Title: MsC Microeconomics Lecture 8
1MsC MicroeconomicsLecture 8
- Francesco Squintani
- University of Essex
2Competitive Markets
- A competitive firm takes the market price of
output as given and outside of its control. - Let p be the market price.
- Then the demand curve faced by the firm is
- 0 if pgtp
- D(p) 0, infinity if pp
- infinity if pltp
3- Because the firm takes price as given, the profit
maximization problem is - max pq c(q)
- q
- Hence, the firm produces the quantity q such
that - p c(q)
- price equals marginal cost,
- provided that c(q)lt0, costs are convex.
4- This provides the firm supply function
- p c(q) if p gt AVC(q)
- 0 if p lt AVC(q)
- Note that the firm cannot recoup fixed costs, not
even if it produces zero output. Hence it is
willing to produce even if p lt AC.
c, p
MC
AC
AVC
q
5- The market supply function is simply the sum of
the individual supply functions Y(p) Si qi
(p). - The market demand function is the sum of
individual demand functions X(p) Si xi (p). - The market equilibrium is given by Si qi (p) Si
xi (p).
p
Y(p)
X(p)
y
6Competitive Markets - Welfare
- Say for simplicity that each consumer consumes
only one unit of good. - The welfare of a consumer j who buys the good at
price p is uj p. - All consumers j such that uj gt p buy the good.
- Hence the aggregate surplus of consumers is
Sjuj gtp uj p.
p
Y(p)
The aggregate surplus of consumers is
depicted by the blue triangle, because consumer
js utility for the good coincides with her
willingness to pay.
X(p)
y
7- Say for simplicity that each producer produces
only one unit of good. - The welfare of a producer i who sells the good at
price p is p cj. - All producers i such that cj lt p buy the good.
- Hence the aggregate surplus of producers is Sic
i lt p p -c.
p
Y(p)
The aggregate surplus of producers is
depicted by the green triangle, because the
supply curve coincides with MC curve.
X(p)
y
8Entry
- If firms make a profit in the short-run, new
firms will enter the market, so that in the long
run, profits are zero. - Similarly, if firms make a loss in the short-run,
some firms will exit the market, so that in the
long run, profits are zero. - In the long run, the supply curve is flat and
coincides with the minimum of MC(q), i.e. the
output q where AC(q)MC(q).
c, p
MC
AC
AVC
q
9Monopoly
- A monopolist is the only supplier of a good or
service. - Because it does not face any competition, it is
price-maker. - Hence, given the inverse demand function P(q), it
chooses output q so as to maximize p(q) P(q)q
c(q). - The first order conditions are
- p(q)p(q)q MR(q) MC(q) c(q).
- Rearranging,
- p(q)11/e(q) c(q),
- where e(q) is the elasticity of demand.
10- Recalling that e(q) lt 0, we see that e(q) gt 1,
or else MRlt0, and the monopolist would produce
zero. - Hence, the monopoly price p(qm) is larger than
marginal cost, the price p(q) chosen by a
competitive firm.
p
MC
p(qm)
p(q)
X(q)
MR
q
qm
q
11Monopoly - Welfare
- The producer welfare is higher under monopoly
than under competition. But the consumer welfare
is smaller. - There is an aggregate welfare loss, the
red triangle.
p
MC
p(qm)
p(q)
X(q)
MR
q
qm
q
12Price Discrimination
- The monopolist would like to price discriminate
among its buyers, i.e. sell at a higher price to
those who value the good most. This allows him to
increase its profit. - Examples
of price discrimination
include low prices for
students and elderly. - In the extreme case
- the monopolist
- captures all
- surplus.
p
MC
p(qm)
X(q)
MR
q
qm
13Cournot's model of oligopoly
- A good is produced by n firms.
- Firm is cost of producing qi units is Ci(qi)
- (Ci is an increasing function).
- The firms' total output is Q q1 qn.
- The market price is P(Q)
- (P is the inverse demand function, it is
decreasing when positive). - Firm i's revenue is qi P(q1 qn).
14- Firm i's profit is revenue minus cost
- pi(q1 qn) qi P(q1 qn) - Ci (qi).
- Linear Costs and Demand
- Ci (qi) cqi, i1, , n.
- P (Q) a Q if a gt Q, P(Q) 0 if a lt Q.
- pi(q1 qn) qi a (q1 qn) - cqi.
