Introduction to Valuation Bond Valuation - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

Introduction to Valuation Bond Valuation

Description:

Suppose Starbucks required everybody to play the following game in order to ... The coupon rate on this bond is 2%. The face value of this bond is $1000 ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:308
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 88
Provided by: aswathda
Learn more at: https://webpage.pace.edu
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Introduction to Valuation Bond Valuation


1
Introduction to ValuationBond Valuation
  • Financial Management
  • P.V. Viswanath
  • For a First course in Finance

2
Lesson Objectives
  • To look at the difference between economics and
    finance
  • To introduce the notion of future dollars as
    traded goods.
  • To introduce the price of future dollars
  • To relate the price of money to interest rates.
  • To use these rates to price Treasury securities
  • To introduce the notion of arbitrage

3
Absolute and Relative Pricing
  • In economics, we tend to price goods and assets
    by considering the factors affecting the supply
    and demand for them.
  • The number of goods and assets are very many.
    Each of them is different in some way or another
    from the other.
  • Computing the price of one good does not allow us
    to price another good, except to the extent that
    other goods are substitutes or complements for
    the first good.
  • In finance, the number of assets can be
    reasonably characterized in terms of a smaller
    number of basic characteristics.
  • Hence most assets can, to a first approximation
    be priced by considering them as combinations of
    more fundamental assets.

4
The Fundamentals of Economics
  • One of the issues that economics analyzes is the
    determination of prices of goods.
  • For example, what determines the price of eggs?
  • We have a supply curve that is, a schedule of
    quantities of eggs that their current possessors
    would be willing to sell and the prices at which
    they would be willing to sell them.
  • The higher the price, the more theyd be willing
    to sell.

5
The Supply Curve
Price ( per unit)
Quantity of Eggs
6
The Demand Curve
  • We can also imagine the different amounts of eggs
    that people would be willing to buy and the
    prices at which they would buy those quantities.
  • The lower the price, the more would be demanded.

7
The Demand Curve
Price ( per unit)
Quantity of Eggs
8
The Determination of the Price of Eggs
Price ( per unit)
Quantity of Eggs
9
Economics and Finance
  • Finance, like Economics, is interested in the
    prices of goods.
  • But the goods that financial analysts are
    interested in, are quite different.
  • As you might imagine, financial economists are
    interested in money (or purchasing power) and in
    the price of money.
  • But what does it mean to talk about the price of
    money? In what currency would you pay to acquire
    money?

10
Money and Time
  • The answer is that access to resources today is
    not the same as access to resources tomorrow
    that is, money available today is not the same as
    money available tomorrow.
  • You can buy something today only if you have the
    money to buy it with today. Having access to
    money, which will be available tomorrow wont
    allow you to necessarily buy things today!
  • This means that we can talk of different kinds of
    money.
  • And, denoting time by the subscript t, we can
    talk of the price of time 1 (tomorrow) money in
    terms of time 0 (today) money.

11
More on the price of money
  • Lets assume that all prices are denominated in
    t0 dollars (todays money).
  • Then, just as we might say that the price of a
    book is 10, the price of a subway token is 2
    and the price of a cup of Starbucks coffee is
    3.50, we could also say
  • The price of a t1 dollar is 0.90, the price of
    a t2 dollar is 0.7831 and the price of a t3
    dollar is 0.675.

12
The price of coffee, said differently
  • This might sound a little strange to you, but
    lets put it slightly differently.
  • Going back to a cup of coffee, we said its price
    was 3.50, but if we know that 3.50 1, we
    could equally well say that the price of a book
    is 1.
  • Then even if we were all in the US and Starbucks
    only accepted US dollars, there would be no
    problem if Starbucks had its price list
    denominated in euros.

13
More ways to price coffee
  • Lets take this further.
  • Suppose Starbucks required everybody to play the
    following game in order to figure out the price
    of its offering.
  • Suppose they took the actual dollar price of a
    coffee multiplied it by 2 and added 3 to it and
    called it java units (J).
  • A cup of coffee that normally cost 3.5 would be
    listed as costing 10J.
  • Then if we saw a cappuccino listed at 13J, we
    would simply subtract 3 to get 10, then divide by
    2 to get a price of 5.
  • It would be a little weird, but nothing
    substantive would change.

