Title: GPEM 200506: Financial Crises Bubbles IV: South Sea
1GPEM 2005-06 Financial CrisesBubbles IV South
Sea
2Outline
- Context and background
- Why look at a distant historical event in such
detail? - Where did the South Sea bubble come from?
- Why did it happen in 1720?
- Temin-Voth rational speculators and predictable
sentiment - Dale et al. irrationality
- Shea contract details
3The bubble in long-run perspective
4Mississippi bubble very similar
5Common problem government deficits
6Historical background
- South sea company founded in 1711
- Purpose to trade with Spanish America (Treaty of
Utrecht 1713) - Finance government debt
- Trade never amounts to much (a number of slave
ships etc.) in 1718, ships and assets seized by
Spain - 1719 successful exchange of lottery tickets from
1710 (government debt) for company shares - Lower interest rate debt becomes more liquid
- Financed by new share issue profit for company
- Higher market value of debt for creditors
- 1720 offer to exchange most of remaining
government debt - Total remaining debt approx. 50 million pounds
- 18.3 held by Bank of England, East India Company,
and South Sea Company - 16.5 redeemable, privately held debt
- 15 irredeemable long 72-87 years maturity,
short 22 years
7Historical background - 2
- Debt exchange agreed with Treasury December 1719
- Government will pay 5 until 1727 and 4
thereafter - Bank of England starts to bid for contract,
January-February 1720 - Initial offer South Sea Company 3 million pounds
for the debt conversion privilege - Final offer 7.5 million
- Parliament (and the Court) bribed February-March
1720 - Total expense probably around 1.3 million pounds
- Shares "sold" to politicians, mistresses of the
King, ministers with no cash changing hands,
often below market price similar to granting a
free option to them - Equity raised in four subscriptions,
April-September 1720 - Total amount the company can raise 20 million
- Payments not made in full between 1/10 and ¼
paid initially - Conversion rate not set
- Higher market price means higher "profit" (equity
capital left for other purposes) - _at_135, 20 million in government debt can be
acquired for 14.8 million in stock (face value),
leaving 5.2 million for other purposes - Massive lending against own stock (restricting
free float)
8Some difficulties in determining underlying value
- Flying Post from April 9th, 1720
- with the share price of South Sea stock at 300,
its intrinsic value would be 448 - at 600, it would be worth 880
- the higher the price, the more cheaply
bondholders could be bought out, and the higher
the value of shares - Garber (2000) "the episode is readily
understandable as a case of speculators working
on the basis of the best economic analysis
available and pushing prices along by their
changing view of market fundamentals."
9Trading conditions
- The offices of the South Sea Company very soon
found it impossible to keep abreast of the
transfers of stock reported to them on the three
days a week appointed for settlements. This
sheer physical inability to register changes of
ownership in the stock naturally encouraged
credit trading and speculative forward sales,
particularly when, as happened from time to time,
the transfer office had to close in order to
catch up with the existing arrears, and bargains
could only be made for the opening of the
books. - John Carswell, The South Sea Bubble
10VALUE OF THE SOUTH SEA COMPANY, AUGUST 1720
164
in millions of pounds
87.9
at 4
at 8
20
11The financial situation of the South Sea Company,
end of August 1720
- Market value of South Sea shares 164 million
- Claims
- 1.9 million to 1727
- 1.5 million thereafter
- at 4 ? 40 million
- at 8 ? 20 million
- Cash receivable from investors
- 70 million from subscribers
- 11 million in lending against stock
- Liabilities
- 7.1 million for the conversion privilege
- 6 million in debt
- Net - 56.1 million to - 74.1 million
- at 4 -- 2.25 million in additional profit p.a.
required to close gap - at 8 -- 4.5 million
12A bubble?
