Asset Pricing with Disequilibrium Price Adjustment: Theory and Empirical Evidence - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 61
About This Presentation
Title:

Asset Pricing with Disequilibrium Price Adjustment: Theory and Empirical Evidence

Description:

... have a very long history. ... analyze 30 firms of the Dow Jones Index. ... for most sample portfolios are close to three, which indicates that heavy ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:146
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 62
Provided by: centerforp1
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Asset Pricing with Disequilibrium Price Adjustment: Theory and Empirical Evidence


1
Asset Pricing with Disequilibrium Price
Adjustment Theory and Empirical Evidence
  • Dr. Cheng Few Lee
  • Distinguished Professor of Finance
  • Rutgers, The State University of New
    JerseyEditor of Review of Quantitative Finance
    and Accounting
  • Editor of Review of Pacific Basin Financial
    Markets and Policies

2
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • Another way to analyze the demand and supply
    functions derived in the previous section is to
    reexamine equations (9 and 12), considering the
    possibilities of market in disequilibrium.
    Disequilibrium models have a very long history.
    All the partial adjustment models are in fact
    disequilibrium models. Much of the literature
    concerning the structure of disequilibrium
    markets focus on the commercial loan market and
    the labor market. For the commercial loan
    market, the structure of disequilibrium is
    frequently due to the governments credit
    rationing for economic policies. For the labor
    market the structural disequilibrium is
    frequently due to a rigid wage. The theory of
    credit rationing is first developed by Jaffee
    (1971) for a commercial loan market. One of the
    reasons for credit rationing is the existence of
    bankruptcy costs, as proposed by Miller (1977).
    Given that bankruptcy costs rise when firms fail,
    banks thus choose a lower amount of loan
    offerings than they would have if there were no
    bankruptcy costs. As a result, some firms will
    not receive the loan regardless of the rate they
    are willing to pay.
  • In this section, we discuss and
    develop a model and methodology similar to these
    is sues regarding commercial loan markets. Early
    studies of the disequilibrium model of commercial
    loan markets include Jaffee (1971), Maddala and
    Nelson (1974) and Sealey (1979). One recent
    follow up study is Nehls and Schmidt (2003). They
    use the disequilibrium methodology similar to
    Sealy to evaluate whether loans are constrained
    by demand or supply. In fact, one can see the
    disequilibrium model as a special case of
    simultaneous equation models. Thus, here a
    similar demand and supply schedule is derived but
    solved simultaneously to reexamine the price
    adjustment behavior by assuming that market is in
    disequilibrium.

3
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • All disequilibrium models share the feature
    that prices do not fully adjust to the market
    clearing level. The model used throughout this
    section is a basic model first proposed by Fair
    and Jaffee (1972) and Amemiya (1974) and modified
    as model C in Quandt (1988). This model consists
    of the following equations5
  • (13) QDt a1 Pt ß1X1t µt,
  • (14) QSt a2 Pt ß2X2t ?t ,
  • (15) Qt min (QDt, QSt ),
  • (16) ?Pt Pt - Pt-1 ?(QDt - QSt
    ),

4
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • where the QDt and QSt are the quantities of
    securities demanded and supplied, respectively
    Qt is the actual or observed quantity of
    securities in the market Pt is the observed
    return rate of securities X1t and X2t are
    vectors of exogenous or predetermined variables
    including the lagged Pt-1 a1 and a2 are unknown
    parameters for Pt ß1 and ß2 are vectors of
    unknown parameters for exogenous variables ? is
    an unknown positive scalar parameter and µt and
    ?t are disturbance terms and assumed to be
    jointly normal and independent over time with
    distributions N(0, s2µ) and N(0, s2?)
    respectively. The difficulty comes in estimating
    a1, a2, ß1, ß2, ?, s2µ, and s2? with observations
    of X1t, X2t, Qt and Pt for t 1, 2, , T.

5
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • Some assumptions should to be made to deal
    with the relationships between Qt, QDt QSt and
    the price adjustment process. A basic assumption
    is reflected in equation (15), which shows that
    when demand exceeds supply, the observed quantity
    lies on the supply schedule, and the market is
    characterized by the conditions of excess demand.
    This assumption is often referred to as voluntary
    exchange. That is, in the presence of excess
    demand, seller cannot be forced supply more than
    they wish to supply and in the presence of
    excess supply, purchasers cannot be forced to buy
    more than they wish to buy. Another assumption in
    this model is that the price adjustment is
    proportional to excess demand, which is shown by
    the last equation (16) in the above system. The
    model is also assumed to be identified by
    different sets of exogenous variables (i.e., X1t
    and X2t.)
  • Clearly, the equation system, equations (13) to
    (16), is a special case of simultaneous equation
    models. If there is no equation (15) and if the
    system is identified, one can consistently
    estimate a1, a2, ß1, ß2, ?, s2µ, and s2? by using
    methodologies of simultaneous equation. Since we
    have equation (15) therefore we need to introduce
    equation (16) into the system for estimation of
    a1, a2, ß1, ß2, ?, s2µ, and s2?. However, one
    primary problem exists in this disequilibrium
    model, which is that QDt and QSt are not
    observable variables in the absence of the market
    clearing condition.

