Title: Chinas competitive threat to Latin America
1Chinas competitive threat to Latin America
- Sanjaya Lall (Oxford University) and John Weiss
(ADBI) - 2004 LAEB ANNUAL CONFERENCE
- THE EMERGENCE OF CHINA CHALLENGES AND
OPPORTUNITIES FOR LATIN AMERICA AND ASIA - Beijing, 3-4 December, 2004
2Outline
- Analytical background
- What is a competitive threat?
- Measuring the threat in third markets
- Data analysis China vs. LAC
- Global trends and regional performance
- Technological product level overlap
- Relative market share changes
- Bilateral trade
- Conclusions
3Some LAC countries worry about the Chinese
competitive threat
The Economist (July 24, 2003), in The sucking
sound from the East says Labour costs in China
are about a quarter of their level in Mexico.
The result about 300 manufacturing plants have
moved from Mexico to China in the past two
years. The International Herald Tribune is more
gloomy In all, 500 of Mexicos 3,700 maquila
plants have shut down since 2001, at a cost of
218,000 jobs. September 3, 2003
The Economist (July 24, 2003), in The sucking
sound from the East says Labour costs in China
are about a quarter of their level in Mexico.
The result about 300 manufacturing plants have
moved from Mexico to China in the past two
years. The International Herald Tribune is more
gloomy In all, 500 of Mexicos 3,700 maquila
plants have shut down since 2001, at a cost of
218,000 jobs. September 3, 2003
4Popular perception of a competitive threat
Rapid growth by China can also reduce access to,
or raise cost of, resources like capital (esp.
FDI) and natural resources
This leads to losses in incomes, jobs and growth
Rapid export growth by China reduces exports and
(if they are open to imports) domestic production
by other countries
5Economists dislike this perception trade is not
a zero-sum game
- Countries do not compete like firms where gain
for one is loss for another - Comparative advantage theory
- Resources move between activities loss of one is
offset by the rise of another, with greater
welfare as a result - Entry of low wage competitor induces others to
move up skill/technology scale China accelerates
upgrading elsewhere
Thus, to Krugman, competitiveness is a
meaningless word when applied to national
economies. And the obsession with competitiveness
is both wrong and dangerous. (1994)
6But this simple trade theory is based on strong
assumptions
- It assumes efficient competitive markets, with
perfect information, identical production
functions, no scale economies, no learning, fully
mobile factors within economies, full employment,
no transport costs, etc. - It implies the pattern of specialization does not
matter. With no externalities, cumulative
learning or agglomeration, all activities are
equally beneficial. Structural change is
automatic and instantaneous in response to
changing factor prices
7If these assumptions are relaxed, implications
are different
- With scale economies, cumulative learning,
technology gaps, unemployment, risk
uncertainty, externalities, information failures,
immobile factors, and so on - While there are certainly potential benefits from
specialization trade can be non-zero sum game - The realisation of benefits from trade depends on
the ability of economy to create competitive
capabilities and exploit activities that offer
the best opportunities for growth, technology
spillovers - The process may not be automatic, instantaneous,
costless or complete there are cumulative,
path-dependent effects (leading to multiple
equilibria) - Strategy is necessary, given widespread market
failures, to create capabilities and move from
low to high equilibrium. Success breeds success
8In this (more realistic) world
- Entry of a large, efficient low-wage competitor
like China can involve significant adjustment
costs - Quantitative loss of income, employment, exports
- Qualitative decline of production/export
structure into slower growing, technologically
inferior activities - The outcome depends on
- The similarity of export structures in competing
countries (extent of competitive overlap) - Nature of export structures in both countries
(nature of technological specialisation) - The speed and extent of adjustment in each
country (ability to upgrade within and across
competing activities, move into fast growing
segments, reach new markets and so on)
9If there is a possible competitive threat, how
can we measure it?
- Computable general equilibrium model (needs
strong simplifying assumptions) - Detailed case studies of each industry (rich but
limited in coverage) - Trade data analysis to gauge potential for
competition competitive performance (needs
careful interpretation) - This study uses last method 1990-2002 trade data
on market shares in world/US and bilateral trade
by technology categories
10Five possible combinations of relative market
share changes
11Technological structure
- Primary products
- Manufactured products
- RB (Resource based) e.g. food, wood forestry
products, processed minerals, petroleum products - LT (Low technology) e.g. textiles, clothing,
footwear, toys, sports goods, simple metal
products - MT (Medium technology) e.g. automotive products,
consumer durables (incl. simple electronics),
most industrial machinery, chemicals, steel - HT (High technology) Advanced ICT and
electricals, pharmaceuticals, aerospace,
precision instruments
12Shares of world exports by technology ()
13Shares of developing countries in world exports
(1990-2002)
1450 most dynamic exports in the world, 1990-2002
15LACs manufacturing value added record (world
share, 1980-2000)
16World market shares of LAC and East Asian exports
(1990-2002)
17Changes in world market shares, 1990-2002
18World market share performance in LAC and EA
- EA 8 and China perform impressively across most
sectors, with increasing specialization in
technology-based products. - China outperforms rest of EA in most categories,
suggesting a growing competitive threat within
the region, particularly in LT products. - But in HT there is growing complementarity within
EA. - LAC without Mexico does poorly, raising its world
market share in all manufactured exports by less
than 0.2 percentage points the weakest
performance is by the two giant economies,
Argentina and Brazil. - The largest world market shares held by LAC-M are
in primary and resource-based products and MT
process industries - Mexico behaves like an EA Tiger, with significant
gains across the spectrum (primary products
excepted).