14
Rates
  • So now, lets go back to the price of money we
    said that the price of a t1 dollar was 0.90,
    and that the price of a t2 dollar was 0.7831.
  • Now clearly the price of a t1 dollar, which is
    0.90 today, will rise to 1 at t1.
  • Hence providing todays price of a t1 dollar is
    equivalent to providing the rate of change of the
    price over the coming period.
  • I have exactly the same information in each case.
  • This rate of change is also my rate of return
    over the next year if I buy a t1 dollar, today,
    and is also known as the interest rate.
  • In our example, this works out to (1-0.90)/0.90
    or 11.11

15
Rates
  • What about the price of a t2 dollar, which we
    said was 0.7831?
  • Once again, the price of this t2 dollar would be
    1 at t2 (in t2 dollars, of course).
  • We could compute the gross return on this
    investment, in the same way, as 1/0.7831 1.277
    or a return of 27.70.
  • But this is a return over two periods, and we
    cannot compare it directly to the 11.11 that we
    computed earlier.
  • The solution to this problem is to annualize the
    two-period return

16
Computing Annualized Rates
  • We computed the return on buying a t2 dollar at
    27.70.
  • Suppose the one-period return on this is r that
    is, the return from holding this t2 dollar from
    now until t1 is r. Then, every dollar invested
    in this specialized investment could be sold at
    (1r) at t1.
  • Now, if we assume the return on this t2 dollar
    if held from t1 to t2 is also r, then the
    (1r) value of our outlay of one t0 dollar in
    this investment would be (1r)(1r) or (1r)2.
  • But we already know from our return computation,
    that this is exactly 1.277 (that is 1 plus the
    27.7).
  • Hence we equate (1r)2 to 1.277 and solve for r.

17
Annualized Rates
  • This involves simply taking the square-root of
    1.277, which is 13.
  • Of course, we wont get exactly 13 in each of
    the two periods.
  • The 13 rate is, rather, a sort of average return
    over the two periods, that results in a 27.7
    over the two years.
  • We can now take 0.675, the price of a t3 dollar
    and also convert it to a rate of return.
  • In this case, we take the cube root of (1/0.675),
    which works out 14

18
Yield to maturity
  • So now we have the current prices of t1, t2,
    and t3 dollars, or 0.90, 0.7831 and 0.675
    respectively.
  • Alternatively, the information in these prices
    could also be presented as rates of return, which
    in our case are 11.11, 13 and 14 respectively.
  • These rates are also called yields-to-maturity.
  • Yields-to-maturity, in general, are the
    annualized total returns that you would get if
    you held a particular financial instrument to
    maturity.
  • In this case, the returns each year are only from
    price appreciation, while in other cases, there
    may be annual cash payments received by the
    investor, as well.

19
Using the rates
  • We have assumed, up to this point, that
    purchasing a t1 dollar is riskless. That is, the
    person who sold us the t1 dollar today, in
    return for the 0.90, would, in fact, pay us 1
    at time t1.
  • We will continue with this assumption, for now.
  • Note, as well that buying a t1 dollar is
    equivalent to lending money for one period, while
    selling a t1 dollar is equivalent to borrowing
    money for 1 period.
  • A bond is precisely a promise to pay its holder
    some combination of future dollars.
  • Corporations, governments and other entities who
    need funds for the continuing operations issue,
    that is sell, such bonds.

20
Treasury Bonds
  • Consider now a bond issued by the Treasury
    Department, which essentially acts as banker for
    the Federal Government.
  • These bonds, or promises to pay are considered
    default-free, i.e. we fully expect the Treasury
    to live up to its promises.
  • We can, therefore, evaluate and price these
    Treasury or T-bonds using the risk-free yields
    that we established before.
  • This need not be true of other governmental
    institutions, such as municipalities, such as the
    City of New York or Federal agencies such as PATH
    the Port Authority of New York and New Jersey.

