Externalities and Property Rights - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 83
About This Presentation
Title:

Externalities and Property Rights

Description:

Sara is an accomplished classical violinist. ... For Tom, Sara's music is a positive externality. ... If Sara plays in response to her own costs and benefits, ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:243
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 84
Provided by: jeffc194
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Externalities and Property Rights


1
Externalities and Property Rights
2
Externalities
  • Sometimes costs or benefits that result from an
    activity accrue to people not directly involved
    in the activity.
  • These are called external costs or external
    benefits -- externalities for short.

3
External Costs and Benefits
  • External Cost (negative externality)
  • A cost of an activity that falls on people other
    than those who pursue the activity
  • e.g. air pollution/ noise pollution
  • External Benefit (positive externality)
  • A benefit of an activity received by people other
    than those who pursue the activity
  • e.g. immunizations/ developments in new
    technology

4
External Costs and Benefits
  • How Externalities Affect Resource Allocation
  • Externalities reduce economic efficiency.
  • Solutions of externalities may be efficient.
  • When efficient solutions to externalities are not
    possible, government intervention or other
    collective action may be used.

5
e.g. 12.1 External Benefits
  • Sara is an accomplished classical violinist.
  • Her neighbor Tom is a fan of classical violin
    music, and on summer evenings enjoys listening to
    Sara play in her garden.
  • For Tom, Sara's music is a positive externality.

If Sara plays only in response to her own costs
and benefits, will the amount of time she plays
be socially optimal?
6
e.g. 12.1 External Benefits
  • If Sara plays in response to her own costs and
    benefits, she will continue to play until the
    marginal benefit of playing another minute is
    equal to the marginal cost.
  • But since Tom also benefits from her playing, at
    that point the total marginal benefit of playing
    another minute will be greater than the marginal
    cost.

7
e.g. 12.1 A Good Whose Production Generates a
Positive Externality for Consumers

Toms MB
Q (minutes)
Sara plays too little from the social viewpoint.
8
e.g. 12.2 External Cost
  • Tom left, Sara has a new neighbour.
  • New neighbor Harry hates violin music, and summer
    evenings become distressed when Sara plays in her
    garden.
  • For Harry, Sara's music is a negative
    externality.

If Sara plays only in response to her own costs
and benefits, will the amount of time she plays
be socially optimal?
9
e.g. 12.2 External Cost
  • If Sara plays in response to her own costs and
    benefits, she will continue to play until the
    marginal benefit of playing another minute is
    equal to the marginal cost.
  • But since Harry also incurs costs from her
    playing, at that point the marginal benefit of
    playing another minute will be smaller than their
    combined marginal costs.
  • Note To Harry, violin sounds are noise
    pollution that kills his productivity. So, he
    regards it as an increase in production cost from
    the societys point of view instead of a drop in
    marginal benefit.

10
e.g. 12.2 A Good Whose Production Generates a
Negative Externality for Consumers

Social MC Saras MC Harrys MC
Q (minutes)
QSOC
Sara plays too much from the social viewpoint.
11
External Costs and Benefits
  • How Externalities Affect Resource Allocation
  • When an activity does not create an externality,
    the optimal level of the activity for the
    individual will equal the socially optimal level
    of the activity.

12
External Costs and Benefits
  • How Externalities Affect Resource Allocation
  • When an activity generates a positive
    externality, the level of the activity will be
    less than the socially optimal level.

13
External Costs and Benefits
  • How Externalities Affect Resource Allocation
  • When an activity generates a negative
    externality, the level of the activity will be
    greater than the socially optimal level.

14
e.g. 12.3
  • Smith can produce with or without a filter on his
    smokestack.
  • Production without a filter results in greater
    smoke damage to Jones.

15
e.g. 12.3
If Smith is not liable for smoke damages and if
the two parties can negotiate costlessly with one
another, will he install a filter?
16
e.g. 12.3
  • The filter costs 245-20045 for Smith to
    install.
  • Total economic surplus (for society) goes up if
    Smith installs the filter
  • 200-35165 245-85160.
  • Smith doesn't have to install it, but if Jones
    pays him at least 45, he will gladly do so.
  • And since the filter results in savings of
  • 85-3550 for Jones, he will pay Smith to
    install the filter.

17
The Coase Theorem
If property rights are fully assigned and if
people can negotiate costlessly with one another,
they will always arrive at efficient solutions to
problems caused by externalities.
Ronald Coase 1991 Nobel Laureate in Economics
18
External Costs and Benefits
  • The Coase Theorem
  • If at no cost people can negotiate the purchase
    and sale of the right to perform activities that
    cause externalities, they can always arrive at
    efficient solutions to problems caused by
    externalities.

