Title: Managerial Economics
1Managerial Economics
- Lecture Ten
- Standard theory of finance
2Recap
- Minskys Financial Instability Hypothesis
- Finance-driven cyclical behavior
3Modern Finance?
- Modern Finance Theory has many components
- Sharpes Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)
- Modigliani-Millers Dividend Irrelevance
Theorem - Markowitzs risk-averse portfolio optimisation
model - Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT)
- Modern as compared to pre-1950 theories that
emphasised behaviour of investors as explanation
of stock prices, value investing, etc. - Initially appeared to explain what old finance
could not - But 50 years on
- Foundation is Sharpes CAPM
4The Capital Assets Pricing Model
- How to predict the behaviour of capital
markets? - Extend theories of investment under certainty...
- to investment under conditions of risk
- Based on neoclassical utility theory
- Investor maximises utility subject to constraints
- Utility
- Positive function of expected return ER
- Negative function of risk (standard deviation) sR
- Constraints are available spectrum of investment
opportunities
5The Capital Assets Pricing Model
Investment opportunities
Z inferior to C (lower ER) and B (higher sR)
Indifference curves
Border (AFBDCX) is Investment Opportunity Curve
(IOC)
6The Capital Assets Pricing Model
- IOC reflects correlation of separate investments.
Consider 3 investments A, B, C - A contains investment A only
- Expected return is ERa,
- Risk is sRa
- B contains investment B only
- Expected return is ERb,
- Risk is sRb
- C some combination of a of A (1-a) of B
- ERcaERa (1-a)ERb
7The Capital Assets Pricing Model
- If rab1, C lies on straight line between A B
8The Capital Assets Pricing Model
- If rab1, C lies on straight line between A B
9The Capital Assets Pricing Model
- If rab1, C lies on straight line between A B
10The Capital Assets Pricing Model
11The Capital Assets Pricing Model
- If rab0, C lies on curved path between A B
This is zero
Hence this is zero
12The Capital Assets Pricing Model
- If rab0, C lies on curved path between A B
13The Capital Assets Pricing Model
- If rab0, C lies on curved path between A B
Straight line relation
Hence lower risk for diversified portfolio (if
assets not perfectly correlated)
14The Capital Assets Pricing Model
15The Capital Assets Pricing Model
- Sharpe assumes riskless asset P with ERPpure
interest rate, sRP0. - Investor can form portfolio of P with any other
combination of assets - One asset combination will initially dominate all
others
16The Capital Assets Pricing Model
Efficiency maximise expected return minimise
risk given constraints
17The Capital Assets Pricing Model
- Assume limitless borrowing/lending at riskless
interest rate return on asset P - Investor can move to anywhere along PfZ line by
borrowing/lending - Problem
- P the same for all investors (simplifying
assumption) - But investor perceptions of expected return,
risk, investment correlation will differ - Solution
- assume homogeneity of investor expectations
- utterly unrealistic assumption, as is assumption
of limitless borrowing by all borrowers at
riskless interest rate. So...
18The Capital Assets Pricing Model
- Defended by appeal to Friedmans
Instrumentalism - the proper test of a theory is not the realism
of its assumptions but the acceptability of its
implications - Consequence of assumptions
- spectrum of available investments/IOC identical
for all investors - P same for all investors
- PfZ line same for all investors
- Investors distribute along line by
borrowing/lending according to own risk
preferences
19The Capital Assets Pricing Model
20The Capital Assets Pricing Model
- Next, the (perfect) market mechanism
- Price of assets in f will rise
- Price of assets not in f will fall
- Price changes shift expected returns
- Causes new pattern of efficient investments
aligned with PfZ line
21The Capital Assets Pricing Model
Range of efficient assetcombinations after
market price adjustments more than just one
efficient portfolio
22The Capital Assets Pricing Model
- Theory so far applies to combinations of assets
- Individual assets normally lie above capital
market line (no diversification) - Cant relate between ERi si
- Can relate ERi to systematic risk
- Investment i can be part of efficient combination
g - Can invest (additional) a in i and (1-a) in g
- a1 means invest solely in i
- a0 means some investment in i (since part of
portfolio g) - Some alt0 means no investment in i
- Only a0 is efficient
23The Capital Assets Pricing Model
24The Capital Assets Pricing Model
- Slope of IOC and igg curve at tangency can be
used to derive relation for expected return of
single asset
- This allows correlation of variation in ERi to
variation in ERg (undiversifiable, or systematic,
or trade cycle risk) - Remaining variation is due to risk inherent in i
25The Capital Assets Pricing Model
26The Capital Assets Pricing Model
- Efficient portfolio enables investor to minimise
asset specific risk - Systematic risk (risk inherent in efficient
portfolio) cant be diversified against - Hence market prices adjust to degree of
responsiveness of investments to trade cycle - Assets which are unaffected by changes in
economic activity will return the pure interest
rate those which move with economic activity
will promise appropriately higher expected rates
of return. OREF II
27The Capital Assets Pricing Model
- Crux/basis of model markets efficiently value
investments on basis of expected returns/risk
tradeoff - Modigliani-Miller extend model to argue valuation
of firms independent of debt structure (see OREF
II) - Combination the efficient markets hypothesis
- Focus on portfolio allocation across investments
at a point in time, rather than trend of value
over time - Argues investors focus on fundamentals
- Expected return
- Risk
- So long as assumptions are defensible
28The Capital Assets Pricing Model
- In order to derive conditions for equilibrium in
the capital market we invoke two assumptions.
