Financial Planning
- Inherent uncertainty is largely ignored
- Simplistic rules for savings and returns
- Frequent absence of personalization to clients
assumptions - Advisors potential conflicts of interest
regarding recommendations - Little attention to spending down savings
- Limited attention to after-tax, constant dollar
representation of lifetime finances
4But These Same Issues Are Longitudinal
Microsimulations Strengths
- We live by probabilities, events, and
distributions - Were used to implementing complex algorithms
- We routinely parameterize everything
- Were used to performing objective, neutral
analyses - We naturally treat full lifetimes, with
end-of-life wrap-ups - We typically model entire tax/transfer systems,
and carry out our analyses in constant dollars
5Potential A New Type of Longitudinal
Microsimulation Model
- Adapt existing longitudinal technologies
- DONT project representative populations!
- INSTEAD, we generate many independent projections
of a single (client) individual, using his/her
(a) assumptions and(b) strategy for financial
decisions - Result is a reasonable distribution of the
consequences of using that strategy.
6What Wed Get From It
- Distributions to reflect inherent uncertainty
- Opportunity to systematically apply sophisticated
strategies, improve them - Personalization to whatever extent desired
- Capacity to be scrupulously objective,
quantitative, regarding conclusions - Explicit attention to savings drawdowns
- Natural presentation of constant-dollar,
after-tax results as the norm
7Ruthen in Single Strategy Mode
8And In Comparative Mode
- Analogous to Base/Option analyses
- Simulate consequences of TWO strategies
simultaneously, using same random s - Results would show not only the absolute
consequences, but the comparative consequences
between the two strategies - Provides a foundation for evolving good
strategies, optimizing, measuring tradeoffs
9Ruthen in Comparative Mode
10Whats Adapted From Existing Models?
- Longitudinal simulation via events for all
relevant life events and financial transactions - Replicable streams of high-quality pseudo-random
deviates - Control and output structures
- Focus on distributions and their presentations
- Base versus option perspective
11Some New Capacities Required
- Convenient specification of assumptions, e.g.,
mortality relative to standard tables - Strategies for saving, dis-saving, and portfolio
adjustments, including housing - Assessing outcomes and comparative outcomes, and
their distributions - Presenting results effectively in tables and
graphs distributions, comparative distributions,
summary measures
12Selected Uses For Individuals
- What is the expected real after-tax rate of
return associated with my financial strategy? - Whats the expected estate Ill leave?
- When can I afford to retire? (constrained choice)
- What kinds of insurance should I buy, and how
much of it? - Should I rent or own my home?
- Do management expense ratios affect my retirement
consumption significantly?
13Selected Uses for Financial Planners
- Deriving personalized financial strategies for
clients to meet their needs and reflect their
assumptions - Showing value-added for the financial planning
services one offers - Assessing whether/when various rules of thumb
make sense for clients
14Illustrative Institutional Use 1
- Derive for the government sector the internal
rates of return for individuals savings - When individuals save, the government sector
loses revenues reduced sales taxes and possibly
income tax revenues - Subsequently, as savings are drawn down (by
choice or death) there are additional revenues
for the government sector
15Illustrative Institutional Use 2
- Government sector sees taxes on returns to
investments, reduced income-tested benefit
payouts, increased sales taxes upon consumption,
greater probate taxes - The series of these net flows (averaged across
independent simulations) implies an internal rate
of return for the government sector - Useful to gauge size of governmental IRR
absolutely, and relative to the individuals IRR
for the same savings strategy
16Challenges/Caveats
- Use of strategies is not well developed (really
an opportunity?) - Finances not the only thing important
- Form of objective function unclear
- Degree of analyst and client comfort in dealing
with distributions - Applicability clearer for individuals than for
families (but most people live in families).
17What We Might Well Find 1
- Saving for retirement often/typically lowers real
discounted lifetime consumption - Its expensive, in terms of current foregone
consumption, to push consumption into the future,
e.g., into retirement - Real financial returns to later-life work are
small, particularly for those with significant
pension entitlements
18What We Might Well Find 2
- The primary beneficiary of individuals decision
to save is the government sector - Governments enjoy a much higher internal rate of
return to citizens savings than the citizens
obtain on those same savings - Individuals, world-wide, are being quite rational
in reducing their voluntary savings rates in the
face of systemic incentives
19Next Steps
- Building such a model will be my focus in my next
career, post-DYNACAN - Preliminary steps, and a modelette, are under
way - I think the project is going to be challenging,
but a lot of fun, and with the potential to do a
fair bit of good - Theres ample room for many players
20 Thanks!
21Inherent Uncertainty
- Seldom know when one will die
- Uncertainty about returns to ones investments
- Statistically, ones work and earnings are highly
variable over time - Possibility of disability, fraud and theft are
often ignored - Retirement is not an on/off switch
22Simplistic Rules
- Plan on living until age 95
- Save 10 of your gross income
- At age X, hold Y of your assets in stocks
- Spend only the returns to your capital
- Keep Z of a years expenditures in an emergency
fund - Assume constant inflation and constant real
returns on investments
23Absence of Personalization
- Mortality based on family history
- Distribution of investment returns as a function
of personal risk tolerance - Personal assumptions about the future of
inflation - Details of ones employer pension plan
- Health strengths and susceptibilities
24Potential Advisor Conflicts of Interest
- Choices of investments may have different returns
to advisors - Over-savings generally leads to bigger earnings
by advisors - Advisors typically unable to provide objective
evidence of the value added by their services
25Spending Down Ones Savings
- Literature is spectacularly weak in indicating
what one can safely spend in retirement without
leaving an undesirably large estate - Planned retirement spending typically doesnt
take into account statistically likely changes in
activities and health-related spending - Over-savings equals under-consumption
26Limited Attention to Real After-Tax
- Many plans deal only with gross, pre-tax income,
rather than consumable income - Many advisors ignore impacts of income-tested
benefits - Many advisors deal primarily in nominal, rather
than real, incomes and expenses - Effects of using up/drawing down existing
stocks in retirement may be ignored