Title: Economic Dynamics
1Economic Dynamics
- And the necessity of nonlinearity
2Definitions
- Economic Dynamics
- the study of any economic process
- Huh?
- Its easier to define by considering what you
have already studied - Economic Statics
- the study of the determination of points of
economic equilibrium - no consideration of the time path taken to get
there - Nonlinearity
- Realism in functional representation of a system
- First step towards evolutionary modelling
3The static-dynamics difference
- Consider standard micro supply and demand. We
have a linear demand curve and a linear supply
curve
- The static approach equate the two
4The static-dynamics difference
- State (timeless) supply and demand formulae
Notethisformula
- Break for lunch
- Problem agricultural markets not this stable
5The static-dynamics difference
- Classic example is Minnesota Hog Cycle
- Not equilibrium but irregular cycles around
long-term trend price
6The static-dynamics difference
- Attempted dynamic explanation cobweb model
- Recast supply and demand as time-lagged (actually
time-delayed) functions - Demand now reflects prices now
- Supply now reflects prices last season
- Farmers plant based on last years returns
- Adaptive expectations
- Basic formulae
Producers expect next seasons price to be same
as last seasons or
- Yields difference equation for prices
Producers plant this seasons crop based on last
seasons price
- Gives same equilibrium result as static formula
7The static-dynamics difference
Notethisformula
- So eventual outcome same as statics?
- Statics is long-run dynamics?
- Depends on values of parameters
8The static-dynamics difference
- If slope parameters bs/bdlt1, dynamicsstatics
- But for bs/bdgt1, dynamic instability
9The static-dynamics difference
- No convergence to equilibrium price
- Crazy prices negative, tending to /- infinity
- Randomness no help
- System tends to impossible prices
10The static-dynamics difference
- In cobweb model, dynamic answer diverges from
static answer if suppliers are more responsive to
price than consumers. (Which group do you think
is more responsive?) - Mad result of negative prices is result of
mad assumption of linear functions (which allow
negative supply, and negative demand!). - Effect disappears with sensible nonlinear
functions - Why sensible?
- Because linearity an abstraction
- Nothing in the real world is really linear
- Not even neoclassical economics
11The static-dynamics difference
- Markets (and models of markets) cannot be linear
- Crazy results (negative prices quantities)
product of linear form for demand supply curves - Given Dtad-bdPt, feed in high Pt, youll get
negative Dt - But even neoclassical theory doesnt justify
linear demand supply curves - Non-satiation implies D?? as P?0
- Ditto supply stops at 0, reaches finite maximum
as marginal cost?? - Nonlinear, time-delayed models give realistic
cyclesno need to hypothesise rational
expectations to tame the cobweb
12The static-dynamics difference
- Compare linear to nonlinear
- Simple nonlinear demand/supply curves
- Modified rectangular hyperbolas
- Basic hyperbola y1/x
- Area under hyperbola crucial to definition of
log, exponential - Used for illustration purposes only here
Generalised hyperbola formula is
- Used to derive S D curves
13The static-dynamics difference
- More realistic even in terms of neoclassical
theory than standard linear curves used - Linear obsession mainly due to lazy pedagogy
- But had real impact on development of theory
14The static-dynamics difference
- Solving for P as a function of time with these
curves
- Generates sustained cycles
- More interesting deterministic dynamics
possible with more complex functions - Chaos can arise
- Impact of noise instructive
15The static-dynamics difference
- Any pattern at all can result, without breakdown
16The static-dynamics difference
- Looks like empirical data too, even though
model incredibly simple
- Apparent volatility clustering
- Very difficult to get from linear models
- Simple with nonlinear modelproduct of being far
from equilibrium
- So statics is not long run dynamics
- Dynamics can answer questions statics cant even
pose
17Why the economic obsession with statics?
- Neoclassical economists tend to think
- Evolution leads to optimising behaviour
- Dynamics explains movement from one equilibrium
point to another - So statics is long run dynamics
- also believed by Sraffian economists
- implicit in Post Keynesian or Marxian analysis
using comparative static or simultaneous equation
methods
Statics
Dynamics
Evolution
18Why the economic obsession with statics?