First, we assume a common pure rate of interest,
with all investors able to borrow or lend funds
on equal terms. Second, we assume homogeneity of
investor expectations investors are assumed to
agree on the prospects of various investmentsthe
expected values, standard deviations and
correlation coefficients described in Part II.
Needless to say, these are highly restrictive and
undoubtedly unrealistic assumptions. - However, since the proper test of a theory is not
the realism of its assumptions but the
acceptability of its implications, and since
these assumptions imply equilibrium conditions
which form a major part of classical financial
doctrine, it is far from clear that this
formulation should be rejectedespecially in view
of the dearth of alternative models leading to
similar results. - Sharpe later admits to qualms
29The CAPM Reservations
- People often hold passionately to beliefs that
are far from universal. The seller of a share of
IBM stock may be convinced that it is worth
considerably less than the sales price. The buyer
may be convinced that it is worth considerably
more. (Sharpe 1970) - However, if we try to be more realistic
- The consequence of accommodating such aspects of
reality are likely to be disastrous in terms of
the usefulness of the resulting theory... The
capital market line no longer exists. Instead,
there is a capital market curvelinear over some
ranges, perhaps, but becoming flatter as risk
increases over other ranges. Moreover, there is
no single optimal combination of risky
securities the preferred combination depends
upon the investors preferences... The demise of
the capital market line is followed immediately
by that of the security market line. The theory
is in a shambles. (Sharpe 1970 emphasis added)
30The CAPM Evidence
- Sharpes qualms ignored CAPM takes over
economic theory of finance - Initial evidence seemed to favour CAPM
- Essential ideas
- Price of shares accurately reflects future
earnings - With some error/volatility
- Shares with higher returns more strongly
correlated to economic cycle - Higher return necessarily paired with higher
volatility - Investors simply chose risk/return trade-off that
suited their preferences - Initial research found expected (positive)
relation between return and degree of volatility - But were these results a fluke?
31The CAPM Evidence
- Volatile but superficially exponential trend
- As it should be if economy growing smoothly
But looking more closely...
32The CAPM Evidence
- Sharpes CAPM paper published 1964
- Initial CAPM empirical research on period
1950-1960s - Period of financial tranquility by Minskys
theory - Low debt to equity ratios, low levels of
speculation - But rising as memory of Depression recedes
- Steady growth, high employment, low inflation
- Dow Jones advance steadily from 1949-1965
- July 19 1949 DJIA cracks 175
- Feb 9 1966 DJIA sits on verge of 1000 (995.15)
- 467 increase over 17 years
- Continued for 2 years after Sharpes paper
- Then period of near stagnant stock prices
33The CAPM Evidence
- Dow Jones treads water from 1965-1982
- Jan 27 1965 Dow Jones cracks 900 for 1st time
- Jan 27 1972 DJIA still below 900! (close 899.83)
- Seven years for zero appreciation in nominal
terms - Falling stock values in real terms
- Nov. 17 1972 DJIA cracks 1000 for 1st time
- Then all hell breaks loose
- Index peaks at 1052 in Jan. 73
- falls 45 in 23 months to low of 578 in Dec. 74
- Another 7 years of stagnation
- And then liftoff
34The CAPM Evidence
21 years ahead of trend...
- Fit shows average exponential growth 1915-1999
- index well above or below except for 1955-1973
Crash of 73 45 fall in 23 months
Sharpes paper published
Jan 11 73 Peaks at 1052
Dec 12 1974 bottoms at 578
Bubble takes off in 82
CAPM fit doesnt look so hot any more
Steady above trend growth 1949-1966 Minskys
financial tranquility
CAPM fit to this data looks pretty good!
35An aside what caused 73 crash?
