Title: Zhigang LI University of Hong Kong
1Zhigang LIUniversity of Hong Kong
Perfectly Competitive Supply The Cost Side of
The Market
2Example 6.1. How should Leroy divide his time
between
picking apples
and writing pulp fiction?
Note Pulp magazines (or pulp fiction often
referred to as the pulps) were inexpensive
fiction magazines. They were widely published
from the 1920s through the 1950s. The term pulp
fiction can also refer to mass market paperbacks
since the 1950s. (from Wikipedia)
3Example 6.1. How should Leroy divide his time
between
- A men's magazine will pay Leroy 10 cents per word
to write fiction articles. - He must decide how to divide his time between
writing fiction, which he can do at a constant
rate of 200 words per hour, and harvesting apples
from the trees growing on his land, a task only
he can perform. - His return from harvesting apples depends on both
the price of apples and the quantity of apples he
harvests. - For each hour Leroy spends picking apples, he
loses the 20 he could have earned writing pulp
fiction. - He should thus spend an additional hour picking
as long as he will add at least 20 worth of
apples to his total harvest.
4Example 6.1. How should Leroy divide his time
between
- Earnings aside, Leroy is indifferent between the
two tasks. - The amount of apples he can harvest depends on
the number of hours he devotes to this activity
5Example 6.1. How should Leroy divide his time
between
- For example, if apples sell for 2.50 per bushel
- Leroy would earn 20 for the first hour he spent
picking apples, but would earn only an additional
10 if he spent a second hour. - Leroy will devote only the first hour to picking
apples. That is, a total of 8 apples.
6Example 6.1. How should Leroy divide his time
between
- If the price of apples then rose to 5 per
bushel
- It would pay Leroy to devote a second hour to
picking, which would mean a total of 12 bushels
of apples.
7Example 6.1. How should Leroy divide his time
between
- Once the price of apples reached 6.67 per bushel
- Leroy would devote a third hour to picking
apples, for a total of 15 bushels.
8Example 6.1. How should Leroy divide his time
between
- If the price rose to 10 per bushel
- Leroy would devote a fourth hour to picking
apples, for a total of 17 bushels.
9Example 6.1. How should Leroy divide his time
between
- If the price rose to 20 per bushel
- Leroy would devote a fifth hour to picking
apples, for a total of 18 bushels.
10Example 6.1. How should Leroy divide his time
between
Leroy's individual supply curve for apples
relates the amount of apples he is willing to
supply at various prices.
11Example 6.1. How should Leroy divide his time
between
- Marginal cost can be computed
The perfectly competitive firms supply curve is
its marginal cost curve.
12Market Supply
- The quantity that corresponds to any given price
on the market supply curve is the sum of the
quantities supplied at that price by all
individual sellers in the market.
13Example 6.2.
- If the supply side of the apple market consisted
of 100 suppliers just like Leroy, what would the
market supply curve for apples look like?
14Reasons for upward sloping supply
- The Fruit Picker's Rule (Always pick the
low-hanging fruit first). - When fruit prices are low, it might pay to
harvest the low-hanging fruit but not the fruit
growing higher up the tree, which takes more
effort to get to. - But if fruit prices rise sufficiently, it will
pay to harvest not only the low-hanging fruit,
but also the fruit on higher branches. - Differences among suppliers in opportunity cost
- People facing unattractive employment
opportunities in other occupations may be willing
to pick apples even when the price of apples is
low. - Those with more attractive options will pick
apples only if the price of apples is relatively
high.
15Profit-Maximizing Firms and Perfectly Competitive
Markets
- Definition. The profit earned by a firm is the
total revenue it receives from the sale of its
product minus all costsexplicit and
implicitincurred in producing it. - Definition. A profit-maximizing firm is one whose
primary goal is to maximize the difference
between its total revenues and total costs. - Definition. A perfectly competitive market is
one in which no individual supplier has
significant influence on the market price of the
product.
16Profit-Maximizing Firms and Perfectly Competitive
Markets
- Definition. A price taker is a firm that has no
influence over the price at which it sells its
product.
Laundry
Art reproduction
17Price setters
Intel microprocessors
Microsoft operating systems
18Price setter vs. price taker
Apple iPod Price setter
Generic USB MP3 player price taker
19Factor of production
- Definition. A factor of production is an input
used in the production of a good or service.
20Fixed factor of production
- Definition. A fixed factor of production is an
input whose quantity cannot be altered in the
short run.
Example Transmission tower for a student radio
station.