21
Treasury Bonds
  • On Feb. 29th 2008, the Treasury issued a 2 note
    with a maturity date of February 28, 2010 with a
    face value of 1000, which was sold at auction.
  • The price paid by the lowest bidder was
    99.912254 of face value.
  • This means that the buyer of this bond would get
    every six months 1 (half of 2) of the face
    value, which in this case works out to 10.
  • In addition, on Feb. 28, 2010, the buyer would
    get 1000.

22
Terminology
  • The maturity of this bond is 2 years.
  • The coupon rate on this bond is 2
  • The face value of this bond is 1000
  • The price paid for this bond is 999.123
  • The yield-to-maturity obtained by this buyer is
    2.045, i.e. the average rate of return for this
    buyer if s/he held it to maturity.

23
Pricing this bond
  • Lets assume for now, that we do not know the
    price of this bond. How can we price this bond?
  • What we do know is that a holder of this bond
    would receive 10 in 6 months, another 10 in 1
    year, 10 again in 1.5 years and 1010 in 2
    years.
  • We also know that a 6-month T-bill issued on Feb.
    21, 2008 sold for 98.968667.
  • A T-bill is a promise to pay money 6 months in
    the future. With the given price then, a buyer
    would get a 1.042 return for those 6 months.
  • This is often annualized by multiplying by 2 to
    get a bond-equivalent yield of 2.084.
  • We also know that yields of bonds generally are
    higher for higher maturities.

24
Yield Curves for Feb. 1-12, 2008
Date 1mo 3mo 6mo 1yr 2yr 3yr 5yr 7yr 10yr 20yr 30yr
02/01/08 1.75 2.10 2.15 2.13 2.09 2.22 2.75 3.13 3.62 4.31 4.32
02/04/08 2.15 2.27 2.22 2.17 2.08 2.23 2.78 3.18 3.68 4.37 4.37
02/05/08 2.22 2.19 2.13 2.06 1.93 2.08 2.66 3.08 3.61 4.32 4.33
02/06/08 2.12 2.10 2.10 2.05 1.96 2.11 2.67 3.08 3.61 4.36 4.37
02/07/08 2.19 2.17 2.13 2.08 1.99 2.21 2.79 3.21 3.74 4.50 4.51
02/08/08 2.24 2.23 2.12 2.05 1.93 2.10 2.69 3.11 3.64 4.41 4.43
02/11/08 2.35 2.31 2.13 2.06 1.93 2.10 2.67 3.09 3.62 4.38 4.41
02/12/08 2.55 2.31 2.12 2.06 1.94 2.13 2.71 3.13 3.66 4.43 4.46
25
Yield Curves for Feb. 1-12, 2008
26
Pricing a Treasury bond
  • Suppose we believe that the current environment
    of uncertainty will continue.
  • We might believe that investors will be even more
    unwilling to invest in securities that have any
    default risk.
  • In that case, they will be willing to buy
    Treasury securities at lower yields.
  • We use this to estimate current bond-equivalent
    yields.
  • Suppose we estimate the current bond-equivalent
    yields for 6-month money, 1 year money, 18-month
    money and 2 year money as 2.07, 2.1, 2.11 and
    2.14.

27
Discounting
  • Keeping in mind that what we have are
    bond-equivalent yields, i.e. yields computed on a
    six-monthly basis and then doubling to get the
    annual yield, we will compute the current prices
    of future dollars.
  • To do this, we need to employ a procedure called
    discounting.
  • Suppose the required risk-free rate of return on
    future dollars is 4 per period.
  • Now, if I have a certain, default-free promise of
    200 in 3 periods, what is the value of this
    promise today?

28
Discounting
  • We know the value at t3 of this promise would be
    exactly 200.
  • The value at t2of the promise would have to be
    such that would yield a return of exactly 4 over
    the last period, i.e. from t2 to t4.
  • Suppose the required value is S. Then, we would
    need (200-S)/S 1.04.
  • Solving this equation, we find S 200/1.04.
  • What would the value at t1 be?
  • Applying the same principle, we see that it must
    be S/1.04 or 200/1.042.
  • Analogously, we can see that the value at t0 of
    a promise to pay 200 in n periods is 200/(1.04)n.