- Many blame OPEC Oil Embargo for economic downturn
- October 17, 1973 OPEC bans export of oil to
countries that supported Israel in 1973
Arab-Israeli War - Oil price rises 4-fold from US2.50 to 10 a
barrel - BUT embargo occurred 9 months after market peak
- Quarterly GDP growth fell from 10.1 in Q1 1973
to -1.6 in Q3 73 before embargo - Market already down 8 by October 17 to 963
- Rose in immediate aftermath to embargo
- Real acceleration of crash occurred with Franklin
National Bank of New York crisis from May-October
1974 - May 1 854 Dec 12 578 32 fall in 7 months
- Minskys financial fragility more important
- OPEC-inspired inflation may have made crisis less
severe reduction of real debt burden
36The CAPM Evidence
- By mid-1990s, clear CAPM and reality werent
related - The Dow ... stood at around 3,600 in early 1994.
- By 1999, it had passed 11,000, more than tripling
in five years... - However, over the same period, basic economic
indicators did not come close to tripling. - U.S. gross domestic product rose less than 30,
and almost half of this increase was due to
inflation. - Corporate profits rose less than 60, and that
from a temporary recession-depressed base. - Viewed in the light of these figures, the stock
price increase appears unwarranted and, certainly
by historical standards, unlikely to persist
(Schiller 4)
37The CAPM Evidence
- Schillers inflation adjusted SP PE ratio
- Very cyclical
- Notice peak in 1966 Minskys nominated date for
transition from robust to fragile financial
system - 2000 valuations highest in history
- Not rational calculation of CAPM but
irrational exuberance
38The CAPM Evidence
- Price far more volatile than earnings
- Volatility should be similar if CAPM true
- Growth in earnings slow steady compared to
highly volatile prices
39The CAPM Evidence
- CAPM predicts no cyclical behavior to prices
(apart from that caused by earnings) you cant
time the market
- Schiller finds clear cyclicality when PE ratio
high, next ten year stock market returns low
vice versa - 1990-2000 valuation off the chart!
- Negative returns for next decade highly likely
40The CAPM Evidence
- The relation between price-earnings ratios and
subsequent returns appears to be moderately
strong... - longterm investors who can commit their money to
an investment for ten full years do well when
prices were low relative to earnings at the
beginning of the ten years and do poorly when
prices were high at the beginning of the ten
years. - Long-term investors would be well advised,
individually, to stay mostly out of the market
when it is high, as it is today, and get into the
market when it is low. (12) - Critics of CAPM thus dismiss itbut even its
one-time champions do too - Fama French
41The CAPM Evidence According to Fama 1969
- Evidence supports the CAPM
- This paper reviews the theoretical and empirical
literature on the efficient markets model We
shall conclude that, with but a few exceptions,
the efficient markets model stands up well.
(383) - Assumptions unrealistic but that doesnt matter
- the results of tests based on this assumption
depend to some extent on its validity as well as
on the efficiency of the market. But some such
assumption is the unavoidable price one must pay
to give the theory of efficient markets empirical
content. (384)
42The CAPM Evidence According to Fama 1969
- CAPM good guide to market behaviour
- For the purposes of most investors the efficient
markets model seems a good first (and second)
approximation to reality. (416) - Results conclusive
- In short, the evidence in support of the
efficient markets model is extensive, and
(somewhat uniquely in economics) contradictory
evidence is sparse. (416) - Just one anomaly admitted to
- Large movements one day often followed by large
movements the nextvolatility clustering
43The CAPM Evidence According to Fama 1969
- one departure from the pure independence
assumption of the random walk model has been
noted large daily price changes tend to be
followed by large daily changes. The signs of the
successor changes are apparently random, however,
which indicates that the phenomenon represents a
denial of the random walk model but not of the
market efficiency hypothesis But since the
evidence indicates that the price changes on days
follow ing the initial large change are random in
sign, the initial large change at least
represents an unbiased adjustment to the ultimate
price effects of the information, and this is
sufficient for the expected return efficient
markets model. (396) - 35 years later, picture somewhat different
44The CAPM Evidence According to Fama 2004
- The attraction of the CAPM is that it offers
powerful and intuitively pleasing predictions
about how to measure risk and the relation
between expected return and risk. - Unfortunately, the empirical record of the model
is poorpoor enough to invalidate the way it is
used in applications. - The CAPM's empirical problems may reflect
theoretical failings, the result of many
simplifying assumptions - In the end, we argue that whether the model's
problems reflect weaknesses in the theory or in
its empirical implementation, the failure of the
CAPM in empirical tests implies that most
applications of the model are invalid. (Fama
French 2004 25)
45The CAPM Evidence According to FF 2004
- Clearly admits assumptions dangerously
unrealistic - The first assumption is complete agreement given
market clearing asset prices at t-1, investors
agree on the joint distribution of asset returns
from t-1 to t. And this distribution is the true
onethat is, it is the distribution from which
the returns we use to test the model are drawn.