- Modern mathematics reverses this
- Field of evolution larger than dynamics
- Dynamics larger than statics
- Results of evolutionary analysis more general
than dynamics - But two generally consistent
- Results of dynamics more general than statics
- GENERALLY INCONSISTENT
- Dynamic results correct if actual system
dynamic/evolutionary
Evolution
Dynamics
Statics
- In general, statics will give wrong answers to
questions posed about economywhether questions
posed in neoclassical or Post Keynesian terms
19General Disequilibrium
- There exist known systems, therefore, in which
the important and interesting features of the
system are essentially dynamic, in the sense
that they are not just small perturbations around
some equilibrium state, perturbations which can
be understood by starting from a study of the
equilibrium state and tacking on the dynamics as
an afterthought. - If it should be true that a competitive market
system is of this kind, then No progress can
then be made by continuing along the road that
economists have been following for 200 years. The
study of economic equilibrium is then little more
than a waste of time and effort Blatt (1983
5-6)
20In summary
- Summarising validity of analytic techniques
relations between them
21Why did economics start with statics?
- Because it was easier!
- Marshall (of Micro fame)
- The modern mathematician is familiar with the
notion that dynamics includes statics. If he can
solve a problem dynamically, he seldom cares to
solve it statically also... But the statical
solution has claims of its own. It is simpler
than the dynamical it may afford useful
preparation and training for the more difficult
dynamical solution and it may be the first step
towards a provisional and partial solution in
problems so complex that a complete dynamical
solution is beyond our attainment. (Marshall,
1907 in Groenewegen 1996 432)
22Why did economics start with statics?
- Jevons (one of the founders of General
Equilibrium analysis) - If we wished to have a complete solution we
should have to treat it as a problem of dynamics.
But it would surely be absurd to attempt the more
difficult question when the more easy one is yet
so imperfectly within our power. Jevons,
Theory of Political Economy, Ch. 4, 4th edition,
p. 93 - So statics regarded as easier way to reach the
same answers as the more general dynamics would
give. - Now known to be incorrect outside economics, but
still not common knowledge within economics
23Why study dynamics?
- Many real world processes
- do not have an equilibrium
- or do not have a single equilibrium
- or do not have stable equilibria
- globally,
- or locally
- Examples
- weather patterns animal population
growth/decline
24Why study dynamics?
- In these systems, equilibrium values will never
apply. - Equilibrium (and therefore static analysis)
irrelevant to system in both short and long term - system will not be at equilibrium now
- it is not moving towards equilibrium over time
- Economics?
- When did you last see an economy at rest?
- Question is whether the economy is stable subject
to shocks, or unstable - Two examples of linear vs nonlinear thinking
- Hickss trade cycle model
- Kaldors nonlinear explanation for cycle
- But first, the data
25The pre-1933 Trade cycle
- Pre-1933 trade cycle predates Big Government
- Cycles and growth performance therefore closer to
pure market economy results than data for
post-1933 - Source NBER Macrohistorical database,
http//www.nber.org/databases/macrohistory/data/01
/a01007a.db (Index of manufacturing production)
26Growth with cycles
27But what cycles!
28What causes these cycles?
