Title: Economic Causes and Consequences of Obesity
1Presented by Eric Finkelstein, Ph.D.
3040 Cornwallis Road P.O. Box 12194
Research Triangle Park, NC 27709
Phone 919-541-8074
Fax 919-541-6683
e-mail finkelse_at_rti.org www.rti.org
RTI International is a trade name of Research
Triangle Institute
2Outline
- Obesity Prevalence
- Economic Causes
- Other Causes of Obesity
- Why Should (or Shouldnt) We Care About Obesity?
- Proper Role of Government
- The Employers Dilemma
- Can the Economy Solve the Problem?
- Conclusion
3Current Obesity Prevalence Rates Select
Countries
Source WHO Global Database on Body Mass Index
and OECD Factbook 2006 Quality of Life
Obesity
4Trends Among Youth
- 17 of U.S. children are overweight and many
more are at-risk - Over the last 30 years
- rate of overweight for 6-11 year olds tripled
(from 4 to almost 19) - rate of overweight for 12-19 year olds increased
from 6 to over 17 - Since 1990, twice as many children aged 2-5 are
overweight (13.9 vs. 7.2) - Large racial disparities among kids
- Overweight prevalence rose by more than 120
among African American and Hispanic children
compared with 50 among Caucasians from 1986 to
1998
5Calories In
Foods Equivalent to about 100 Calories
- A net caloric imbalance of about 100 calories
per day could generate an average weight gain of
10lbs per year (Hill et al).
6Calories In
- In 2004, the average American consumed 52 gallons
of soft drinks - represents a 50 increase from 1980
- Fruit juice consumption increased by 40 since
1980 - Soft drinks are the number one food consumed in
the American diet - accounting for 7 of all calories consumed
7Calories In (youth)
- Caloric intake changes from NHANES I (1971-74) to
NHANES (1999-2000) - Children
- Boys 2,550 to 2,800 kcal/day (10)
- Girls 1,780 to 1,900 kcal/day (7)
- Boys consume 300 more soft drinks than in the
1970s (from 7oz. to 22oz. per day) - Childrens sugar consumption is twice what is
recommended
8- But why the increase in consumption?
9Cheap Food Gets Cheaper
- Food costs (both money and time) have been
steadily declining - Greatest drops are for calorie dense foods
- Since 1960, the relative price of food compared
with other goods has decreased by 16 - Since 1978, food prices have dropped by 38
(until very recently) - Since 1983, prices of fresh fruits and
vegetables, all fruits and vegetables, fish, and
dairy products have increased by 190, 144, 100
and 82, respectively - Fats and oils, sugars and sweets, and carbonated
beverages increased at much lower ratesby 70,
66, and 32, respectively
10Non-Monetary Costs
- Opportunity cost of preparing foods from scratch
continues to increase relative to purchasing
prepared and pre-packaged foods - Increased prevalence/convenience of fast-food and
restaurants lowers acquisition costs - Technology lowers the cost of preparing
pre-packaged foods more than it does for foods
cooked from scratch - Consider the microwave
- 95 of homes have them today
- 8 had them in 1978
11Calories Out
12Activities and Calories Burned Per Hour
Source METs Compendium
13Changes in Caloric ExpenditureLeisure Activity
- The (opportunity) costs of being physically
active continue to increase
14Changes in Caloric ExpenditureLeisure Activity
- The benefits of inactive leisure have gone up
so we would expect leisure time physical activity
to decrease - Internet, computer games, cable TV,
- Between 1970 and 2000, the of homes with more
than one TV rose from 35 to 75 - Those with cable TV rose from 7 to 76
- 55 of homes now have Internet access
15Average Hours Per Day Spent in Leisure and Sports
Activities
Source Bureau of Labor Statistics, Dept. of
Labor, U.S. GovernmentAmerican Time Use Survey
(ATUS) 2003 Released September 2004
16Inactivity Among Youth
- 1/4 of U.S. young people (ages 12-21 years)
report no vigorous physical activity - About 14 of young people report no recent
vigorous or light to moderate physical activity - Participation in all types of physical activity
declines as grade in school increases - 17 of children watch TV for 5 hours a day vs.