- To find the optimal quantity, differentiate pi
with respect to qi, set it equal to zero, and
obtain - dpi (q1 qn)/dqi a (q1 qn) qi
c 0. - Best Response functions
- bi (q-i) a (q1 qi-1 qi1 q n)
c/2.
15- Solving for the Nash equilibrium.
- Because the system of best-response functions is
linear and symmetric, equalize qi across i
1,,n - qi bi (qi) a (n-1) qi c/2.
- The Nash equilibrium quantity is
- qi a c/(n1).
- The Nash equilibrium price is
- pi (q) a Q a na c/(n1)
- a nc/(n1).
- The Nash equilibrium profits are
- pi (q) qia Q cqi
- a c 2/(n-1)2
16q2
- With n 2,
- b1(q2) a q2 c/2.
- b2(q1) a q1 c/2.
b1(q2)
(q1, q2) qi a c/3, i1,2.
a c/3
b2(q1)
q1
a c/3
17- Comparison with Perfect Competition
- In a perfectly competitive market,
- price equals marginal cost pi c,
- profits are zero pi 0.
- In the Nash Equilibrium of Cournot model,
- price is pi (qi) c a c /(n1) gt c,
- profits are pi (qi) a c 2/(n-1)2 gt 0.
- In the limit for large n,
- price pi (qi) c a c /(n1) converges
to c - profits pi (qi) a c 2/(n-1)2 go to zero.
18Comparison with Collusion
- Suppose the firms collude and act like a
monopolist maximizing the sum of profits - p(Q) Qa Q cQ.
- Differentiating the optimal quantity, we have
- Qm a c/2.
- In the Nash Equilibrium of Cournot model,
- Q na c/(n1).
- The firms would like to collude, but cannot
commit - (as in the Prisoners Dilemma).
19- In Cournot competition, firms cannot collude.
- But perfectly competition is not achieved either.
P
Cournot competition
P(Qm)
P(Q)
Q
Qm
Q
20Bertrand Competition
- Unlike Cournot competition, firms compete in
prices. - The demand function is denoted by D, if the good
is available at the price p then the total amount
demanded is D(p). - The firm setting the lowest price sells to all
the market.
21Linear Costs and Demand
- Ci (qi) cqi, i1, , n.
- D (p) a p if a gt p, D (p) 0 if a lt p.
- Let pj min p1, , pn.
- Profit is
- pi(p1, , pn) (pi c)(a - pi) if pi lt pj,
- pi(p) (pi c)(a - pi)/m if pi pj,
- pi(p) 0 if pi gt pj.
22Best-Response Correspondence
- If pj lt c, then pi(p) lt 0 for pi lt pj,
- pi(p) 0 for pi gt pj bi(p) pi pi gt pj.
pi
pj
pi
c
pm
23- If pj c, then pi(p) lt 0 for pi lt pj,
- pi(p) 0 for pi gt pj bi(p) pi pi gt pj.
- If pj gt pm, then bi(p) pm.
pi
pi
pj
c
c
pm
pm
pj
pi
pi
24- If c lt pj lt pm then pi(p) increases in pj, but
discontinuously drops at pi pj. So, bi(p) f. - The best response correspondence is empty.
pi
pj
pi
c
25- In sum, the best-response correspondence is
- bi(p) pi pi gt pj, if pj lt c,
- bi(p) pi pi gt pj, if pj c,
- bi(p) f, if c lt pj lt pm,
- bi(p) pm, if pj gt pm.
- The Nash equilibrium is pi c, for all i
1,,n. - Intuitively, selling at any price pi lt c yields
negative profit. If the lowest industry price
were pj gt c, then firm i sells to the whole
industry at any price pi with c lt pi lt pj. In
equilibrium, pi c, for all i.
26Stackelbergs model of duopoly
- There are two firms in the market.
- Firm i s cost of producing qi units of the good
is Ci (qi) the price at which output is sold
when the total output is Q is P(Q). - Each firms strategic variable is output, as in
Cournots model, but the firms make their
decisions sequentially, rather than
simultaneously one firm chooses its output, then
the other firm does so, knowing the output chosen
by the first firm.
27- Extensive form of Stackelberg Game
- Players The two firms.