- 2 classes of possible explanations
- Exogenous shocks to stable system
- economy stable, but disturbed by weather
patterns, wars, etc. - Endogenous fluctuations generated by dynamics of
the economy itself - can also have exogenous shocks imposed on this
class of systems, of course - First interpretation dominated early work in
economic dynamics
29Propagation and impulse
- If cycles caused by exogenous shocks then
- propagation mechanism
- that which keeps disturbance at time t rippling
through system till time tT, at which time
impact of disturbance completely dissipated - differs from impulse mechanism
- source of random shocks from outside the economy
- This interpretation dominated early work because
economists believed (wrongly) that endogenous
cycles were not possible
30The exogenous shocks interpretation
- Frisch in 1933 (depth of Great Depression)
- The majority of the economic oscillations which
we encounter seem to be explained most plausibly
as free oscillations. In many cases they seem to
be explained by the fact that certain exterior
impulses hit the economic system and thereby
initiate more or less regular oscillations
(Economic essays in honour of Gustav Cassel 171) - If you hit a rocking horse with a club, the
movement of the horse stable propagation
mechanism will be very different to that of the
club exogenous shocks (198)
31An example Hickss 2nd order model
- Investment a lagged function of change in income
- Consumption a lagged function of income
- Saving equals income minus consumption
- A 2nd order difference equation
322nd order difference equation
- Second order multiplier-accelerator model
dominates theory of cycles in economics
1950s-1960s - But properties of model show all drawbacks of
linear models - Unrealistic cycles
- Too muchor too littleinstability
- No goldilocks here
- Zero equilibrium output level
332nd order difference equation
- 5 basic patterns, none realistic
342nd order difference equation
- Adding noise doesnt help much
- The problem is linearity!
- But its also bad mathematics
352nd order difference equation
- Economists stuffed around with this model for
decades - A mathematician would have rejected it on day one
- Reason? Its only solution is the trivial
solution - YtYt-1Yt-20
- Takes elementary mathematical analysis to show
this - Convert model into matrix form
- If matrix non-invertible, model has meaningful
solutions - If non-invertible, only solution is
trivialzero.
36The trivial solution
- Special derived form of matrix can be inverted
- Means that only solution the trivial solution.
- Why is thiseconomically speaking?
37Hickss error
- Because model equates desired I and actual S
??????????
- When does desired investment equal actual
savings? - When income equals zero!
- Actual investment is related to this periods
output
or
38A better (but still linear!) model
- Desired investment a function of change in output
- Capitalists carry out investment plans
- Investment adds to capital
- Capital determines output
- 3rd order difference equation
- A more interesting (but still linear!) model.
- Behaviour can be broken down into equilibrium
trend cycle components
39A better (but still linear!) model
- Special derived form of matrix cant be inverted
- As a result, non-trivial solutions possible
- Non-zero values for Y over time
40Economic properties
- Cycles with growth
- Cv ratio determines nature of cycles growth
- Exponential with cgtv
- Linear with cv
- Damped with cltv
- Realistic period-independent values for c v
feasible
41Mathematical meaningful closed form
Equilibrium if c lt v
Growth term
Cycle term
42But the limitations of being linear
- Model itself a quirk
- Cycle size perfectly synchronised with growth of
output - Mathematically, eigenvalue for growth exactly
same magnitude as eigenvalue for cycles - Normally, these differ in linear models
- Cycles also symmetrical
- Trade cycle is notlong booms and short slumps
- Need nonlinearity to get asymmetry of real world
- First economist to realise the importance of
being nonlinear was Kaldor
43The endogenous critique
- Kaldor 1940, A model of the trade cycle
- Considered static model based on interaction of
ex-ante savings and ex-ante investment - the basic principle underlying all these
theories may be sought in the proposition
derived from Mr Keyness General Theory that
economic activity always tends towards a level
where Savings and Investment are equal in the
ex-ante sense. (78) - Savings and Investment both assumed to be
positively sloped functions of activity level
(employment as proxy). - If we assume the S and I functions as linear, we
have two possibilities (79)
44The endogenous critique
(1) Savings function steeper than
Investment (savings rises more than investment as
employment rises
SltI, system expands
SgtI, system contracts
Equilibrium stable
45The endogenous critique
SltI, system expands
(2) Savings function flatter than
Investment (savings rises less than investment as
employment rises
SgtI, system contracts
Equilibrium unstable
46The endogenous critique
- Kaldor
- In slope of Sgt slope of I situation
- any disturbances would be followed by the
re-establishment of a new equilibrium, with a
stable level of activity this assumes more
stability than the real world, in fact, appears
to possess. (80) - In IgtS situation
- the economic system would always be rushing
either towards a state of hyper-inflation or
towards total collapse Since recorded experience
does not bear out such dangerous instabilities,
this possibility can be dismissed (80)
47The endogenous critique
- Kaldors solution
- Since thus neither of these two assumptions can
be justified, we are left with the conclusion
that the I and S functions cannot both be
linear. (81) - Insight nonlinear functions make endogenous
fluctuations possible, and limit size to
meaningful levels - Endogenous fluctuations and nonlinearity are
inseparable elements of dynamic analysis.