36 who watch TV for less than an hour a day
17Non-Leisure Time Physical Activity
- The (opportunity) costs of being active on the
job have gone up - Due to technology, you can accomplish more by
doing less (energy expenditure) - More physical activity would decrease
productivity (and wages) - Many of us could choose more active (and lower
paying) jobs but at a significant cost (Ill
return to this point)
18Non-Leisure Time Physical Activity
- After 18 years, an average male worker will weigh
25 pounds more if he works in the lowest-fitness
demanding job than if he had worked in the
highest fitness-demanding jobs - Accidental exercise is hard to come by
- We used to get paid to exercise, we now have to
pay to exercise (Lakdawalla Phillipson, 2007) - Note a 30-minute jog followed by 8 hours at a
desk job falls short of the 10,000 Steps
recommendation
19Recap
- The rise in obesity rates is a direct result of
changes in relative costs that promote excess
food consumption and inactivity (at work, at
home, and in between) - Prices and opportunity cost of food consumption
has decreased - Largest decrease is for high calorie foods
- Benefits of inactive leisure have gone up
- Opportunity costs of active labor have gone up
- Net Effect rising rates of obesity
- Note much of these changes are technology
driven and reflect consumer preferences
20Other Causes of Obesity?
21Sprawl
- In 1960, 64 of people drove to work, 10 walked,
and 12 used public transportation - In 2000, 88 drove to work, 3 walked, and 5
used public transportation - A survey of Atlanta residents (Frank) found that
each half-hour spent in the car is associated
with a 3 greater likelihood of being obese.
Those who commuted by foot were far less likely
to be obese - For many, long commutes are also a choice and are
largely driven by property values
22One More Potential Cause of Rising Obesity Rates
Moral Hazard
23Moral Hazard
- Over the past few decades, there has been a
tremendous increase in medical, pharmacological
and surgical treatments for the risk factors and
diseases that are promoted by obesity - Statins for cholesterol
- Metformin for diabetes
- Many new BP meds
- Over 1.5 million procedures performed last year
in the U.S. aimed at opening up clogged arteries
24Moral Hazard
- Among todays obese population, the prevalence of
high cholesterol and high blood pressure are now
21, and 18 percentage points lower, respectively,
than among obese persons 30 to 40 years ago
(Gregg et al) - Todays obese population has better BP and
Cholesterol values than normal weight adults had
a few decades ago (Gregg et al) - Maybe being obese is not so costly anymore
25Recap Its the Economy, Stupid
- Obesity is the result of technological
advancements that have changed relative costs of
food consumption, physical activity, and obesity - Decreased cost of food consumption
- Increased cost of physical activity
- Decreased health costs of being obese
- Technology (or a growing economy) is responsible
for (or at least exacerbates) rising rates of
obesity - Obesity is a side-effect of our own success
26- We may be fatter, but are we worse off?
27A Growing Waistline Can Be Bad For Your Health
- Substantial excess weight reduces life
expectancy, but most notably for BMIs 35 - Excess weight causes 70 of diabetes cases in the
United States - Excess weight greatly increases the risks of
developing hypertension and high cholesterol - Obesity adversely affects nearly every system of
the human body
28A Growing Waistline Can Be Bad For Your Health
SOURCE NAASO, The Obesity Society
29Utility Maximizing
A Growing Waistline Can Be Bad For Your Health
but Diet and Exercise have their own costs
30So Is There a Role for Government?
31Role of Gov. as Seen by Economists
- Government should intervene only in the case of
market failures (or undo past government
failures) - Market Failure occurs when resources are not
being allocated efficiently by the private sector - Externalities
- Market Power
- Public Goods
- Imperfect (Asymmetric) Information
- Consumer Irrationality
32The Role of Government When It Comes to Obesity
- Where are the market (or government) failures?
33Externalities
- Second-hand smoke provides a clear motivation for
government interventions to reduce smoking rates - Smokers impact non-smokers
- Does obesity increase the health risks of those
they come into contact with? - Not likely
- Obesity in Pregnancy may be one exception
- Increases risk for the offspring
- During pregnancy delayed diagnosis, increased
cesarean and instrumental delivery, preeclampsia,
eclampsia, and gestational diabetes - For the child neural tube defects, spina bifida,
heart defects and delivery-related neonatal
morbidity - Provides a role for government to address obesity
among women of child-bearing age
34Market Power
- More (not less) market power would be helpful
when it comes to obesity - Monopolists tend to raise prices
- Recent surge in food prices may slow rising rate
of obesity
35Public Goods
- The government already funds many public goods
related to obesity - 83.6 million acres of public parks and
recreational facilities - Food Guide Pyramid
- 200 million Steps to a HealthierUS Initiative
- CDC funded obesity prevention programs
- 440 million NIH budget for obesity research (up
250 since 1998) - Could gov. do more, yes, but would it help?
36Imperfect (Asymmetric) Information
- Lots of markets function fine with asymmetric
information - Should government force mandatory labeling for
store-bought foods or restaurant foods? - FDA advisory panel says no
- Key Question - Can the market solve this issue
without government intervention (i.e., is there a
market failure)?