6
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • One can reformulate the above model by
    considering periods of rising prices ?Pt 0 and
    periods of falling prices ?Pt in the period with rising prices, the supply
    function (14) can be estimated using the observed
    quantity, Qt, as the dependent variable since
    there will be excess demand and thus Qt will
    equal to QSt. The details of constructing the
    econometric procedures is discussed in next
    section.
  • The last topic of this section is to
    incorporate the demand and supply schedules
    developed in the previous section into this
    disequilibrium equation system. The demand and
    supply schedule in equations (9) and (12) can be
    restated and presented as equations (17) and (18)
    as part of the disequilibrium system as6

7
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • (17)
  • QDt1 cS-1 EtPt1 - cS-1(1 r)Pt
    cS-1EtDt1 µ1t
  • (18)
  • QSt1 QSt A-1B Pt - A-1Et Dt1 µ2t
  • (19)
  • Qt1 min (QDt1, QSt1 )
  • (20)
  • ?Pt ?(QDt1 - QSt1 ).

8
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • From the above equation system, it is clear
    that some conditions in equation (17) and (18)
    are different from the basic disequilibrium
    equation system, particularly QSt in the supply
    schedule. These problems are dealt with, before
    the empirical studies, by imposing more
    assumptions or by using alternative
    specifications in econometric methodologies in
    the next section.

9
IV. ALTERNATIVE METHODS OF ESTIMATING ASSET
PRICING MODEL WITH DISEQUILIBRIUM EFFECT
  • In this section, we first reformulate
    the disequilibrium asset pricing model to allow
    for empirical study. Then we discuss the
    alternative methods of estimating and testing
    price adjustment process in capital asset
    pricing.
  • A. Reformulation of the Disequilibrium Model
  • B. Estimation Methods and Hypothesis of Testing
    Price Adjustment Process
  • 1. 2SLS Estimator
  • 2. Maximum Likelihood Estimator
  • 3. Testing of the Price Adjustment Process

10
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • A. Reformulation of the Disequilibrium Model
  • To estimate a1, a2, ß1, ß2, ?, s2µ, and s2? with
    observations of X1t, X2t, Qt and Pt for t 1, 2,
    , T in equations (13), (14), (15), and (16). It
    is clear that the ordinary least squares will
    produce inconsistent estimators. Following
    Amemiya (1974) and Quandt (1988), we discuss two
    estimation methods to obtain consistent
    estimators.. The first method is the two stage
    least square (2SLS) estimator, and the other is
    the maximum likelihood estimator (MLE).

11
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • Before constructing the estimating procedures,
    the model can be reformulated by considering as
    two different periods, the period of rising
    prices in which ?Pt 0 and the period of falling
    prices, ?Pt prices, there exists excess demand, QDt ? QSt, so
    the quantity observed equals the supply (i.e., Qt
    QSt). As a result, the supply schedule in
    equation (14) now can be estimated by using the
    observed quantity, Qt, as the dependent variable.
    Equation (16) becomes ?Pt ? (QDt - Qt ). or
    QDt ?Pt/? Qt (?Pt is greater than zero here).
    That is, the demand schedule can be rewritten as
  • (21)

12
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • Similarly, for periods of falling prices, there
    exists excess supply, and the supply schedule can
    be rewritten as
  • (22)
  • Or, the system of equations determining the
    endogenous variables can be summarized as
  • when QDt ? QSt,
  • (23a)
  • (23b) Qt a 2 Pt ß2X2t ?t.

13
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • Or when QDt
  • (24a) Qt a1 Pt ß1X1t µt,
  • (24b)

14
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • By defining the following artificial variables,
    the equations (23) and (24) can be summarized as
  • (25a)
  • (25b)
  • where

15
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • B. Estimation Methods and Hypothesis of Testing
    Price Adjustment Process
  • In this section, we first discuss two
    alternative methods (2SLS and MLE) for estimating
    disequilibrium model, then the null hypothesis of
    testing price adjustment process is developed.
  • 1. 2SLS Estimator
  • The equations system shown in (25) contains
    the jointly dependent variables Qt, Pt, , and .
    The parameters in the modified model seem can be
    consistently estimated by conventional two-stage
    least squares (2SLS) method. This can be briefly
    described as the following two stages. In the
    first stage, regress and on
    all the exogenous variables, X1t and X2t to
    obtain the estimations of and
    , then, in the second stage, regress Qt on X1t
    and in equation (25a), and regress Qt on
    X2t and in equation (25b). However, the
    estimators of , , and
    are not asymptotically efficient in this model,
    though could be consistent if the predictions of
    the endogenous variables are used for all
    observations7. The reasons are, first, there is
    no imposed restriction to force the same ? to
    appear in both equations and, second,
    and are not, strictly speaking, linear
    functions of the X1t and X2t.