- Terminal histories The set of all sequences (q1,
q2) of outputs for the firms (where each qi, the
output of firm i, is a nonnegative number). - Player function P(Ø) 1 and P(q1) 2 for all
q1. - Preferences The payoff of firm i to the terminal
history (q1, q2) is its profit qi P(q1 q2) -
Ci(qi), for i 1, 2.
28- A strategy of firm 1 is simply an output choice
q1. - Firm 2 moves after every history in which firm 1
chooses an output. A strategy of firm 2 is a
function that associates an output q2 to each
possible output q1 of firm 1. - We use backward induction to find its subgame
perfect equilibria. - For any q1 output of firm 1, we find the output
b2 (q1) of firm 2 that maximize its profit q2
P(q1 q2) C2 (q2). - In any subgame perfect equilibrium, firm 2s
strategy is b2. - We find the output q1 of firm 1 that maximize its
profit, given the strategy b2 (q1) of firm 2. - Firm 1s output in a subgame perfect equilibrium
is the value q1 that maximizes q1P(q1 b2(q1)) -
C1 (q1).
29- Suppose that Ci(qi) cqi for i 1, 2, and P(Q)
a - Q if Q a, P(Q) 0 if Q gt a, where c gt 0
and c lt a. - We know that firm 2s best response to output q1
of firm 1 is b2(q1) (a - c - q1)/2 if q1 a -
c, b2(q1) 0 if q1 gt a - c. - In a subgame perfect equilibrium of Stackelbergs
game firm 2s strategy is this function b2 and
firm 1s strategy q1 maximizes q1 (a - c - (q1
(a - c - q1)/2)) - q1 (a - c - q1)/2.
- The FOC yields q1 (a - c)/2.
- The unique subgame perfect equilibrium is (q1,
b2).
30- The SPE outcome of the Stackelberg game is
- q1S (a - c)/2, q2S (a - c - q1 )/2 (a -
c)/4. - Firm 1s profit is q1S(P(q1Sq2S) - c) (a -
c)2/8, firm 2s profit is q1S(P(q1Sq2S) - c)
(a - c)2/16. - Recall that in the unique Nash equilibrium of
Cournots (simultaneous-move) game, q1C q2C
(a - c)/3, so that each firms profit is (a -
c)2/9. - First-Mover Advantage Firm 1 produces more
output and obtains more profit in the subgame
perfect equilibrium of the sequential game where
it moves first than it does in the Nash
equilibrium of Cournots game, and firm 2
produces less output and obtains less profit.
31Repeated Oligopoly
- Suppose that n firms repeatedly play a Bertrand
oligopoly game. - If the discount factor is not too small, they can
collude on the monopoly price and split the
profits equally. - Suppose that there are two firms, for simplicity.
- Consider the following Grim Trigger strategy,
which prescribes that the player initially
collude, and continues to do so if all players
collude at all previous times. - pi (a1, . . . , aT) pm if at (pm, pm) for
all t 1, . . . , T. - si (a1, . . . , aT) c otherwise.
32Grim Trigger SPE
- Suppose that both players adopt the grim trigger
strategy. - There are two sets of histories. Those for which
grim trigger strategy prescribes that the players
play (pm, pm) and those for which the grim
trigger strategy prescribes that they do not play
(pm, pm) . - In the first set of histories, if player i plays
grim trigger, then the outcome is (pm, pm) in
every period with payoffs P(qm)qm c(qm)/2,
whose discounted average is P(qm)qm c(qm)/2. - If i deviates only once, she plays p lt pm. Then
she reverts to the grim trigger strategy, that
prescribes to play c at all subsequent periods.
33- The opponent, playing grim trigger strategy,
plays c forever as a consequence of is one-shot
deviation. - Let q P-1(p). The OSD yields the stream of
payoffs - (P(q)q c(q), 0, 0, . . .) with discounted
average - (1 - d) P(q)q c(q).
- Thus player i cannot increase her payoff by
deviating if and only if - P(qm)qm c(qm)/2 supqltq m P(q)q
c(q)(1 - d), - or d 1/2.
- In the second set of histories, if player i plays
grim trigger, then the outcome is (c, c) in every
period with payoffs (0, 0, . . .), whose
discounted average is 0. - If I deviates only once, she plays C. Then she
reverts to the grim trigger strategy, that
prescribes to play D at all subsequent periods.