21Variable factor of production
- Definition. A variable factor of production is an
input whose quantity can be altered in the short
run.
Example Music library for a student radio
station.
22Example 6.3. Louisville Slugger uses two inputs
labor (e.g., woodworkers) and capital (e.g.,
lathes, tools, buildings)
A lathe is a tool which spins a block of material
to perform various operations such as cutting,
sanding, knurling, or deformation with tools that
are applied to the workpiece to create an object
which has symmetry about an axis of rotation.
to transform raw materials (e.g., lumber)
into finished output (baseball bats).
23The short-run production function
Note that output gains begin to diminish with the
third employee. Economists refer to this
pattern as the law of diminishing returns, and it
always refers to situations in which at least
some factors of production are fixed.
24Some Important Cost Concepts
- Suppose the lease payment for the Louisville
Sluggers lathe and factory is 80 per day. - This payment is both a fixed cost (since it does
not depend on the number of bats per day the firm
makes) and, for the duration of the lease, a sunk
cost. - FC rK
25Some Important Cost Concepts
- The companys payment to its employees is called
variable cost, because unlike fixed cost, it
varies with the number of bats the company
produces. - VC wL
26Some Important Cost Concepts
- The firms total cost is the sum of its fixed and
variable costs - Total cost Fixed Cost Variable Cost
- TC FC VC
- TC rK wL
27Some Important Cost Concepts
- The firms marginal cost is the change in total
cost divided by the corresponding change in
output. - MC DTC/DQ
- MC DVC/DQ
28Example 6.4.
- If Louisville slugger pays a fixed cost of 80
per day, and to each employee a wage of 24/day,
calculate the companys output, variable cost,
total cost and marginal cost for each level of
employment.
29Example 6.4.
30Choosing Output to Maximize Profit
- If a companys goal is to maximize its profit, it
should continue to expand its output as long as
the marginal benefit from expanding is at least
as great as the marginal cost.
31Example 6.5.
- Suppose the wholesale price of each bat (net of
lumber and other materials costs) is 2.50. - How many bats should Louisville Slugger produce?
32Example 6.5.
- If we compare this marginal benefit (2.50 per
bat) with the marginal cost entries shown in
table, we see that the firm should keep expanding
until it reaches 175 bats per day (6 employees
per day).
33Example 6.5.
- To confirm that the cost-benefit principle thus
applied identifies the profit-maximizing number
of bottles to produce, we can calculate profit
levels directly
34Choosing Output to Maximize Profit
- When the law of diminishing returns applies (that
is, when some factors of production are fixed),
marginal cost goes up as the firm expands
production beyond some point. - Under these circumstances, the firm's best option
is to keep expanding output as long as marginal
cost is less than price. - The profit maximizing output level for the
perfectly competitive firm - P MC
35Note on Example 6.5.
- Note in Example 6.5 that if the company's fixed
cost had been any more than 293.50 per day (say,
300), it would have made a loss at every possible
level of output.
36Note on Example 6.5.
- As long as it still had to pay its fixed cost,
however, its best bet would have been to continue
producing 175 bats per day, because a smaller
loss is better than a larger one. - If a firm in that situation expected conditions
to remain the same, it would want to get out of
the bat business as soon as its equipment lease
expired.
37A Note on the Firms Shut-Down Condition
- It might seem that a firm that can sell as much
output as it wishes at a constant market price
would always do best in the short run by
producing and selling the output level for which
price equals marginal cost. - But there are exceptions to this rule.
38A Note on the Firms Shut-Down Condition
- Suppose, for example, that the market price of
the firms product falls so low that its revenue
from sales is smaller than its variable cost at
all possible levels of output. - The firm should then cease production for the
time being. - By shutting down, it will suffer a loss equal to
its fixed costs. - But by remaining open, it would suffer an even
larger loss.
39A Note on the Firms Shut-Down Condition
- P market price of the product
- Q number of units produced and sold
- PxQ total revenue from sales
- Shutdown rule
- Cease production if PxQ is less than VC for every
level of Q.
40Average Variable Cost and Average Total Cost
- Suppose that the firm is unable to cover its
variable cost at any level of outputthat is,
suppose that PxQ - Then P obtain the second inequality by simply dividing
both sides of the first one by Q. - The firms short-run shut-down condition may thus
be restated a second way - Discontinue operations in the short run if the
product price is less than the minimum value of
its average variable cost (AVC).
41Short-run shut-down condition (alternate version)
42Profitability
- Average total cost
- ATC TC/Q.