16
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • 2. Maximum Likelihood Estimator
  • To estimate the parameters of a model as (20),
    Quandt (1988) employs an appropriately formulated
    full-information maximum likelihood technique.
    Let the joint density of the endogenous variables
    Qt and Pt be denoted by ?t (Qt, Pt Xt ) where Xt
    is a vector of the exogenous variables in the
    model.
  • The joint density function ?t can be derived from
    the joint density of the structure disturbances
    ut (µt, ?t). By assuming that the distribution
    of disturbance terms is joint normal, i.i.d.
    distributed with N (0, O), the density ?t becomes

17
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • (26)
  • where the J is the Jacobian determinant
    of the transformation from the disturbances, ut,
    to (Q, Pt ) O is the covariance matrix of the
    structural disturbances and ut is the vector of
    disturbances (µt, ?t). To complete the joint
    density ?t, the Jacobian of the transformation
    must be evaluated separately for?Pt 0and ?Pt 0. In either case, the absolute value of the
    Jacobian is a2a11/?. Therefore, equation (26)
    implied that the log likelihood function is
  • (27)
  • where

18
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • Alternatively, there is another way to derive the
    likelihood function. Amemiya (1974) shows the
    following iterative method of obtaining the
    maximum likelihood estimator.8 Since in period A
    when QDt QSt, the conditional density of ?Pt
    given Qt is N ?(Qt -a2Pt -ß2X2t ), ?2s2?, and
    in period B when QDt density of ?Pt given Qt is N ?(a1Pt ß1X1t
    -Qt), ?2s2µ, then, the log likelihood function
    is
  • (28)

19
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • Thus, the maximum likelihood estimators can be
    obtained by solving the following equations
    simultaneously
  • (29)
  • (a)
  • (b)
  • (c)
  • (d)
  • (e)

20
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • That is, the ML estimators of a and ß are the
    same as LS estimators given ? applied to equation
    (25a) and (25b), respectively. The equations for
    s2µ and s2? (equations c and d) are the residual
    sums of squares of equations (25a) and (25b),
    given ?, divided by T as for the usual ML
    estimators. Equation (d) is a quadratic function
    in ?. Amemiya (1974) suggests the above
    parameters can be solved by using the following
    iterative procedures
  • Step 1 Use 2LSL estimates of a, ß, s2µ and s2?
    as the initial estimates.
  • Step 2 Substitute , , and
    into (e) and solve for the positive root of ?,
    .
  • Step 3 Use in (25) to obtain least squares
    estimates of a, ß, s2µ and s2?.
  • The iteration repeats step 2 and 3 until the
    solutions converge.

21
III. DEVELOPMENT OF DISEQUILIBRIUM MODEL
FOR ASSET PRICING
  • 3. Testing of the Price Adjustment Process
  • Comparing with equilibrium model, the parameter
    of most interest in the disequilibrium model is
    the market adjustment parameter, ?. In the case
    of continuous time, the limiting values of ? are
    zero and infinity. If ? 0, then there is no
    price adjustment in response to an excess demand,
    and if ? is infinity, it indicates instantaneous
    adjustment. In other words, if one assumes there
    is price rigidity in response to an excess
    demand, then the value of ? should be equal to
    zero. That is, the most important test of the
    disequilibrium model is to test the hypothesis
    that the price adjustment parameter is zero. The
    null hypothesis can be stated as if there is no
    price adjustment mechanism in response to an
    excess demand, the value of ? will be equal to
    zero. Or, can be stated as
  • H0 ? 0 vs. H1 ? ? 0.
  • This hypothesis will be empirically tested in the
    following section.

22
IV. ALTERNATIVE METHODS OF ESTIMATING ASSET
PRICING MODEL WITH DISEQUILIBRIUM EFFECT
  • Now that we have our disequilibrium asset
    pricing model for empirical study, we test for
    the price adjustment mechanism by examining the
    market adjustment parameter, ?, as stated in the
    previous section. First in this section, we
    describe our empirical data.
  • A. Data Description
  • 1. International Equity Markets Country
    Indices
  • 2. United States Equity Markets
  • B. Testing the Existence of the Price Adjustment
    Process

23
V. DATA AND TESTING THE EXISTING OF PRICE
ADJUSTMENT PROCESS
  • A. Data Description
  • Our data consists of two different types of
    markets--the international equity market and the
    U.S. domestic stock market, which we examine here
    in terms of summary return statistics and key
    profitability financial ratios. In addition, we
    also analyze 30 firms of the Dow Jones Index.
    Most details of the model, the methodologies, and
    the hypotheses for empirical tests are discussed
    in previous sections. We first examine
    international asset pricing by looking at summary
    statistics for our international country indices,
    and then we look at our data for the U.S.
    domestic stock market with portfolios formed from
    the SP 500 and also the 30 companies used to
    compile the Dow Jones Industrial Average.