34- The opponent, playing grim trigger strategy,
plays c forever as a consequence of is one-shot
deviation. - The OSD yields the stream of payoffs (0,0,) with
discounted average 0 - Player i cannot increase her payoff by deviating
1 d. - We conclude that if d ½ then the strategy pair
in which each players strategy is the grim
trigger strategy is a Subgame-Perfect equilibrium
of the infinitely repeated Bertrand Game.
35Public Goods
- A good is called excludable if people can be
excluded from consuming it. - A good is called nonrival if one persons
consumption does not reduce the amount available
to others. - Goods that are nonrival and not excludable are
called public goods. - Goods that are nonrival but excludable are called
club goods.
36Public Goods Discrete Case
- Consider a market with two agents and two goods.
- The good xi is private, we call it income.
- Agent i has endowment wi of the private good and
chooses the contribution gi towards the public
good. - So, the consumption of private good is xi wi -
gi - The public good production is
- G 0 if g1g2 lt c
- G 1 if g1g2 gt c.
- The utility of agent i is ui (G,xi).
37Public Goods Discrete Case
- The provision of the public good with
contributions g1, g2 is a Pareto improvement if
for i1,2, - ui(1, wi gi) gt ui(0, wi).
- Let the reservation price ri solve
- ui(1, wi ri) ui(0, wi).
- The provision of the public good is a Pareto
improvement if and only if r1 r2 gt c.
38Public Goods Discrete Case
- The private provision of a discrete public good
is similar to a Prisoners Dilemma. - Suppose that c/2 lt r1 lt c, c/2 lt r2 lt c.
Agent 2 Contribute Not
Agent 1 Contribute
Not
u2(1, w1-c), u2(1, w2)
u1(1, w1 c/2), u2(1, w2 c/2)
u1(1, w1), u2(1, w2 c)
u1(0, w1), u2(0, w2)
39Public Goods Continuous Case
- Suppose that the public good is provided in
continuous amounts, so that G f (g1, g2). - The utility of agent i is ui(f(g1g2), wi gi).
- Efficiency requires
- max a1u1(f(g1g2), w1 g1) a2u2(f(g1g2), w2
g2) - First-Order conditions are, for i 1,2,
- a1(du1/dG) f a2(du2/dG) f ai(dui/dxi)
0 - It follows that a1 du1/dx2 a2 du1/dx1, and
rearranging - (du1/dG) f (du2/dG) f
- (du1/dx1) (du1/dx1)
1 or MRS1 MRS2 1
40Public Goods Private Provision
- Suppose that agent j contributes gj, agent choose
gi - maxg ui(f(g1g2), wi gi) s.t.
gi gt 0. - Kuhn-Tucker conditions are
- dL/dgi (dui/dG) f (dui/dxi) lt 0, gi gt 0,
(dL/dgi)gi 0. - Let the function bi(wi) be the solution of dL/dgi
0, it follows that agent is
reaction function is - gi maxbi(wi gj )
gj , 0. - These two equations determine the Nash
Equilibrium g - When utility is quasilinear in income, ui vi
(f(g1g2)) wi gi, bi(wi) gi constant in
wi, so gi maxgj gj , 0.
41Lindahl Equilibrium
- Suppose that we offer each consumer i the right
to buy any quantity of G at price pj. - Agent i choose gi
- maxG ui(G, xi) s.t. xi pi G
wi. - First-Order Conditions are
- dui/dG
- dui/dxi
- Hence, letting G and x be the Pareto efficient
allocations, - dui (G, xi)/dG
- dui (G,
xi)/dxi - delivers the efficient allocations. Each agent i
pays the tax pi G.
pi
choosing pi
42Groves-Clarke Mechanism
- Consider the discrete case again, G 0,1.
- Let si be the share of cost paid by agent i.
- Let vi ri sic, be the net value of agent i
for the public good. - Each agent is asked to report her net value, we
denote the report by bi. - The public good is provided if and only if Si bi
gt 0. - If the good is provided, each agent i receives a
(possibly negative) side-payment equal to the sum
Sji bj of other agents bids.
43Groves-Clarke Mechanism
- We now show that the profile b v is weakly
dominant. - Agent i payoff is
- ui(bi, b-i) vi Sji bj if bi
Sji bj gt 0, - ui(bi, b-i) 0 if bi Sji bj lt 0.
- Suppose that vi Sji bj gt 0.