19
Example 12.3
  • Traditional (pre-Coase) view
  • Smith is the perpetrator, Jones is the victim.
  • If it is Smith's smoke that is causing the damage
    to Jones, why should Jones pay Smith to install a
    filter on his smokestack?

20
e.g. 12.3
  • Coases insight was that externalities are purely
    reciprocal.
  • The smoke harms Jones, true enough.
  • But to restrain Smith from producing smoke would
    harm Smith.
  • The two parties have a shared interest in
    achieving the outcome that is least costly
    overall.

21
Benefit to all when the pie is larger
22
e.g. 12.4
Ted and Bill can live together in a two-bedroom
apartment for 500/mo
23
e.g. 12.4
or each rent a one-bedroom apartment for 300/mo.
24
e.g. 12.4
If the rent were the same, they would be
indifferent between living together or
separately, except for one problem
Ted likes to practice his trumpet late at night
and this will disturb Bill's sleep.
25
e.g. 12.4
  • Ted would pay up to 150 per month rather than to
    reschedule his playing to some other time.
  • Bill would pay up to 80 per month not to have
    his sleep disturbed.
  • Will they live together or separately?

26
e.g. 12.4
  • The question is whether the benefits of joint
    living exceeds the costs.
  • The benefit is the 100 per month reduction in
    rent.(2 individual apt rent 300X2 600 1
    shared apt rent 500)
  • What is the least costly accommodation to the
    trumpet problem?

27
e.g. 12.4
  • If they live together
  • Cost to Ted of stopping playing 150/month(pay
    at least 150 for rescheduling practice)
  • Cost to Bill of tolerating the noise
    80/month(value of good sleep)
  • So the least costly solution is for Bill to put
    up with the noise (since 80
  • Since this cost (80) is less than the gain (100
    reduction in rent), they should live together.

28
e.g. 12.4
  • In the preceding example, what is the largest
    rent Bill would be willing to pay if the two were
    to live together?

If Bill were to live alone, he would pay
300/month and suffer no trumpet noise. Since
the noise costs him 80/month (in terms of good
sleep), the most he would be willing to pay for
the shared apartment is 300 - 80 220.
29
e.g. 12.4
  • How should Ted and Bill split the 500/month rent
    if they agree that each should benefit equally
    from living together?

Their total gain from living together is 100
(reduction in rent) - 80 20/month. If Ted
pays 290/month and Bill pays 210/month, each
will be 10/month better off than to live alone.
30
External Costs and Benefits
  • Legal Remedies for Externalities
  • When negotiation is costless
  • Efficient solutions to externalities can be
    found.
  • The adjustment to the externality is usually done
    by the party with the lowest cost.

31
Costly negotiations
  • However, it is often impractical to negotiate
    solutions to the problems created by
    externalities due to Transaction Costs (costs
    incur in negotiating/ agreeing/ and implementing
    an agreement) .
  • E.g. Hospital patients are unable to negotiate
    with passing motorists about not blowing their
    horns.
  • In such cases, the law tries to impose the burden
    of adjustment on the party that can accomplish it
    at the lowest cost.

32
External Costs and Benefits
  • Legal Remedies for Externalities
  • When negotiation is not costless
  • Laws may be used to correct for externalities.
  • The burden of the law can be placed on those who
    have the lowest cost.

33
Costly negotiations
Not blowing his horn is a cost to the motorist,
but a benefit to the patient. Because peace
and quiet is especially valuable for hospital
patients, the law prohibits horn blowing in the
vicinity of hospitals.
34
e.g. 12.5 The Right to an Unobstructed View
  • Legal Remedies for Externalities
  • e.g. Why do most communities have zoning laws?
  • Lehman owns a house overlooking the lake, from
    which he enjoys a commanding sunset view.

35
e.g. 12.5 The Right to an Unobstructed View
  • Now Martin purchases the property below Lehman's
    and is considering which of two houses to build
  • a one-story house that would leave Lehman's view
    intact
  • or a two-story design that would completely block
    Lehman's view.

36
e.g. 12.5 The Right to an Unobstructed View
  • Suppose the gain to Lehman from an unobstructed
    view is 100,
  • the gain to Martin from having a one-story house
    is 200, and a two-story house is 280.
  • If the laws of property let people build houses
    of any height they chose, and if negotiation
    between property owners were costless, which
    house would Martin build?