- Profit total revenue total cost
- PxQ ATCxQ
- (P ATC) Q
- A firm can be profitable only if the price of
its product price (P) exceeds its ATC.
43A Graphical Approach to Profit-Maximization
- For Louisville Slugger, we have
44A Graphical Approach to Profit-Maximization
Properties of the cost curves
- The upward sloping portion of the marginal cost
curve (MC) corresponds to the region of
diminishing returns. - The marginal cost curve must intersect both the
average variable cost curve (AVC) and the average
total cost curve (ATC) at their respective
minimum points.
45Price Marginal Cost The Maximum-Profit
Condition
- In earlier examples, we implicitly assumed that
the firm could employ workers only in whole
number amounts. - Under these conditions, we saw that the
profit-maximizing output level was one for which
marginal cost was somewhat less than price
(because adding yet another employee would have
pushed marginal cost higher than price). - But when output and employment can be varied
continuously, the maximum-profit condition is
that price be equal to marginal cost.
46Example 6.6.
- For the bat-maker whose cost curves are shown in
the next slide, find the profit-maximizing output
level if bats sell for 0.80 each. - How much profit will this firm earn?
- What is the lowest price at which this firm would
continue to operate in the short run?
47Example 6.6.
- The cost-benefit principle tells us that this
firm should continue to expand as long as price
is at least as great as marginal cost. - If the firm follows this rule it will produce 130
bats per day, the quantity at which price and
marginal cost are equal.
48Example 6.6.
- Suppose that the firm had sold some amount less
than 130say, only 100 bats per day. - Its benefit from expanding output by one bat
would then be the bat's market price, 80 cents. - The cost of expanding output by one bat is equal
(by definition) to the firms marginal cost,
which at 100 bats per day is only 40 cents.
MB
MC
49Example 6.6.
- So by selling the 101st bat for 80 cents and
producing it for an extra cost of only 40 cents,
the firm will increase its profit by 80 40 40
cents per day. - In a similar way, we can show that for any
quantity less than the level at which price
equals marginal cost, the seller can boost profit
by expanding production.
MB
MC
50Example 6.6.
- Conversely, suppose that the firm were currently
selling more than 130 bats per daysay, 150at a
price of 80 cents each. - Marginal cost at an output of 150 is 1.32 per
bat. If the firm then contracted its output by
one bat per day, it would cut its costs by 1.32
cents while losing only 80 cents in revenue. As
a result, its profit would grow by 52 cents per
day.
MC
MB
51Example 6.6.
- The same arguments can be made regarding any
quantities that differ from 130. - Thus, if the firm were selling fewer than 130
bats per day, it could earn more profit by
expanding and that if it were selling more than
130, it could earn more by contracting. - So at a market price of 80 cents per bat, the
seller maximizes its profit by selling 130 units
per week, the quantity for which price and
marginal cost are exactly the same.
52Example 6.6.
- Total revenue PxQ
- (0.80/bat)x(130 bats/day)
- 104 per day.
- Total cost ATCxQ
- 0.48/bat x 130 bats/day
- 62.40/day
- So the firms profit is 41.60/day.
53Example 6.6.
- Profit is equal to (P ATC)xQ, which is equal to
the area of the shaded rectangle.
54Example The Holiday Store at Tung Lung Island
Why does the store open only on holidays?
55SUPPLY AND PRODUCER SURPLUS
- The economic surplus received by a buyer is
called consumer surplus. - The analogous construct for a seller is producer
surplus, the difference between the price a
seller actually receives for the product and the
lowest price for which she would have been
willing to sell it (her reservation price, which
in general will be her marginal cost). - Producer surplus sometimes refers to the surplus
received by a single seller in a transaction,
sometimes to the total surplus received by all
sellers in a market or collection of markets.
56Example 6.7. Calculating Producer Surplus
- How much do sellers benefit from their
participation in the market for cashews?
57Example 6.7. Calculating Producer Surplus
- For all cashews sold up to 8,000 pounds per day,
sellers receive a surplus equal to the difference
between the market price of 8 per pound and
their reservation price as given by the supply
curve. - Total producer surplus received by buyers in the
cashew market is the area of the shaded triangle
between the supply curve and the market price
PS (1/2)(8,000 lbs/day)x(8/lb) 32,000/day
58Producer surplus
- Producer surplus is the highest price sellers
would pay, in the aggregate, for the right to
continue participating in the cashew market.
59Supply is all about marginal cost.
60End