24
V. DATA AND TESTING THE EXISTING OF PRICE
ADJUSTMENT PROCESS
  • 1. International Equity Markets Country Indices
  • The data come from two different sources. One is
    the Global Financial Data (GFD) from the
    databases of Rutgers Libraries, and the second
    set of dataset is the MSCI (Morgan Stanley
    Capital International, Inc.) equity indices.
    Mainly we focus on the Global Financial Data,
    with the MSCI indices used for some comparisons.
    We use both datasets to perform the
    Granger-causality test. The monthly (GFD) dataset
    for February 1988 to March 2004 consists of the
    index, dividend yield, price earnings ratio, and
    capitalization for each equity market. Sixteen
    country indices and two world indices are used to
    do the empirical study, as listed in Table 1. For
    all country indices, dividends and earnings are
    converted into U.S. dollar denominations. The
    exchange rate data also comes from Global
    Financial Data.
  • In Table 2, Panel A shows the first four moments
    of monthly returns and the Jarque-Berra
    statistics for testing normality for the two
    world indices and the seven indices of
    G7countries, and Panel B provides the same
    summary information for the indices of nine
    emerging markets. As can be seen in the mean and
    standard deviation of the monthly returns, the
    emerging markets tend to be more volatile than
    developed markets though they may yield
    opportunity of higher return. The average of
    monthly variance of return in emerging markets is
    0.166, while the average of monthly variance of
    return in developed countries is 0.042.

25
V. DATA AND TESTING THE EXISTING OF PRICE
ADJUSTMENT PROCESS
  • 2. United States Equity Markets
  • Three hundred companies are selected from the SP
    500 and grouped into ten portfolios by their
    payout ratios, with equal numbers of thirty
    companies in each portfolio. The data are
    obtained from the COMTUSTAT North America
    industrial quarterly data. The data starts from
    the first quarter of 1981 to the last quarter of
    2002. The companies selected satisfy the
    following two criteria. First, the company
    appears on the SP500 at some time period during
    1981 through 2002. Second, the company must have
    complete data available--including price,
    dividend, earnings per share and shares
    outstanding--during the 88 quarters (22 years).
    Firms are eliminated from the sample list if
    either .their reported earnings are either
    trivial or negative or their reported dividends
    are trivial.
  • Three hundred fourteen firms remain after these
    adjustments. Finally excluding those seven
    companies with highest and lowest average payout
    ratio, the remaining 300 firms are grouped into
    ten portfolios by the payout ratio. Each
    portfolio contains 30 companies. Figure 1 shows
    the comparison of SP 500 index and the
    value-weighted index (M) of the 300 firms
    selected. Figure 1 shows that the trend is
    similar to each other before the 3rd quarter of
    1999. However, the two follow noticeable
    different paths after the 3rd quarter of 1999.

26
V. DATA AND TESTING THE EXISTING OF PRICE
ADJUSTMENT PROCESS
  • To group these 300 firms, the payout ratio for
    each firm in each year is determined by dividing
    the sum of four quarters dividends by the sum of
    four quarters earnings then, the yearly ratios
    are further averaged over the 22-year period. The
    first 30 firms with highest payout ratio
    comprises portfolio one, and so on. Then, the
    value-weighted average of the price, dividend,
    and earnings of each portfolio are also computed.
    Characteristics and summary statistics of these
    10 portfolios are presented in Table 3 and Table
    4, respectively. Table 3 presents information of
    the return, payout ratio, size, and beta for the
    10 portfolios. There appears to exist some
    inverse relationship between mean return and
    payout ratio. However, the relationship between
    payout ratio and beta is not so clear. This
    finding is similar to that of Fama and French
    (1992).
  • Table 4 shows the first four moments of quarterly
    returns of the market portfolio and 10
    portfolios. The coefficients of skewness,
    kurtosis, and Jarque-Berra statistics show that
    one can not reject the hypothesis that log return
    of most portfolios is normal. The kurtosis
    statistics for most sample portfolios are close
    to three, which indicates that heavy tails is not
    an issue. Additionally, Jarque-Berra coefficients
    illustrate that the hypotheses of Gaussian
    distribution for most portfolios are not
    rejected. It seems to be unnecessary to consider
    the problem of heteroskedasticity in estimating
    domestic stock market if the quarterly data are
    used.
  • Finally, we use quarterly data of thirty
    Dow-Jones companies to test the existence of
    disequilibrium adjustment process for asset
    pricing. The sample period of this set of data
    is from first quarter of 1981 to fourth quarter
    of 2002.