The second assumption is that there is borrowing
and lending at a risk free rate, which is the
same for all investors and does not depend on the
amount borrowed or lent. (26) - Bold emphasis model assumes all investors
effectively know the future - Assumptions, which once didnt matter (see
Sharpe earlier) are now crucial
46The CAPM Evidence According to FF 2004
- The assumption that short selling is
unrestricted is as unrealistic as unrestricted
risk-free borrowing and lending But when there
is no short selling of risky assets and no
risk-free asset, the algebra of portfolio
efficiency says that portfolios made up of
efficient portfolios are not typically efficient.
This means that the market portfolio, which is a
portfolio of the efficient portfolios chosen by
investors, is not typically efficient. And the
CAPM relation between expected return and market
beta is lost. (32) - Still some hope that, despite lack of realism,
data might save the model
47The CAPM Evidence According to FF 2004
- The efficiency of the market portfolio is based
on many unrealistic assumptions, including
complete agreement and either unrestricted
risk-free borrowing and lending or unrestricted
short selling of risky assets. But all
interesting models involve unrealistic
simplifications, which is why they must be tested
against data. (32) - Unfortunately, no such luck
- 40 years of data strongly contradict all versions
of CAPM - Returns not related to betas
- Other variables (book to market ratios etc.)
matter - Linear regressions on data differ strongly from
risk free rate (intercept) beta (slope)
calculations from CAPM
48The CAPM Evidence According to FF 2004
- Tests of the CAPM are based on three
implications - First, expected returns on all assets are
linearly related to their betas, and no other
variable has marginal explanatory power. - Second, the beta premium is positive, meaning
that the expected return on the market portfolio
exceeds the expected return on assets whose
returns are uncorrelated with the market return. - Third, assets uncorrelated with the market have
expected returns equal to the risk-free interest
rate, and the beta premium is the expected market
return minus the risk-free rate. (32)
49The CAPM Evidence According to FF 2004
- There is a positive relation between beta and
average return, but it is too "flat." the
Sharpe-Lintner model predicts that - the intercept is the risk free rate and
- the coefficient on beta is the expected market
return in excess of the risk-free rate, E(RM) -
R. - The regressions consistently find that the
intercept is greater than the average risk-free
rate, and the coefficient on beta is less than
the average excess market return (32)
50The CAPM Evidence According to FF 2004
- Average Annualized Monthly Return versus Beta for
Value Weight Portfolios Formed on Prior Beta,
1928-2003
- the predicted return on the portfolio with the
lowest beta is 8.3 percent per year the actual
return is 11.1 percent. The predicted return on
the portfolio with the highest beta is 16.8
percent per year the actual is 13.7 percent.
(33)
51The CAPM Evidence According to FF 2004
- The hypothesis that market betas completely
explain expected returns - Starting in the late 1970s evidence mounts that
much of the variation in expected return is
unrelated to market beta (34) - Fama and French (1992) update and synthesize the
evidence on the empirical failures of the CAPM
they confirm that size, earnings-price, debt
equity and book-to-market ratios add to the
explanation of expected stock returns provided by
market beta. (36) - Best example of failure of CAPM as guide to
building investment portfolios Book to Market
(B/M) ratios provide far better guide than Beta
52The CAPM Evidence According to FF 2004
- Average returns on the B/M portfolios increase
almost monotonically, from 10.1 percent per year
for the lowest B/M group to an impressive 16.7
percent for the highest. - But the positive relation between beta and
average return predicted by the CAPM is notably
absent the portfolio with the lowest
book-to-market ratio has the highest beta but the
lowest average return. - The estimated beta for the portfolio with the
highest book-tomarket ratio and the highest
average return is only 0.98. With an average
annualized value of the riskfree interest rate,
Rf, of 5.8 percent and an average annualized
market premium, Rm - Rf, of 11.3 percent, the
Sharpe-Lintner CAPM predicts an average return of
11.8 percent for the lowest B/M portfolio and
11.2 percent for the highest, far from the
observed values, 10.1 and 16.7 percent.
53The CAPM Evidence According to FF 2004
- Average Annualized Monthly Return versus Beta for
Value Weight Portfolios Formed on B/M, 1963-2003
- Simple regression of data gives opposite
relationship to CAPM return rises as beta falls!
54Beta is dead, long live?
- CAPM clearly a failure
- As predictor of stock market behaviour
- As guide to formation of return-maximising,
risk-minimising portfolio - Early success possibly due to unusual
financial tranquility nature of post-WWII to
1966 stock market - New model of finance needed
- To explain behaviour of asset markets in general
- To guide portfolio selection
- Next week the developing Really New Finance
- The Inefficient Market Hypothesis
- The Fractal Market Hypothesis
- Chaos, heterogeneity and minority games