48The importance of being nonlinear
Linear models can be
Cycles in linear system require
Frisch/Hicks/Econometrics approach
Harrods initial model
49The importance of being nonlinear
- Cycles can occur because system is
Not so different from linear model
Completely unlike linear model
50The importance of being nonlinear
- Advantages of linear systems
- Easily analysed (closed form solutions exist)
- Powerful analytic maths (linear algebra)
- Proof by theorem
- Stable linear dynamic systems behaviour a
function of parameter values of system only - Behaviour can be broken down into
- Equilibrium value
- Growth component
- Cyclical component
- Disadvantages of linear systems
- Unrealistic for most open systems
51The importance of being nonlinear
- Disadvantages of nonlinear systems
- Difficult to analyse (no closed form solutions)
- No analytic maths
- Many high level forms of maths needed to
characterise, but no analytic results possible - Proof by simulation rather than theorem
- Systems behaviour a function of both parameter
values and initial conditions - Path dependent behavior
- Behaviour cannot be broken down into growth and
cyclical components - Instead, magnitude of cycles a function of
deviation from equilibrium equilibria often
repellers rather than attractors
52The importance of being nonlinear
- Advantages of nonlinear systems
- Realistic for most open systems
- Most open systemsones subject to evolutionary
changeare far from equilibrium ones - Nonlinear dynamics approximate this
- Evolution with fixed parameters
- Tractable compared to true evolutionary modelling
53Statics vs. Dynamics
- Economics unique amongst mathematically-oriented
disciplines in reliance upon static methodology
(simultaneous equations rather than differential
equations) - Reliance on statics not limited to Neoclassicals
- Many Keynesian/Kaleckian theorists (including the
masters) use simultaneous equations - Sraffian economists criticise all other schools
using advanced equilibrium-oriented methodology - Why?
- Belief that economic system will settle down to
equilibrium in the long run - Dynamics simply describes transients
54Statics vs. Dynamics
- Long ago shown to be untrue even for general
equilibrium neoclassical models (Jorgenson
1960,61, 63 McManus 1963 Blatt 1983) - Linear component of input-output system with
growth must be unstable in either price or output
vector - Reliance on static methods a hangover from past
practice and faith - Dynamic answers to economic questions
fundamentally different to static ones - EVEN IF model Keynesian
- Example Steedmans critique of Kaleckian pricing
theory
55Steedman on Kalecki
- A (mathematical/methodological) critique of
Kaleckian microfoundations - A Kalecki after Sraffa?
- No consideration of macro (capitalists get what
they spend...) - Input-output analytic critique of markup pricing
theory and related theory of distribution
56A brute fact
- the costs of any industry are constituted by the
prices of industrial products and it would be ...
one-sided to say that prices are largely cost
determined without saying also that costs are
to a significant degree price determined - Justified attack on lack of analytic
consideration of input-output relations in
Kaleckian tradition... - Unjustified attack on Kaleckian analysis of the
process of price setting
57Steedmans Crucible
- A model of price setting which takes account of
input-output relations - Circulating capital only no overhead labour
- Equilibrium analysis, quantities taken as given,
which leaves prices only
58Equilibrium Prices
- Reworking this equation yields
- Price can be expressed as a function of markup,
but - Given input-output relations, price in industry j
will at least depend on all 1...n industries
which are basic - QED I prices in industry j cannot be set without
regard to conditions in other industries - (Followed by critiques of averages, vertical
integration, wages share, etc.)
59What about dynamics?
- Steedman considers a once-only exogenous change
(of du) in u. - Then from
Note this equation
60Their full effects
- QED II Price converges to a new equilibrium
vector where initial interdependence of (each)
price on many (at least basic industries) markups
is restored. Steedman concludes that - QED III static analysis does not ignore time.