27
V. DATA AND TESTING THE EXISTING OF PRICE
ADJUSTMENT PROCESS
  • B. Testing the Existence of the Price Adjustment
    Process
  • Another way to evaluate the demand and supply
    schedules derived in Section II is to reexamine
    these equations, considering the possibilities of
    market in disequilibrium. In fact, one can see
    the disequilibrium model as a special case of
    simultaneous equation models. In this section, a
    similar demand and supply schedule will be
    derived individually but solved simultaneously to
    reexamine the price adjustment behavior by
    assuming that market is in disequilibrium. Recall
    that the disequilibrium model derived in Section
    III can be represented as

28
V. DATA AND TESTING THE EXISTING OF PRICE
ADJUSTMENT PROCESS
  • (17)
  • QDt1 cS-1 EtPt1 - cS-1(1 r)Pt cS-1EtDt1
    µ1t,
  • (18) QSt1 QSt A-1B Pt - A-1Et Dt1 µ2t,
  • (19) Qt1 min (QDt1, QSt1 ),
  • (20) ?Pt ?(QDt1 - QSt1 ).

29
V. DATA AND TESTING THE EXISTING OF PRICE
ADJUSTMENT PROCESS
  • In the above system, one need to estimate the
    coefficients of EtPt1, Pt and EtDt1 in demand
    schedule (i.e., a1 and ß1), the coefficients of
    QSt, Pt and EtDt1 in the supply schedule (a2,
    and ß2) and the coefficient of excess demand, ?,
    with the observations on EtPt1, Pt, EtDt1 and
    QSt for t 1, 2, , T. µt and ?t are disturbance
    terms and assumed to be jointly normal and
    independent over time with distributions N(0,
    s2µ) and N(0, s2?), respectively. It is clear
    that some terms in equation (17) and (18) are
    different from the basic disequilibrium equation
    system proposed. Some assumptions or adjustments
    are imposed in empirical studies. Please refer to
    Appendix A1 for details. The quantity
    observation, Qt, for each index comes from the
    capitalization data. Since the capitalization for
    each index is denominated in U.S. dollars, we
    first divide the capitalization by its own
    countrys index and then adjust by the currency
    rate with U.S. dollar.
  • The maximum likelihood estimators are computed
    from the derivation in Section IV. First, use the
    2SLS approach to find the initial values for the
    estimates, and then the maximum likelihood
    estimate is obtained from the calculation of the
    log likelihood function described as equation
    (27).

30
V. DATA AND TESTING THE EXISTING OF PRICE
ADJUSTMENT PROCESS
  • The results of sixteen country indexes are
    summarized in Table 5. Fifteen out of sixteen,
    the maximum likelihood estimates of ? are
    significant different from zero at the 1
    significance level.9 The results in terms of 10
    portfolios are summarized in Table 6. There are
    six portfolios, including market portfolio, with
    a maximum likelihood estimates of ? statistically
    significantly different from zero. For example,
    for portfolios 1, 2, 4, and 7, ? is significantly
    different from zero at the 1 significance level.
    Portfolio 5 and the market portfolio are
    significance level of 5 , and portfolio 10 is
    significant at a 10 level. We cannot reject the
    null hypothesis that ? equals to zero for three
    portfolios -- 3, 6, 8, and 9. The results imply
    some but less than complete price adjustment
    during each quarter in the U.S. stock markets.
  • Table 7 shows the results of thirty companies
    listed in the Dow Jones Index. The price
    adjustment factor is significantly different from
    zero at the 5 level in twenty-two companies out
    of twenty-eight companies. On average, an
    individual company has a higher estimated value
    of ? than the individual portfolio and individual
    portfolio has a higher value than market
    portfolio. For example, IBMs ? is 0.0308, which
    indicates that an excess demand of 32.47 million
    shares is required to cause a change in the price
    of 1 dollar, whereas 476 million shares is
    required to cause one unit price change for
    market portfolio since its ? is only 0.0021.10
  • We use four datasets (two international indexes
    and two US equity) to test the existence of the
    disequilibrium adjustment process in terms of the
    disequilibrium model defined in equations 13
    through16. We find that there exists a
    disequilibrium adjustment process for
    international indexes, ten portfolios from SP
    500, and thirty companies of Dow Jones index.
    These results imply that asset pricing with
    disequilibrium price adjustment maybe important
    for investigating asset pricing in security
    analysis and portfolio management.

31
VI. SUMMARY
  • In this paper, we first theoretically review
    and extend Blacks CAPM to allow for a price
    adjustment process. Next, we derive the
    disequilibrium model for asset pricing in terms
    of the disequilibrium model developed by Fair and
    Jaffe (1972), Amemiya (1974), Quandt (1988), and
    others. MLE and 2SLS are our two methods of
    estimating our asset pricing model with
    disequilibrium price adjustment effect. Using
    three data sets of price per share, dividend per
    share and volume data, we test the existence of
    price disequilibrium adjustment process with
    international index data, US equity data, and the
    thirty firms of the Dow Jones Index. We find
    that there exist disequilibrium price adjustment
    process. Our results support Lo and Wangs
    (2000) findings that trading volume is one of the
    important factors in determining capital asset
    pricing.