19Export dynamism dynamic products in
manufactured exports
20Technological similarity of export structures,
China and LAC
21Structural stability of exports (181 three-digit
manufactured products)
22Correlation of Chinese and LAC export structures,
1990 2000
23Measuring the competitive threat by relative WMS
changes
24Chinese competitive threat by LAC country in
2000 ( of manufactured exports)
25(No Transcript)
26Some implications
- Most threatened LAC countries are C Rica, El
Salvador, Chile. - In Chile it reflects the large share of its
exports in copper, where China gains WMS while
Chile loses (direct threat). Its fish exports are
partially threatened because China gains more WMS - In C Rica the Chinese threat is largely partial
China gains greater WMS in electronics,
instruments, apparel and processed foods. - In El Salvador, direct and partial threat in
textiles and clothing - Mexico faces the greatest potential threat from
China, but because of its very rapid gains in WMS
it has not actually faced a significant threat
over 1990-2002. - Brazil faces a larger competitive threat (30
direct and 31 partial threat in 2002) but the
direct threat declines from 60 in 1990. The
largest threatened exports by Brazil are in the
partial threat category telecoms and footwear.
But its largest single export, aircraft, faces no
threat from China. - EA faces much greater direct and partial threat
than LAC. The unweighted average for EA 8 is
75.2, much higher than LACs total of 39. - However, these results have to be interpreted
with care (e.g. Chinese threat to Chile in
copper). And past is not good guide to future
(e.g. threat to Mexico)
27Bilateral trade patterns
28Technology breakdown of bilateral trade between
LAC China
29Bilateral trade of big three
30Some findings on the big three
- Argentina is overwhelmingly an exporter of
primary products, with its share of RB declining
significantly. It has no noticeable exports of HT
products to China. Its imports from China are
predominantly LT, but with large and growing
shares of MT and HT products. Argentina runs a
trade surplus with China, 763 m. in 2002, most
of it in primary products, with a smaller surplus
in agro-based RB products. - Brazil also raises its exports of primary
products but maintains a very large share for RB.
It has a small, growing share for HT but a
sharply falling one for MT. Chinas exports to
Brazil span all categories, with all manufactured
categories growing at the expense of primary
products. The largest category by far is HT
products. Brazil runs a trade surplus with China,
823 m., mostly in primary products and RB
manufactures (both mineral and agro-based
products). Its largest deficit is in HT products,
followed by MT engineering products. - Mexico exports few primary or resource-based
products to China, and makes a massive shift from
MT to HT products. Chinese exports to Mexico
have HT as the largest category. This suggests
growing integration of electronics production in
the 2 economies, similar to EA. - The values of Mexican HT exports to China are far
smaller than Chinese HT exports to Mexico. In
2002, the figures are 320 million and 2.1
billion, respectively. Overall, Mexico runs a
huge 5.7 billion trade deficit with China. It
also runs a deficit with China in every single
category of trade, including primary products
31To sum up on bilateral trade
- There is a rapid structural transformation of
LACs trade pattern with China in the course of a
relatively few years. - This transformation is undesirable in
technological terms. - To the extent that this influences LACs future
competitiveness patterns in bilateral trade or
exports to third countries, it can be damaging
32But bilateral trade so far is very small
33Conclusions
- Some LAC countries are benefiting from growing
imports of primary and RB products by China - China remains a relatively small market for LAC
(but China overtook Japan as import supplier in
2003). - The trade structure of most LAC is more
complementary than competitive with that of China
- The main exceptions are Mexico and Costa Rica,
but in HT they may benefit from intra-industry
trade with China within MNC production networks - WMS analysis suggests that all threatened exports
(direct partial) in LAC are well below
comparable figure for EA. Goods in the more
serious direct threat category are only 11 of
exports - This suggests low competitive impact of China
34But there are caveats
- Past is not good guide to future, in particular
for Mexico - LAC is suffering massive downgrading of
comparative advantage in bilateral trade not a
good portent for future - China may reinforce LAC poor export performance
in third markets, pre-empting dynamic segments.
Different export structures may be sign of LAC
weakness if it means specialisation in
slow-growing and technologically unrewarding
products