37
e.g. 12.5 The Right to an Unobstructed View
  • Value of view to Lehman 100
  • Value of second story to Martin 280-20080
  • The increase in Martin's gain from having the
    taller house is 80, which is 20 less than the
    cost to Lehman from the loss of his view.

38
e.g. 12.5 The Right to an Unobstructed View
  • Since we assumed ZERO negotiation cost
  • The most efficient outcome is thus for Martin to
    build the one-story house.
  • WHY?
  • Rather than seeing Martin to build the taller
    house, it will be in Lehman's interest to
    compensate Martin for choosing the shorter
    version.

39
e.g. 12.5 The Right to an Unobstructed View
  • To do so, he will have to give Martin at least
    80.
  • The most Lehman would be willing to pay is 100,
    since that is all the view is worth to him.
  • For some payment P, where 80?P?100, Lehman will
    get to keep his view.

40
e.g. 12.6 The Right to an Unobstructed View
  • Suppose, however, that negotiations between the
    two parties were impractical due to a huge
    negotiation cost.
  • Martin would then go ahead with the two-story
    house, since that is the version he values most.
  • By comparison with the one-story design, Martin
    would gain 80, but Lehman would lose 100.

41
e.g. 12.6 The Right to an Unobstructed View
  • In this case, the best solution/ optimal
    structure of property rights would be to prohibit
    any building that blocks a neighbor's view.
  • i.e. the court would comes in and take over the
    role of resource allocation.
  • Since the legal system may have a lower cost in
    assigning property rights and resolving conflicts
    between private parties.

42
e.g. 12.6 The Right to an Unobstructed View
  • Of course, in these examples, if the valuations
    assigned by parties were different, a different
    conclusion might follow.
  • If Martin valued the two-story house at 300 and
    Lehman valued the view at only 80, the optimal
    structure of property rights would be to allow
    people to build to whatever height they choose.

43
Modified Coase Theorem
  • The optimal structure of property rights is the
    one that places the burden of adjustment (either
    the loss of a view or the loss of a preferred
    building design) on the party that can accomplish
    it at the lowest cost.
  • As a practical matter, the laws of property in
    many jurisdictions often embody precisely this
    principle.

44
Legal Remedies for Externalities
  • As said above, legal remedies are often chosen in
    correcting externalities.
  • The most common form would be the use of taxation
    in tackling negative externalities and the use
    subsidies in tackling positive externalities.
  • In particular, the most efficient form of
    taxation/ subsidies would be to impose a per-unit
    tax/ subsidy that equals to the marginal value of
    the externality.

45
Per Unit Tax on Negative Externality
46
Per Unit Subsidy on Positive Externality
Private equilibrium with per unit subsidy
Social optimum
XB 6/ ton
Subsidy 6/ ton
14
MC
10
Subsidized demand Private demand per unit
subsidy
8
Private demand
1,200
1,600
47
e.g. 12.7 Taxing Negative Externalities
  • Two firms, X and Y, have access to five different
    production processes, each one has a different
    cost and gives off a different amount of
    pollution.

If pollution is unregulated, and negotiation
between the firms and their victims is
impossible, each firm will use A, the least
costly of the five processes. Each will emit 4
tons of pollution per day, for a total pollution
of 8 tons/day.
48
e.g. 12.7 Taxing Negative Externalities
  • The city council wants to cut smoke emissions by
    half. To accomplish this, they are considering
    two options.
  • I. Require each firm to curtail its emissions by
    half.
  • II. Set a tax of T on each ton of smoke emitted
    each day.
  • How large would T have to be in order to curtail
    emissions by half?
  • And how would the total costs to society be
    different under the two alternatives?

49
e.g. 12.7 Taxing Negative Externalities
  • I If each firm is required to cut pollution by
    half, each must switch from process A to process
    C.
  • It will result in two tons/day of pollution for
    each firm.

The cost of the switch for firm X will be
700/day-200/day500/day. The cost to Y will
be 140/day-50/day90/day, So increase in total
production cost for the two firms 590/day.
50
e.g. 12.7 Taxing Negative Externalities
  • II How will each firm respond to a pollution tax
    of T/ ton of pollution?Switching to the next
    process will cut pollution by 1 ton per day and
    save tax of T/day.
  • Thus, if cost of switching to the next process
    is less than or equal to T, it will switch,
    otherwise not.

51
e.g. 12.7 Taxing Negative Externalities
  • T 50/ton Firm X would stick with process A.
    Firm Y will switch to process B.