37Irrationality
- Are consumers able to maximize utility subject to
their constraints? - Evidence of food addictions but can these be
overcome? - Can we not over-exercise to make up for
over-consumption or control our consumption? - Some cannot but most can
38Financial Externality
- Is government intervention warranted to save
money?
39Financial Externality
- Overweight and obesity increase the annual
medical bill by 90 billion per year - In the absence of overweight and obesity, health
insurance expenditures would be 9 lower - Medicare expenditures would be 11 lower
- The government finances half of the total annual
medical costs attributable to obesity, or more
than 45 billion per year - The average taxpayer spends 175 per year to
finance obesity-related medical expenditures
among Medicare and Medicaid recipients
40Financial Externality (cont.)
- But is this a reasonable justification for
government intervention? - Arent Medicare and Medicaid entitlement programs
by design? - Hard to use these costs to justify government
intervention - If unhappy about these costs, solution is easy
- Experience rate
- Resolving the financial externality would suggest
that only cost-saving interventions are warranted - These dont exist to my knowledge
- Would also suggest giving away free cigarettes!
41So Is There a Role for Government?
- Government imposes laws and regulations that
influence food consumption and physical activity
decisions - This ultimately influences rates of obesity
- An appropriate role may not be to solve existing
market failures, but to revisit past laws and
regulations to determine whether or not they may
be doing more harm than good - Farm bill, zoning, publicly provided health
insurance, - But kids are a different story
- The utility maximization argument is unlikely to
hold for them - Bad decisions as youth are especially hard to
undue - Easier sell for youth-focused government
interventions
42The Employers Dilemma
43CHAPTER TEN
44The Employers Dilemma
- Why Dont Businesses Invest More in the Health of
their Workforce?
45Missed Work Days by BMI Category
46Annual Medical Expenditure for Normal Weight and
Obese Employees 2001-2003 Medical
Expenditure Panel Survey
Source Finkelstein, E.A. and D.S. Brown. 2006.
Why Does the Private Sector Underinvest in
Obesity Prevention and Treatment? North Carolina
Medical Journal 67(4)310-312
47Why Dont Businesses Invest More in the Health of
their Workforce?
- Unlike government, most employers are profit
maximizers and will invest in their workforce
only to the extent that it is profit maximizing
to do so - Even though the costs of obesity to employers are
high, expensive obesity-related initiatives are
likely to be a bad investment for many firms
48Why Dont Businesses Invest More in the Health of
their Workforce?
- Employers rarely look further than 5 years down
the road - Individuals switch jobs roughly every 4-5 years
- Investment return is likely to be received by
another businesspossibly even competitor (e.g.
gastric bypass surgery) - Little financial incentive to invest in younger
obese workers who are not yet costly - Medicare further reduces incentives to invest in
obesity treatment - 38 of the 58,000 cost of obesity accrues after
age 65 - Retiree health insurance benefits are
increasingly uncommon
49So Whats an Employer to Do?
- A successful obesity prevention program should
make it cheaper and easier to be thinnot fat - Interventions that change marginal costs and
benefits are likely to be followed by changes in
behavior - It also needs to be profit maximizing for the
employer - Incentive-based programs are increasingly common
and may be cost-saving (Finkelstein et al JOEM)
50Will the Market solve the Obesity Problem?
51Private Sector Solutions
- There is a huge demand for effective weight loss
solutions (and even ineffective ones) - 50 million Americans will attempt to lose weight
this year through many different mechanisms - Companies are hard at work looking for innovative
strategies to reduce rates of obesity and improve
health - Potential profits are enormous
52Private Sector Solutions
- The commercial weight-loss industry is a 49
billion per year industry - Health club memberships have doubled in past 15
years - Sales for anti-obesity agents in the U.S. are
expected to triple by 2010 from 723 million in
2005 to 1.4 billion - Between 1998 and 2004, bariatric procedures,
including bypass and banding, have increased by
more than 800 in the U.S. - Active video games and other technologies are
increasingly popular - Public health folks may not like some of these
solutions but they may be optimal from a utility
maximizing perspective
53Conclusion
- Obesity is a side-effect of our own success
- Utility maximizing individuals may optimally
choose to weigh more than public health officials
would like - Government efforts should focus on revisiting
past policies that may have inadvertently
promoted rising rates of obesity - Optimal private sector response may be to use
incentives or other strategies that make it
cheaper and easier to be thin, not fat - Technology is part of the problem but will also
be part of the solution