29
Pricing the 2-yr T-bond
  • Coming back to our T-bond, the annualized yield
    on 6-month money is 2.07 hence the six-month
    yield is 2.07/2 or 1.035.
  • Hence a promised dollar-payment at t 0.5 would
    sell today for 1/1.01035 or 0.989756 today.
  • The annualized yield on 1-year money is 2.1
    hence the six-month yield is 2.10/2 1.05.
  • Hence a promised dollar-payment at t1 would sell
    today for 1/1.01052 0.979326.

30
Pricing the 2-yr T-bond
  • The annualized yield on 1.5 year money is 2.11
    hence the six-month yield is 2.11/2 1.055.
  • Hence the price today of a promised
    dollar-payment at t1.5 is 1/1.010553 0.96901,
    using the discounting method.
  • The annualized bond-equivalent yield on 2-year
    money is 2.14.
  • The price today of a promised dollar-payment at
    t2 is 1/1.01074 0.95832

31
Pricing the 2-yr T-bond
  • So now we know that our bond pays 10 in 6
    months, another 10 in 1 year, 10 again in 1.5
    years and 1010 in 2 years.
  • We also know that one dollar promised for each of
    those dates is worth, today, 0.989756,
    0.979326, 0.96901 and 0.95832 respectively.
  • Our bond, therefore, must sell for 10(0.989756)
    10(0.979326) 10(0.96901) 1010(0.95832)
    997.28.

32
Arbitrage
  • What we have done is to treat our 2 year 2
    coupon bond as a portfolio of four other
    zero-coupon bonds and then priced it as the sum
    of the values of those zero-coupon bonds.
  • But what will guarantee that this price equality
    will hold?
  • Heres where the efficient functioning of markets
    comes into play.
  • A process called arbitrage ensures that the price
    of a combination of other financial securities
    does not deviate too much from the price implied
    the prices of those other securities.

33
Arbitrage
  • Suppose, for example that our two-year bond sold
    for 996.
  • Then a bond trader could buy a bond at this
    price, then, himself, issue the corresponding
    four zero-coupon bonds and sell them at their
    market prices.
  • He would then end up with a profit of 1.28 per
    bond.
  • If the bond sold for, say, 998, he could buy the
    zero-coupon bonds and then create a synthetic
    coupon bond and sell it at the higher price and
    make a profit of 998-997.28 or 72 cents per bond.

34
Relative pricing of financial assets
  • Consider first riskless financial assets, i.e,
    assets that are claims on riskless cashflows over
    time.
  • Consider a fundamental asset, i, defined by a
    claim to 1 at time t i.
  • There can be T such fundamental assets,
    corresponding to the t 1,..,T time units.
  • Then, any arbitrary riskless financial asset that
    is a claim to ci at time i, i 1,..,T can be
    considered a portfolio of these T fundamental
    assets.
  • Hence, the price, P of any such asset is related
    to the prices of these first T fundamental
    assets.
  • In fact, the price of this asset would simply be

35
Relative pricing of risky financial assets
  • What about risky financial assets?
  • We can equivalently imagine, for every level of
    risk, a set of T fundamental risky assets. Then,
    for any arbitrary risky asset of this level of
    risk, we can equivalently write
  • Of course, this is not entirely satisfactory,
    because wed have TxM fundamental assets
    corresponding to each of M levels of risk. We
    will come back to this when we talk about the
    CAPM.
  • In any case, we need to examine how this pricing
    is established in the market-place.

36
Arbitrage and the Law of One Price
  • Law of One Price In a competitive market, if two
    assets generate the same cash (utility) flows,
    they will be priced the same.
  • How is this enforced?
  • If the law is violated if asset 1 sells for
    more than asset 2, then investors can make a
    riskless profit by buying asset 2 and selling it
    as asset 1!
  • In practice we need to take transactions costs
    into account.
  • Also, it may be difficult to execute the two
    transactions at the same time prices might
    change in that interval this introduces some
    risk.