32
Table 1. World Indices and Country Indices List
  • I. World Indices

II. Country Indices
33
Table 1. (Cont.)
  • II. Country Indices

34
Table 2 Summary Statistics of Monthly Return1, 2
  • Panel A G7 and World Indices

35
Table 2 Summary Statistics of Monthly Return1, 2
  • Panel B Emerging Markets

Notes 1 The monthly returns from Feb. 1988 to
March 2004 for international markets. 2 and
denote statistical significance at the 5 and
1, respectively.
36
Table 3 Characteristics of Ten Portfolios
Notes 1The first 30 firms with highest payout
ratio comprises portfolio one, and so on. 2The
price, dividend and earnings of each portfolio
are computed by value-weighted of the 30 firms
included in the same category. 3The payout ratio
for each firm in each year is found by dividing
the sum of four quarters dividends by the sum of
four quarters earnings, then, the yearly ratios
are then computed from the quarterly data over
the 22-year period.
37
Table 4. Summary Statistics of Portfolio
Quarterly Returns1
Notes 1Quarterly returns from 1981Q1to 2002Q4
are calculated. 2 and denote
statistical significance at the 5 and 1 level,
respectively.
38
Table 5. Price Adjustment Factor, ?, for 16
International Indexes 1, 2
  • Notes
  • 1 Sample periods used are other than 19882 to
    20043
  • 2 Null hypothesis if there is no price
    adjustment mechanism in response to an excess
    demand, the value of ? will be equal to zero.
    (H0 ? 0).
  • 3 , and denote statistical
    significance at the 10, 5, and 1 level,
    respectively.

39
Table 6. Price Adjustment Factor, ?, for 10
Portfolios from SP 500 1
  • Notes 1 Null hypothesis if there is no price
    adjustment mechanism in response to an excess
    demand, the value of ? will be equal to zero.
    (H0 ? 0).
  • 2 , and denote statistical
    significance at the 10, 5, and 1 level,
    respectively.

40
Table 7. Price Adjustment Factor, ? , Dow Jones
30 1, 2
41
Table 7. (Cont.)
  • Notes 1 Null hypothesis if there is no price
    adjustment mechanism in response to an excess
    demand, the value of ? will be equal to zero.
    (H0 ? 0).
  • 2 Microsoft and Intel are not in the list
    since their dividends paid are trivial during the
    period analyzed here.
  • 3 , and denote statistical
    significance at the 10, 5 and 1 level,
    respectively.

42
Figure 1Comparison of SP500 and Market portfolio
43
APPENDIX A ESTIMATING DISEQUILIBRIUM ADJUSTMENT
PARAMETER, G
  • A.1 The Disequilibrium Equation System
  • A.2 How to Solve MLE Estimates in the
    Disequilibrium Model
  • A.3 Estimation of the Disequilibrium Model

44
APPENDIX A ESTIMATING DISEQUILIBRIUM ADJUSTMENT
PARAMETER, G
  • In this appendix we will describe the procedure
    for estimating the disequilibrium adjustment
    parameter, ?. First we define the equation
    system, then we will discuss how to solve MLE
    estimate of the disequilibrium model. Finally,
    the procedure of Estimating the disequilibrium
    model is discussed in detail.
  • A.1 The Disequilibrium Equation System
  • The last topic of this section is to
    incorporate the demand and supply schedules
    developed in the previous section into this
    disequilibrium equation system. The demand and
    supply schedule in equations (9) and (12) can be
    restated as

45
APPENDIX A ESTIMATING DISEQUILIBRIUM ADJUSTMENT
PARAMETER, G
  • (17)
  • QDt1 cS-1 EtPt1 - cS-1(1 r)Pt
    cS-1EtDt1 µ1t
  • (18) QSt1 QSt A-1B Pt - A-1Et Dt1 µ2t
  • (19) Qt1 min (QDt1, QSt1 )
  • (20) ?Pt ?(QDt1 - QSt1 ).

46
APPENDIX A ESTIMATING DISEQUILIBRIUM ADJUSTMENT
PARAMETER, G
  • From the above equation system, it is clear that
    some conditions in equation (17) and (18) are
    different from the basic disequilibrium equation
    system (e.g., QSt in the supply schedule and the
    expectation term of price in the demand
    function). These problems will be dealt with,
    before the empirical studies, by imposing some
    more assumptions or by using alternative
    specification in econometric methodologies in the
    next section.
  • Since the purpose of this study is to understand
    the price adjustment in response to an excess
    demand therefore, all expectation terms in the
    above equations are replaced by the actual or
    real observations. In addition, the original
    model derives the supply schedule based on the
    assumption that there exist quadratic costs to
    retire or issue securities (i.e., there is a
    quadratic cost on ?QSt). In this study, the cost
    is assumed to be restricted to a deviation from
    the previous observation of the quantities
    issued. We also assume that the expectation of
    the adjustment in dividend can be forecasted and
    computed from the adaptive expectation model by
    utilizing the past dividend and earnings
    information. As a result, the disequilibrium
    equation system can be restated as followings

47
APPENDIX A ESTIMATING DISEQUILIBRIUM ADJUSTMENT
PARAMETER, G
  • (A.1.1) QDt a1 Pt-1a2Pt a3Dt u1t
  • (A.1.2) QSt Qt-1 ß1Pt-1 ß2 Dt u2t
  • (A.1.3) Qt min (QDt, QSt )
  • (A.1.4) ?Pt Pt -Pt-1 ?(QDt - QSt ).

