Early exercise and Monte Carlo obtaining tight bounds

1 / 24
About This Presentation
Title:

Early exercise and Monte Carlo obtaining tight bounds

Description:

University of Melbourne. www.markjoshi.com. Bermudan optionality. A Bermudan option is an option that be exercised on one of a fixed finite numbers of dates. ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:64
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 25
Provided by: MarkJ85

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Early exercise and Monte Carlo obtaining tight bounds


1
Early exercise and Monte Carlo obtaining tight
bounds
  • Mark Joshi
  • Centre for Actuarial Sciences
  • University of Melbourne
  • www.markjoshi.com

2
Bermudan optionality
  • A Bermudan option is an option that be exercised
    on one of a fixed finite numbers of dates.
  • Typically, arises as the right to break a
    contract.
  • Right to terminate an interest rate swap
  • Right to redeem note early
  • We will focus on equity options here for
    simplicity but same arguments hold in IRD land.

3
Why Monte Carlo?
  • Lattice methods are natural for early exercise
    problems, we work backwards so continuation value
    is always known.
  • Lattice methods work well for low-dimensional
    problems but badly for high-dimensional ones.
  • Path-dependence is natural for Monte Carlo
  • LIBOR market model difficult on lattices
  • Many lower bound methods now exist, e.g.
    Longstaff-Schwartz

4
Buyers price
  • Holder can choose when to exercise.
  • Can only use information that has already
    arrived.
  • Exercise therefore occurs at a stopping time.
  • If D is the derivative and N is numeraire, value
    is therefore
  • Expectation taken in martingale measure.

5
Justifying buyers price
  • Buyer chooses stopping time.
  • Once stopping time has been chosen the derivative
    is effectively an ordinary path-dependent
    derivative for the buyer.
  • In a complete market, the buyer can dynamically
    replicate this value.
  • Buyer will maximize this value.
  • Optimal strategy exercise when
  • continuation value lt exercise value

6
Sellers price
  • Seller cannot choose the exercise strategy.
  • The seller has to have enough cash on hand to
    cover the exercise value whenever the buyer
    exercises.
  • Buyers exercise could be random and would occur
    at the maximum with non-zero probability.
  • So seller must be able to hedge against a buyer
    exercising with maximal foresight.

7
Sellers price continued
  • Maximal foresight price
  • Clearly bigger than buyers price.
  • However, seller can hedge.

8
Hedging against maximal foresight
  • Suppose we hedge as if buyer using optimal
    stopping time strategy.
  • At each date, either our strategies agree and we
    are fine
  • Or
  • 1) buyer exercises and we dont
  • 2) buyer doesnt exercise and we do
  • In both of these cases we make money!

9
The optimal hedge
  • Buy one unit of the option to be hedged.
  • Use optimal exercise strategy.
  • If optimal strategy says exercise. Do so and
    buy one unit of option for remaining dates.
  • Pocket cash difference.
  • As our strategy is optimal at any point where
    strategy says do not exercise, our valuation of
    the option is above the exercise value.

10
Rogers/Haugh-Kogan method
  • Equality of buyers and sellers prices says
  • for correct hedge Pt with P0 equals zero.
  • If we choose wrong t, price is too low lower
    bound
  • If we choose wrong Pt , price is too high upper
    bound
  • Objective get them close together.

11
Approximating the perfect hedge
  • If we know the optimal exercise strategy, we know
    the perfect hedge.
  • In practice, we know neither.
  • Anderson-Broadie pick an exercise strategy and
    use product with this strategy as hedge, rolling
    over as necessary.
  • Main downside need to run sub-simulations to
    estimate value of hedge
  • Main upside tiny variance

12
Improving Anderson-Broadie
  • Our upper bound is
  • The maximum could occur at a point where D0,
    which makes no financial sense.
  • Redefine D to equal minus infinity at any point
    out of the money. (except at final time horizon.)
  • Buyers price not affected, but upper bound will
    be lower.
  • Added bonus fewer points to run sub-simulations
    at.