To the contrary, that analysis allows enough time
for changes in prime costs, markups, etc., to
have their full effects. - Really?
- Like most economists, Steedman is apparently
unaware of basic methods of mathematical
dynamical analysis - Reworking his equation into a standard difference
equation
61Their full effects
- As autonomous difference equation
- This is solved by breaking into two components
- First, homogeneous
- Presume solution of the form
Substituting
62Solving difference equation
Dispense with
Collect terms in x
Factor
- Only possible for non-trivial x if
constant
- Presume solution of the form
63Solving difference equation
- Simple matrix manipulation
- Particular result same as Steedmans static
solution
- General result sum of homogeneous plus particular
solutions
- Static solution same as dynamic iff this?0 as t??
Skip eigenvalues
64Eigenvalues eigenvectors
- Eigen (German for characteristic) values tell
you how much a matrix is stretching space - If modulus of dominant eigenvalue of discrete
dynamic system lt 1, matrix shrinks space and?0
as t?? - If modulus of dominant eigenvalue of discrete
dynamic system gt 1, matrix expands space and??
as t??
How much does matrix stretch space?
in which direction?
Only possible for non-trivial v if
65Eigenvalues eigenvectors
- If the modulus of the dominant root of this
polynomial lt 1, then this dynamic system will ?0
as t?? and static price vector will be the final
price vector
- If gt 1, then this dynamic system will ?? as t??
and static price vector will be irrelevant - If 1, then system marginally unstable
66Steedmans stability
- Steedmans example system used
- modulus of maximum eigenvalue of
67Steedmans stability
- Convergence to equilibrium in Steedmans example
system
68Steedmans stability
- A different example system
- Which static analysis would rule out for obvious
reasons, but of which the modulus of maximum
eigenvalue of
The consequence?
69Steedmans stability
- With different input-output matrix, instability
- Permanent inflation away from the negative
equilibrium price vector
70Steedmans stability
- Continuous price inflation
- Negative equilibrium price vector irrelevant
since equilibrium unstable and prices will always
diverge from it. - Static analysis does not describe the full
effects of a dynamic system unless the dynamic
system is stable - In real-world systems, instability/marginal
instability rather than stability seems to be the
rule - Complex systems/evolutionary intepretation
evolution to the edge of chaos
71With more reality?
- Increased realistic complexity would introduce
add quantity, banks, effective demand, nonlinear
wage investment functions, etc., to prices
markups - Each additional element of reality brings
increased nonlinearity (even with no explicit
nonlinear functions) - Full system almost certainly has unstable
(multiple) equilibria, hence exhibits
far-from-equilibrium dynamic behaviour
72Conclusion
- Static equilibrium not the end-product of dynamic
processes - Dynamicsnot staticsthe true crucible of
economics - Not so much Kalecki after Sraffa as Sraffa
after Lorenz - Kaleckian price-setting process fully consistent
with dynamic input-output analysis but - Kaleckian results require nonlinear dynamic
input-output analysis for full expression - Kaleckian analysis insufficiently developed on
this front to date but on the other hand, - Sraffians unjustifiably reliant upon statics
- Time for some cross-pollination
73Conclusion
- Non-neoclassical economists almost have as much
to learn about dynamics as do neoclassicals - Most Post Keynesian/Marxian/Sraffian economists
still only learn maths from other economists - Dont learn basics of dynamic modelling
- Dont appreciate importance of nonlinearity
- Next lecture some examples of how to be
dynamically nonlinear
74References
- Blatt, J.M., (1983). Dynamic Economic Systems, ME
Sharpe, Armonk. - Jorgenson, D.W., (1960). 'A dual stability
theorem', Econometrica 28 892-899. - Jorgenson, D.W., (1961). 'Stability of a dynamic
input-output system', Review of Economic Studies,
 28 105-116. - Jorgenson, D.W., (1963). 'Stability of a dynamic
input-output system a reply', Review of Economic
Studies, 30 148-149. - McManus, M., (1963). 'Notes on Jorgensons
model', Review of Economic Studies, 30 141-147.