37
Exchange Rates and Triangular Arbitrage
  • Consider the exchange rates reigning at closing
    on January 30.
  • The yen/euro rate was 157.87 yen per euro
  • The euro/ rate was 1.4835 per euro.
  • The yen/ rate was 106.4 yen per dollar.
  • If we start with a dollar, we can buy 106.4 yen
    these can then be used to buy 106.4/157.87 or
    0.674 euros, which can, in turn, be used to
    acquire 0.9998, which is very close to a dollar.

38
Triangular Currency Arbitrage
  • Suppose the euro/ rate had been 1.50 per euro.
  • Then, it would have been possible to start with
    one dollar, acquire 0.674 euros, as above, and
    then get (0.674)(1.5) or 1.011, or a gain of
    1.1 on the initial investment of a dollar.
  • This would imply that the dollar was too cheap,
    relative to the euro and the yen.
  • Many traders would attempt to perform the
    arbitrage discussed above, leading to excess
    supply of dollars and excess demand for the other
    currencies.
  • The net result would be a drop a rise in the
    price of the dollar vis-à-vis the other
    currencies, so that the arbitrage trades would no
    longer be profitable.

39
Risk Arbitrage
  • In this case, trading will continue until there
    are no more riskfree profit opportunities.
  • Thus, arbitrage can ensure that the sorts of
    pricing relationships referred to above can be
    supported in the marketplace, viz
  • What if there are still opportunities that will,
    on average, lead to profit, but the investors
    intending to benefit from this profit will have
    to take on some risk?
  • Presumably investors will trade off the risk
    against the expected profit so that there will be
    few of these expected profit opportunities, as
    well this brings us to the notion of the
    informational efficiency of financial markets.

40
Efficient Markets Hypothesis EMH
  • An assets current price reflects all available
    information this is the EMH.
  • If it didnt, there would be an incentive for
    investors to act on that information.
  • Suppose, for example, that investors noticed that
    good news led to stock prices rising slowly over
    two consecutive days.
  • This would mean that at the end of the first day,
    the good news was not all incorporated in the
    stock price.

41
Efficient Markets Hypothesis
  • In this situation, it would be optimal for
    traders to buy even more of a stock that was
    noted to be rising on a given day, since the
    stock would rise more the next day, giving the
    trader an unusually good chance of making money
    on the trade.
  • But if many traders pursue this strategy, the
    stock price would rise on the first day, itself,
    and the informational inefficiency would be
    eliminated.
  • Empirically, financial markets seem to be
    reasonably close to being efficient.
  • This allows us to price financial assets with
    respect to fundamentals without worrying about
    deviations from these fundamental prices.

42
Stock Price Fundamentals
  • What determines the price of a stock? Or, in
    other words, why would an investor hold stocks?
  • The answer is that s/he expects to receive
    dividends and hopefully benefit from a price
    increase, as well.
  • In other words, P0 PV(D1) PV(P1)
  • However what determines P1?
  • Again, using the previous logic, we must say that
    its the expectation of a dividend in period 2
    and hopefully a further price rise. Continuing,
    in this vein, we see that the stock price must be
    the sum of the present values of all future
    dividends.

43
Dividend Mechanics
  • Declaration date The board of directors declares
    a paymentRecord date The declared dividends are
    distributable to shareholders of record on this
    date.Payment date The dividend checks are
    mailed to shareholders of record.
  • Ex-dividend date A share of stock becomes
    ex-dividend on the date the seller is entitled to
    keep the dividend.   At this point, the stock is
    said to be trading ex-dividend. 

44
Dividend Discount Model
  • What is the price of a stock on its ex-dividend
    date?
  • Using the previous logic, we see that its simply
  • where k is the appropriate discount rate to
    discount the dividends consistent with their
    riskiness.
  • We assume that the one-period ahead discount rate
    is the same for all periods. That is, we use the
    same rate to discount D1 to time 0, as we use to
    discount D2 to time 1.