- Guaranteed payments worth 13-24 of market
capitalization in September 1720 - 50 of "assets" were simply claims on equity
owners, with low probability of being paid up
(especially when prices turned down) - Required profit to close valuation gap very large
no other corporation in English history had
made profits on such a scale, not even for a
single year, let alone continuously - Ponzi scheme element
- South Sea Company pays dividend out of equity
just raised from subscription - lends against stock from fresh equity
- Underlying profitability minimal
- Not even Garber claims that the valuations in the
summer of 1720 can be rationalized by
expectations of future dividends expected price
increases of the asset itself must have been key
13Three competing hypotheses and observable
implications
- Actions driven by irrational impulses
- gt Does as well as someone buying and selling
randomly throughout the year - Investment decisions severely constrained by
trading/settlement microstructure, short-sale
constraints, etc. - gt Sells off its holdings as soon as
overvaluation becomes substantial, but does not
go short for most of the bubble - Behavior best explained by predictable investor
sentiment riding the bubble, despite knowledge
that overvaluation is massive - gt Continues to hold stock throughout the bubble
episode, selling periodically possibly missing
the optimum time to sell
14Data and the early history of Hoares
- Hoare's a private bank on Fleet Street, steps
from the LSE - Moved to its current location in 1690 origins as
a goldsmith in the 16th century "at the sign of
the golden bottle" Cromwell's daughter banked
with Hoare's banking business since 1672 started
by Sir Richard Hoare - Archive used by permission of the current
managing partner, Henry Hoare - Two main sources
- Account ledgers
- Balance sheets
15The sign of the golden bottle and Sir Richard
Hoare
16Evidence A goldsmith bank in the South Sea bubble
- We look at positions held by one goldsmith bank,
Hoare's - Initially a goldsmith, with a sideline in
pawnbroking - Turns to lending from the 1690s
- Total size of balance sheet in 1720 262,000
pounds peak valuation of South Sea company
164,000,000 pounds - Maximum position March 1720, 1.1 of South Sea
shares average for the year 0.4 average
trade 0.09 of shares outstanding Hoare's is a
substantial investor, but by no means big enough
to dominate the market - Why a goldsmith bank?
- Amongst the most sophisticated investors in the
early modern English market - Owners have high-powered incentives unlimited
liability partnership, deposit-taking
incentives similar to hedge funds today - Data availability trading records are rare, even
today unusually lucky find - If anyone managed to go short, it was goldsmith
banks and other brokers - Not a small group in 1700, as many as 42 banks
in total 13 "West End" bankers in 1725 - Goldsmith banks as close to the ideal of
rational speculators as one can expect during
the the eighteenth century
17(No Transcript)
18The Technology Bubble
NASDAQ Combined Composite Index
- Ofek-Richardson (2001WP) Valuation of Internet
stocks implied - Average expected earnings growth of about 3,000
in ten years, assuming that they already achieved
old economy profit margins - Zero percent cost of capital for ten years
- How unique was the tech bubble?
- How unique were the conditions that contributed
to the bubble's birth and growth?
Chart (Jan. 98 - Dec. 00)
38 day average
19Comparing the South Sea bubble and the dotcom
mania
20Outline Preview
- Theoretical Context and Related Literature
- Historical Background and Data
- Empirical Results
- Hoare's maintained a significant positive
exposure during most of the bubble episode
skillfully anticipated the downturn, by selling
out near the market peak - Timing not quite perfect sells too early in the
year, and then too late (comparison with hedge
funds during the tech bubble shows similar
behavior) - Significant outperformance of buy-and-hold, and
momentum strategies - Cross-sectional evidence Outperformance most
impressive in the most speculative assets - Information from customers, insider trading
probably not key - Strong, indirect evidence that Hoare's believed
the market to be overvalued - Conclusions
21Trading activity at Hoare's in 1720
22South Sea stock price and Hoare's trading
23Hoare's holdings and South Sea prices
24Returns following Hoare's trading
25Returns following Hoare's trading
26Hoare's daily return vs. the return on South Sea
stock
Buy and hold
27Jensen's alpha Hoare's and momentum strategy
- While the value of South Sea stock is
increasing beta is 0.94 for unleveraged
portfolio, 1.67 for leveraged - While returns are negative beta is 0.57
unleveraged, 0.87 leveraged - Outperformance from Jensen's alpha implies
annualized return of 54 to 222
28Profit/Loss, from 6 months prior to market peak
to 6 months after
29- Figure 6 Performance of a copycat fund that
replicates hedge fund holdings in the NASDAQ high
P/S segment - From Brunnermeier and Nagel 2003
30Hoare's timing not perfect, but similar to hedge
funds during the tech bubble
31Hoare's trading in other shares
- Bubble in progress in other shares, too
- If predictable investor sentiment is crucial,
then the most overvalued/"hot" shares should show
most of it greatest opportunity for Hoare's - This is what we find trading success is greatest
in the most speculative assets - Hoare's earns 200 over 2 months in shares of the
Royal African Company - Ram's Insurance (one of the "bubbles"), 43 in 17
days - Bank of England 51 annualized
- East India Company partly negative returns
- Similarity with hedge fund results Brunnermeier
and Nagel only find outperformance for shares
with very high P/S ratios
32What determined success?