A tax of 50/ton thus does not produce the desired
50 percent reduction in pollution.
52
e.g. 12.7 Taxing Negative Externalities
  • T 91/ton. X will adopt process B, Y will adopt
    process D.

Total emissions will be the desired 4 tons/day.
Cost to firm X will be 290/day-200/day 90/day.
Cost to firm Y will be 230/day-50/day 180/day.
Increase in total production cost for both
firms is thus only 270/day, or 320/day less than
policy I.
53
e.g. 12.7 Taxing Negative Externalities
  • Note that the taxes paid by the firm are not
    included in our reckoning of social costs,
    because this money is not lost to the society.
  • The tax revenue can be used to reduce whatever
    taxes would otherwise have to be levied on
    citizens.
  • Thus, policy II would be more effective than
    policy I from the social point of view.

54
Property Rights and the Tragedy of Commons
  • The Problem of Unpriced Resources
  • A common refers to a resource with NO clearly
    defined property rights
  • Thus, any parties can be entitled to the use of
    it
  • When no one owns the commons, the opportunity
    cost of using it is not considered by these
    individuals
  • i.e. One persons use of the commons imposes an
    external cost on the others by making the
    property less valuable. Still, no one will pay
    attention to it.

55
Property Rights and the Tragedy of Commons
  • The Problem of Unpriced Resources
  • Thus, a common will be kept using until all its
    value (to the society) is being exploited.
  • We can expect that no one will be willing to pay
    a positive price in acquiring these commons.
  • e.g. Would you like to buy an orange tree that is
    located along the Nathan Road, Kowloon?

56
Property Rights and the Tragedy of Commons
  • The Problem of Unpriced Resources
  • The Tragedy of Commons is a classic theory in
    economics that describes the dissipation of value
    of a valuable resource under undefined property
    rights.
  • Without clearly defined property rights in
    protecting resources, economic agents will NOT be
    restrained from their selfish behaviour.

57
e.g. 12.8 The Tragedy of the Commons
In the following example, we will show how
individuals steering (cow breeding) decision
will exploit the value of a commonly owned
pasture (land with grass). Then, we will see how
cooperation alleviate the value dissipation
problem on pastures.
58
e.g. 12.8 The Tragedy of the Commons
  • A village has five residents, each of whom has
    accumulated savings of 100.
  • Each villager has two investment opportunities
  • Buy government bond for 100 that pays 12
    interest per year, totally risk free.
  • Buy a year-old steer for 100, send it onto the
    commons to graze, then sell it after one year.

59
e.g. 12.8 The Tragedy of the Commons
  • The Relationship Between Herd Size, Selling
    Price, and Profit per Steer

If each person decides individually how to
invest, how many steers will be sent onto the
commons?
60
e.g. 12.8 The Tragedy of the Commons
If each person decides individually how to
invest, how many steers will be sent onto the
commons? (reminder each person has 100 to
invest on either 100 bond OR a 100 steer)
  • Opportunity cost of investing in one steer
    return on government bond 12
  • Send steer if and only if price of 2-year-old
    steer is at least 112
  • Four of the villagers send 1 steer, and hence a
    total of 4 steers.
  • Total village income 12 bond 4 steers X
    (12) 60

61
e.g. 12.8 The Tragedy of the Commons
However, what is the socially optimal number of
steers?
  • Decision rule for socially optimal
    investmentSend another steer only if the NET
    value of the herd increases by at least 12,
    otherwise invest in bond.
  • Thus, we should send a second steer but not a
    third. Total village income 32 (by 2 steers)
    36 (by 3 bond) 68

62
e.g. 12.8 The Tragedy of the Commons
  • If the 5 villagers act individually in investment
    decision (objective max individual income)
  • 4 villagers will buy graze steers and 1 will buy
    bond
  • Total village income 12 1 buy bond 4
    steers X (12) 60
  • If the 5 villagers act cooperatively (objective
    max villages total income)
  • Only 2 villagers will graze steers. The remaining
    3 will notice that to the village, the 3rd
    steers return is lower than bond return, so
    these 3 people will buy bond
  • Total village income 32 (by 2 steers) 36
    (by 3 bond) 68

63
e.g. 12.8 The Tragedy of the Commons
  • The problem with private decisions is that no
    individual has any incentive to take into account
    that an extra steer will eat grass (and thus
    reduce the return on 2-yr-steer price) that
    otherwise would have been available to the steers
    already on the commons.
  • The tragedy of the commons is thus a type of
    externality.