13
Provable sub-optimality
  • Suppose we have a Bermudan put option in a
    Black-Scholes model.
  • European put option for each exercise date is
    analytically evaluable.
  • Gives quick lower bound on Bermudan price.
  • Would never exercise if value lt max European.
  • Redefine pay-off again to be minus infinity.
  • Similarly, for Bermudan swaption.

14
Breaking structures
  • Traditional to change the right to break into the
    right to enter into the opposite contract.
  • Asian tail note
  • Pays growth in FTSE plus principal after 3 years.
  • Growth is measured by taking monthly average in
    3rd year.
  • Principal guaranteed.
  • Investor can redeem at 0.98 of principal at end
    of years one and two.

15
Non-analytic break values
  • To apply Rogers/Haugh-Kogan/Anderson-Broadie/Longs
    taff-Schwartz, we need a derivative that pays a
    cash sum at time of exercise or at least yields
    an analytically evaluable contract.
  • Asian-tail note does not satisfy this.
  • Neither do many IRD contracts, e.g. callable CMS
    steepener.

16
Working with callability directly
  • We can work with the breakable contract directly.
  • Rather than thinking of a single cash-flow
    arriving at time of exercise, we think of
    cash-flows arriving until the contract is broken.
  • Equivalence of buyers and sellers prices still
    holds, with same argument.
  • Algorithm model independent and does not require
    analytic break values.

17
Upper bounds for callables
  • Fix a break strategy.
  • Price product with this strategy.
  • Run a Monte Carlo simulation.
  • Along each path accumulate discounted cash-flows
    of product and hedge.
  • At points where strategy says break. Break the
    hedge and Purchase hedge with one less break
    date, this will typically have a negative cost.
    And pocket cash.
  • Take the maximum of the difference of cash-flows.

18
Improving lower bounds
  • Most popular lower bounds method is currently
    Longstaff-Schwartz.
  • The idea is to regress continuation values along
    paths to get an approximation of the value of the
    unexercised derivative.
  • Various tweaks can be made.
  • Want to adapt to callable derivatives.

19
The Longstaff-Schwartz algorithm
  • Generate a set of model paths
  • Work backwards.
  • At final time, exercise strategy and value is
    clear.
  • At second final time, define continuation value
    to be the value on same path at final time.
  • Regress continuation value against a basis.
  • Use regressed value to decide exercise strategy.
  • Define value at second last time according to
    strategy
  • and value at following time.
  • Work backwards.

20
Improving Longstaff-Schwartz
  • We need an approximation to the unexercise value
    at points where we might exercise.
  • By restricting domain, approximation becomes
    easier.
  • Exclude points where exercise value is zero.
  • Exclude points where exercise value less than
    maximal European value if evaluable.
  • Use alternative regression methodology, eg loess

21
Longstaff-Schwartz for breakables
  • Consider the Asian tail again.
  • No simple exercise value.
  • Solution (Amin)
  • Redefine continuation value to be cash-flows that
    occur between now and the time of exercise in the
    future for each path.
  • Methodology is model-independent.
  • Combine with upper bounder to get two-sided
    bounds.

22
Example bounds for Asian tail

23
Difference in bounds
24
References
  • A. Amin, Multi-factor cross currency LIBOR market
    model implemntation, calibration and examples,
    preprint, available from http//www.geocities.com/
    anan2999/
  • L. Andersen, M. Broadie, A primal-dual simulation
    algorithm for pricing multidimensional American
    options, Management Science, 2004, Vol. 50, No.
    9, pp. 1222-1234.
  • P. Glasserman, Monte Carlo Methods in Financial
    Engineering, Springer Verlag, 2003.
  • M.Haugh, L. Kogan, Pricing American Options A
    Duality Approach, MIT Sloan Working Paper No.
    4340-01
  • M. Joshi, Monte Carlo bounds for callable
    products with non-analytic break costs, preprint
    2006
  • F. Longstaff, E. Schwartz, Valuing American
    options by simulation a least squares approach.
    Review of Financial Studies, 14113147, 1998.
  • R. Merton, Option pricing when underlying stock
    returns are discontinuous, J. Financial Economics
    3, 125144, 1976
  • L.C.G. Rogers Monte Carlo valuation of American
    options, Mathematical Finance,
  • Vol. 12, pp. 271-286, 2002
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)