- Anecdotal evidence few connections between South
Sea Company and Hoare's - None of the "insiders" listed in the literature
directly connected with Hoare's - No politicians of the time deal through Hoare's
- Lord Carlton buys 6,000 shares immediately before
Parliament debates the conversion Hoare's buys
9,000 shares during the two weeks before and
after, but timing is off - Quantitative tests
- How well did Hoare's do during periods when its
customers traded? - How much of Hoare's trading can be predicted from
trading of its customers?
33Predicting Hoare's trading behavior Poisson
regressions
34Customer "flow" was not key to Hoare's trading
performance
35Detecting Overvaluation
I verily believe that there is no real
foundation for the present, much less for the
further expected, high price of South-Sea stock
and that the frenzy which now reigns can be of no
long continuance in so cool a climate It seems
to be the universal opinion within and without
doors of Parliament that the present price of
South Sea Stock is much too high. -- Hutcheson,
Collection of Calculations and Remarks Relating
to the South Sea Scheme, March 1720
36Greater fools
This comes to good Mr. Warner, to lett him know
that I am allmost sure, I can mack an advantage
by bying in the South Seas with the hundred and
four score pounds is still in your hands so I
would bye as much as theat will bye today, and
sell it out agane next week, for tho I have no
oppinion of the South Sea to contineue in it I am
almost certine thus to mack sum litell advantage
to her that is good Mr. Warners reaell friend
-- Dutchess of Rutland, letter to her broker,
March 1720
37Hoare's lending against South Sea stock
- Similar evidence from interest rates on brokers'
loans - January 5 per annum
- April 10 per month
- From May 1 per day
- September 5 per month
- (from Hutcheson)
38Eventual collapse
- From September 1720, growing pressure on share
price Company lends frantically against shares - Bubble Act enforced by Company supporters
- Sword Blade company collapses
- "coordinating event" that allows rational
speculators to attack simultaneously
synchronization risk goes to zero - Most stock held on margin "Greenspan put"
equivalent through renegotiation of payments
payment to treasury cancelled, shares
redistributed
39Conclusions
- The South Sea bubble a useful historical episode
to isolate the behavioral/market microstructure
aspects that contribute to overvaluation episodes - Only tentative conclusions possible based on the
behavior of one investor - Hoare's apparently thought South Sea stock was
overpriced -- warnings about overvaluation
available for a long time Hoare's limits amount
of lending against stock during the run-up in
prices, suggesting that it doesn't expect the
bubble to last - Nonetheless, the bank did not attack the bubble,
but maintained (or increased) its positions
during the run-up of prices. Nonetheless did
spectacularly well much better than hedge funds
in 1998-2001.
40Conclusions - 2
- In this case, market microstructure and delegated
portfolio management were not responsible for the
bubble inflating. - Rational bubbles story very unlikely lending
against stock speaks against this interpretation - Balance of probabilities suggests that insider
trading was not key, and that Hoare's could to
some extend anticipate investor sentiment - Cannot distinguish conclusively if return
predictability was driven by insider knowledge,
second-guessing of noise traders, or of
sophisticated investors
41Dale et al.
- The premise Markets can go mad
- The argument
- Violations of no-arbitrage condition (idea
similar to 3Com-Palm) - Why would options systematically trade at prices
different from those of shares (adjusted)? - Background how to invest in the south seas
- Pricing equations
- Some observations, Garber style
42(No Transcript)
43(No Transcript)
44(No Transcript)
45(No Transcript)
46Whats wrong with the Dale et al. argument?
- Contrast with 3Com
- Clear market microstructure limitation there
- Mispricing disappears
- It is not impossible to explain (Cochrane)
- Doesnt pass the smell test
47(No Transcript)