48
APPENDIX A ESTIMATING DISEQUILIBRIUM ADJUSTMENT
PARAMETER, G
  • A.2 How to Solve MLE Estimates in the
    Disequilibrium Model
  • In order to estimate the disequilibrium model
    described as equation (A.1.1) to (A.1.4) in
    section A.1, we follow the method presented
    Amemiya (1974) and Quandt (1988).
  • Recall that the disequilibrium equation system
    shown as equation (13) to (16) can be
    reformulated and summarized as equation (25a) and
    (25b). That is,
  • (A.2.1a)
  • (A.2.1b)
  • where

49
APPENDIX A ESTIMATING DISEQUILIBRIUM ADJUSTMENT
PARAMETER, G
  • Xi,t are vectors of predetermined variables
    including the lagging price Pt-1. Qt is the
    observed quantity, and ?Pt Pt-1 - Pt-1.
  • If one assumes u1t and u2t are serially and
    contemporaneously independent with distributions
    and N0, su12 and N0, su22, and since in
    period A when QDt QSt, the conditional density
    of ?Pt given Qt is N?(Qt -ßX2t ), ?2su22, and
    in period B when QDt density of ?Pt given Qt is N?(aX1t -Qt),
    ?2su12, Amemiya (1974) shows that the log
    likelihood function can be solved as
  • (A.2.2)

50
APPENDIX A ESTIMATING DISEQUILIBRIUM ADJUSTMENT
PARAMETER, G
  • Amemiya (1974) suggests that the maximum
    likelihood estimator can be obtained by
    simultaneously solving the following equations
  • (A.2.3)
  • (A.2.4)
  • (A.2.5)

51
APPENDIX A ESTIMATING DISEQUILIBRIUM ADJUSTMENT
PARAMETER, G
  • (A.2.6)
  • (A.2.7)
  • That is, one can substitute the
    two-stage least squares (2SLS) estimates of a, ß,
    su12and su22 into (A.2.7) and solve for ?
    (choosing a positive root), then use the estimate
    of ? thus obtained to find new 2SLS estimates of
    a, ß, in (A.2.1a) and (A.2.1b), and find new
    estimates of su12 and su22 in (A.2.5) and
    (A.2.6). One can repeat this process until the
    solution converge.

52
APPENDIX A ESTIMATING DISEQUILIBRIUM ADJUSTMENT
PARAMETER, G
  • That is, the parameters can be solved by using
    the following iterative procedure
  • Step 1 Use 2LSL estimates of a, ß, s2µ and s2?
    as the initial estimates.
  • Step 2 Substitute,,andinto (A.2.7) and solve for
    the positive root of ?,.
  • Step 3 Use in (25) to obtain 2SLS estimates of
    a, ß, su12 and su22.
  • Step 4 Repeat step 2 and 3 until the solutions
    converge.
  • Quandt (1988) suggests an alternative way to
    derive the log-likelihood function. The
    disequilibrium equation system in equations
    (A.2.1a) and (A.2.1b) is intrinsically the same
    as the Model C in Chapter 2 suggested by Quandt
    (1988), though there are some different notions
    for the coefficients. After modifying the
    different notions, Quandts log-likelihood
    function is as followings

53
APPENDIX A ESTIMATING DISEQUILIBRIUM ADJUSTMENT
PARAMETER, G
  • (A.2.8)
  • where
  • In Quandts specification, is
    assumed to be i.i.d. with N(0, S). In other
    words, this is the same as what we assume u1t and
    u2t are serially and contemporaneously
    independent with distributions and N0, su12
    and N0, su22.

54
APPENDIX A ESTIMATING DISEQUILIBRIUM ADJUSTMENT
PARAMETER, G
  • A.3 Estimation of the Disequilibrium Model
  • From section A.2, the disequilibrium equation
    system of (A.1.1) to (A.1.4) discussed in section
    A.1 can be reformulated as
  • (A.3.1a)
  • (A.3.1b)
  • where

55
APPENDIX A ESTIMATING DISEQUILIBRIUM ADJUSTMENT
PARAMETER, G
  • And, from equation (A.2.8), we can derive the
    log-likelihood function for this empirical study.
    That is, we need to estimate the following
    equations simultaneously.
  • (A.3.2)
  • (A.3.3)
  • (A.3.4)

56
APPENDIX A ESTIMATING DISEQUILIBRIUM ADJUSTMENT
PARAMETER, G
  • The procedures and the related code in
    Eviews-package are as followings. For step 2, w
    use the Marquardt procedure implemented in the
    Eviews-package to find out the ML estimates of a,
    ß, s2µ and s2? in equations (A.3.2) to (A.3.4).
    The order of evaluation is set to evaluate the
    specification by observation. The tolerance level
    of convergence, tol, is set as 1e-5.
  • Step 1 Use 2LSL estimates of a, ß, s2µ and s2?
    in equation (A.3.1) as the initial estimates.
  • Step 2 Substitute , , and into
    equation (A.3.2) to (A.3.4) and solve for the
    MLE of , , , and
    simultaneously.