64
e.g. 12.9 The Tragedy of the Commons
  • Sam and Stan are identical twins with a craving
    for chocolate malted milkshakes, and have agreed
    to share one.
  • If each has a straw and each knows that the other
    is self-interested, will the rate at which they
    consume the milkshake be optimal?
  • Each knows that any part of the milkshake he
    doesn't drink will be drunk by the other.
  • So each consumes at a faster rate than he would
    if he had half the shake all to himself.

65
Examples of Tragedies of the CommonsHarvesting
timber on public land.
Each tree cutter knows that a tree not harvested
this year will be bigger, and hence more
valuable, next year. But he also knows that if
he doesn't cut the tree down this year, someone
else will.
66
Examples of Tragedies of the Commons Picking
blackberries in a public park
Each individual knows that the blackberries would
taste better if allowed to ripen for another
week. But each also knows that blackberries
not eaten today may not be there next week.
67
Examples of Tragedies of the CommonsHarvesting
whales in international waters
Each individual whaler knows that harvesting an
extra whale reduces the breeding population of
whales and hence the size of future whale
populations. But he also knows that any whale
he fails to harvest today will just be taken by
some other whaler.
68
Private Property Rights
  • Clearly defined property rights are one way to
    solve the tragedy of the commons
  • 3 essential features of private property rights
  • 1. right to exclusive use
  • 2. right to income
  • 3. right to ownership transfer

69
Defined property rights as a solution to tragedy
of the commons
Weyerhauser, an international forest products
company, doesn't cut trees down too quickly on
its own land.
70
Defined property rights as a solution to tragedy
of the commons
People don't harvest blackberries too soon from
their backyard garden.
71
Regulation as a solution to tragedy of the commons
When private property rights is hard to implement
and enforce, regulations can be an alternative
solution to commons.
e.g. Fishing licenses limit the amount of fish
that can be taken
72
Regulation as a solution to tragedy of the commons
Laws regulate air and water pollutants.
73
Regulation as a solution to tragedy of the commons
Zoning laws limit the size and other features of
buildings, signs, land-use patterns, etc.
74
e.g. 12.10 taxation as solution to tragedy of
commons
  • Last but not least, taxation is also a solution
    to commons.
  • In the steer-grazing economy considered earlier,
    suppose there is now a 25 tax on income earned
    from steering.
  • If people decide individually between bonds and
    cattle, how many steers will be sent onto the
    commons?

75
e.g. 12.10 taxation as solution to tragedy of
commons
With a 25 tax on income from steers, only 2
steers will be sent onto the commons, and this is
the socially optimal number.
Total income 3(12) 2(12) 8
68 (bonds) (steers) (tax)
76
Coming next
  • Tragedy of Commons illustrate how the deficiency
    of property rights will generate value
    dissipation on valuable resources.
  • Next, we will turn to look at Positional
    Externality in economics

77
Positional Externalities
  • Positional Externality
  • When an increase in one persons performance
    reduces the expected reward of another in
    situations in which reward depends on relative
    performance
  • e.g. Champion in tennis competition/
  • first position in exams

78
Positional Externalities
  • Payoffs That Depend on Relative Performance
  • In a competitive situation
  • There is an incentive to take an action to
    increase the odds of winning.
  • The overall gain to the players as a group will
    be zero.
  • When the payoff depends on relative performance,
    incentive to invest in performance activities
    will be excessive from a collective point of view.

79
e.g. 12.11 Why do football players take anabolic
steroids?
  • Smith and Jones are competing for a single
    position and a 1 million contract.

80
e.g. 12.11 Why do football players take anabolic
steroids?
Jones
Dont take steroids
Take steroids
Dont take steroids
Smith
Take steroids
  • Dominant strategy for each yields the third best
    outcome
  • This prisoners dilemma outcome is the attraction
    of rules banning performance-enhancing drugs.

81
Positional Arms Race and Positional Arms Control
Agreement
  • Positional Arms Race
  • A series of mutually offsetting investments in
    performance enhancement that is stimulated by a
    positional externality
  • e.g. steroid-consumption scandals in
    Olympics/
  • advertising/
  • political campaign spending

82
Positional Arms Race and Positional Arms Control
Agreement
  • Positional Arms Control Agreement
  • An agreement in which contestants attempt to
    limit mutually offsetting investments in
    performance enhancements
  • Campaign spending limits
  • Roster limits
  • Arbitration agreements
  • Mandatory starting dates for kindergarten

83
End of Chapter
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com