- ui(bi, b-i) vi Sji bj gt0 if bi vi,
- ui(bi, b-i) vi Sji bj gt0 if bi gt - Sji bj
- ui(bi, b-i) 0 if bi lt - Sji bj
44Groves-Clarke Mechanism
- Suppose that vi Sji bj lt 0.
- ui(bi, b-i) 0 if bi vi,
- ui(bi, b-i) vi Sji bj lt 0 if bi gt - Sji bj
- ui(bi, b-i) 0 if bi lt - Sji bj
- In general, any mechanism with side transfer of
the form - ui(bi, b-i) h(b-i) Sji bj if bi gt - Sji
bj - ui(bi, b-i) h(b-i) if bi lt - Sji bj
- will yield truthful reporting as a weakly
dominant strategy.
45Groves-Clarke Mechanism continuous case
- Suppose that the good is continuous.
- If G units of good are provided, and utilities
are quasilinear - vi (G) ui (G) siG.
- Each agent reports a function bi(.) of the public
good provided. - The government chooses G argmaxG Si bi(G).
- Each agent receives a transfer Sji bj(G).
- Again, we show that reporting the truthful
function vi(.) is a weakly dominant strategy.
46Groves-Clarke Mechanism continuous case
- Take any profile of opponents reports b i.
- Agent i wants to maximize her net utility
- vi(G) Sji bj(G)
- The government maximizes
- bi(G) Sji bj(G).
- Hence, by truthfully reporting, agent i makes
sure that the government maximizes her own net
utility.
47Externalities
- A choice by an agent that effects the utility of
other agents is called an externality. - Among the example of negative externalities
pollution. - Among the example of positive externalities
education. - When there are externalities, the First Welfare
Theorem does not hold, because there are external
effects that are not priced.
48Externalities - An Example
- Suppose there are two firms.
- Firm 1 produces output x at cost c(x), sold in a
competitive market. - Output x imposes a negative externality e(x) on
firm 2. - We assume that c(x) and e(x) are increasing and
convex. - The profits are p1 maxx px c(x), p2
-e(x). - The market solution satisfies pc(x).
- But the socially efficient solution maximizes p1
p2, - Hence it satisfies pc(x) e(x).
- Firm 1 should internalize the cost e(x) borne on
firm 2.
49Externalities Pigouvian Taxes
- Pigouvian taxes are a means to solve the
externality problem. - The firms producing the externalities are taxed
so that they internalize the externalities
produced. - In the example, suppose that the Government
imposes a tax t on the good x. - Firm 1 now maximizes (p-t)x c(x),
- and chooses x so that p-t c(x).
- Evidently, choosing t e(x) solves the
externality problem.
50Externalities Missing Markets
- Suppose that the Government establishes a
competitive market for pollution. - Firm 1 can decide how much pollution it wants to
sell to firm 2, and firm 2 can decide how much
pollution it wants to buy. - Let r be the price of a unit of pollution.
- Firm 1 maximizes px1 rx1 c(x1).
- Firm 2 maximizes rx2 e(x2).
- The first-order conditions are pr c(x1), -r
e(x2). - Equating demand and supply, x1x2x, we recover
the optimality condition p c(x) e(x).
51Compensation Mechanism
- The missing markets solution is often impractical
because of high administrative costs. - The Pigouvian taxes are also difficult to
implement because the Government is unlikely to
know the cost function of externality producing
firms. - The government may try to elicit Pigouvian taxes
from the firms. - First, each firm i 1,2 is asked to report a
Pigouvian tax rate ti. - Second, firm 1 chooses x, pays tax t2x and firm 2
receives transfer t2x. If t1 t2, each firm pays
(t1 t2)2 to the Government.
52Compensation Mechanism
- We show that reporting t1 e(x) and t2
e(x) is the unique Subgame Perfect Equilibrium. - By backward induction, in stage 2, firm 1s
chooses x so as to - maxx px c(x) t2x (t1 t2)2
- Hence, firm 1 chooses x so that p c(x) t2
- At the first stage, the best response of firm 1
is t1(t2) t2, because t1 has no influence on
the x chosen in second stage. - The best response of firm 2 at stage 1
incorporates the effect of t2 on the second
period choice of x - max t1x(t2) e(x(t2)) (t2 t1)2,
- yields (t1 e(x))x(t2) (t2 t1) 0
- Solving, we recover the efficiency condition p
c(x) e(x).