57
APPENDIX A ESTIMATING DISEQUILIBRIUM ADJUSTMENT
PARAMETER, G
  • Code
  • 'Aassume zero correlation between demand and
    supply error
  • Define delta(p) and delta(p)- in (A.3.1)
  • series dp_pos (d(p1)0)d(p1)
  • series dp_neg (d(p1)
  • Estimate 2SLS for Equation (A.3.1a) and (A.3.1b)
  • Equation (A.3.1a)
  • equation eqa.tsls q p(-1) dv p dp_pos _at_ p(-1)
    p(-2) dv(-1) dv(-2)
  • alpha eqa._at_coefs
  • sigma(1) eqa._at_se
  • show eqa.output
  • Equation (A.3.1b)
  • equation eqb.tsls q p(-1) dv q(-1) dp_neg _at_ p(-2)
    dv(-1) q(-2) dv(-2)
  • beta eqb._at_coefs
  • sigma(2) eqb._at_se
  • show eqb.output
  • mu(2) -1/eqb.c(4)

58
APPENDIX A ESTIMATING DISEQUILIBRIUM ADJUSTMENT
PARAMETER, G
  • 'Setup log likelihood as in (A.3.2) to (A.3.4)
  • logl ll1
  • ll1.append _at_logl logl1
  • Equation (A.3.3)
  • ll1.append u1 q-alpha(1)p(-1)-alpha(2)dv-alpha
    (3)pdp_pos/gamma(1)
  • Equation (A.3.4)
  • ll1.append u2 q-beta(1)p(-1)-beta(2)dv
    -q(-1)dp_neg/gamma(1)
  • Equation (A.3.2)
  • ll1.append logl1 -log(2!pi) -log(_at_abs(beta(1)-a
    lpha(1)1/(gamma(1))))
  • - log(sigma(1)) -log(sigma(2))
  • - u12/sigma(1)2/2 u22/sigma(2)2/2
  • 'Do MLE
  • ll1.ml(showopts, m1000, c1e-5)

59
ENDNOTES
  • 1 This dynamic asset pricing model is different
    from Mertons (1973) intertemporal asset pricing
    model in two key aspects. First, Blacks model is
    derived in the form of simultaneous equations.
    Second, Blacks model is derived in terms of
    price change, and Mertons model is derived in
    terms of rates of return.
  • 2 It should be noted that Lo and Wangs model
    does not explicitly introduce the supply equation
    in asset pricing determination. Also, one can
    identify the hedging portfolio using volume data
    in the Lo and Wang model setting.
  • 3 The basic assumptions are 1) a single period
    moving horizon for all investors 2) no
    transactions costs or taxes on individuals 3)
    the existence of a risk-free asset with rate of
    return, r 4) evaluation of the uncertain
    returns from investments in term of expected
    return and variance of end of period wealth and
    5) unlimited short sales or borrowing of the
    risk-free asset.

60
ENDNOTES
  • 4 Theories as to why taxes and penalties affect
    capital structure are first proposed by
    Modigliani and Miller (1958) and then Miller
    (1977). Another market imperfection, prohibition
    on short sales of securities, can generate
    shadow risk premiums, and thus, provide further
    incentives for firms to reduce the cost of
    capital by diversifying their securities.
  • 5 There are four major models and some
    alternative specifications in constructing
    disequilibrium issues (see Quandt (1988), though
    the time period notation is slightly different
    from the models here).
  • 6 While there is a slight difference in the
    notation of time period, the essence of model is
    still remained.
  • 7 Amemiya show that the 2SLS estimators proposed
    by Fair and Jaffee are not consistent since the
    expected value of error in first equation, Eµt
    given t belonging to period B, is not zero, or,
    according to Quandt, the plim Xa µa/T is not
    zero (see Amemiya (1974) and Quandt (1988)).

61
ENDNOTES
  • 8 Quandt (1988) points out that the alternative
    way to derive likelihood function proposed by
    Amemiya can be obtained by, first, finding the
    joint density of Pt and Qt from equations (23)
    and (24), denoted by f1(Qt, Pt) and f2(Qt, Pt)
    respectively, and then, summing up the
    log-likelihood function for two different
    periods. One can have the appropriate
    log-likelihood function as following, which is,
    in fact, the same as (27).
  • 9 The procedure of estimating disequilibrium
    adjustment parameter, is presented in the
    Appendix A.
  • 10 According to equation (27), ?Pt ? (QDt1 -
    QSt1 ), the amount of excess demand needed to
    cause a dollar change in price can be calculated
    by 1/0.0308.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com