45
Gordon Growth Model
  • If we assume that the dividend is growing at a
    rate of g per annum forever, this formula
    simplifies to
  • We see that the price of a stock is higher, the
    higher the level of dividends, the higher the
    growth rate of dividends and the lower the
    required rate of return or the discount rate, k.

46
Two essential concepts
  • Cash flows at different points in time cannot be
    compared and aggregated. All cash flows have to
    be brought to the same point in time, before
    comparisons and aggregations are made.
  • The concept of a Time Line

47
Cash Flow Types and Discounting Mechanics
  • There are five types of cash flows -
  • simple cash flows,
  • annuities,
  • growing annuities
  • perpetuities and
  • growing perpetuities

48
I. Simple Cash Flows
  • A simple cash flow is a single cash flow in a
    specified future time period.
  • Cash Flow CFt
  • ____________________________________________
  • Time Period t
  • The present value of this cash flow is-
  • PV of Simple Cash Flow CFt / (1r)t
  • The future value of a cash flow is -
  • FV of Simple Cash Flow CF0 (1 r)t

49
Application The power of compounding - Stocks,
Bonds and Bills
  • Between 1926 and 1998, Ibbotson Associates found
    that stocks on the average made about 11 a year,
    while government bonds on average made about 5 a
    year.
  • If your holding period is one year,the
    difference in end-of-period values is small
  • Value of 100 invested in stocks in one year
    111
  • Value of 100 invested in bonds in one year
    105

50
Holding Period and Value
51
The Frequency of Compounding
  • The frequency of compounding affects the future
    and present values of cash flows. The stated
    interest rate can deviate significantly from the
    true interest rate
  • For instance, a 10 annual interest rate, if
    there is semiannual compounding, works out to-
  • Effective Interest Rate 1.052 - 1 .10125 or
    10.25
  • The general formula isEffective Annualized Rate
    (1r/m)m 1where m is the frequency of
    compounding ( times per year), andr is the
    stated interest rate (or annualized percentage
    rate (APR) per year

52
The Frequency of Compounding

53
II. Annuities
  • An annuity is a constant cash flow that occurs at
    regular intervals for a fixed period of time.
    Defining A to be the annuity,
  • A A A A
  • 0 1 2 3 4

54
Present Value of an Annuity
  • The present value of an annuity can be calculated
    by taking each cash flow and discounting it back
    to the present, and adding up the present values.
    Alternatively, there is a short cut that can be
    used in the calculation A Annuity r
    Discount Rate n Number of years

55
Example PV of an Annuity
  • The present value of an annuity of 1,000 at the
    end of each year for the next five years,
    assuming a discount rate of 10 is -
  • The notation that will be used in the rest of
    these lecture notes for the present value of an
    annuity will be PV(A,r,n).

56
Annuity, given Present Value
  • The reverse of this problem, is when the present
    value is known and the annuity is to be estimated
    - A(PV,r,n).

57
Computing Monthly Payment on a Mortgage
  • Suppose you borrow 200,000 to buy a house on a
    30-year mortgage with monthly payments. The
    annual percentage rate on the loan is 8.
  • The monthly payments on this loan, with the
    payments occurring at the end of each month, can
    be calculated using this equation
  • Monthly interest rate on loan APR/12 0.08/12
    0.0067

58
Future Value of an Annuity
  • The future value of an end-of-the-period annuity
    can also be calculated as follows-

59
An Example
  • Thus, the future value of 1,000 at the end of
    each year for the next five years, at the end of
    the fifth year is (assuming a 10 discount rate)
    -
  • The notation that will be used for the future
    value of an annuity will be FV(A,r,n).

60
Annuity, given Future Value
  • If you are given the future value and you are
    looking for an annuity - A(FV,r,n) in terms of
    notation -

Note, however, that the two formulas, Annuity,
given Future Value and Present Value, given
annuity can be derived from each other, quite
easily. You may want to simply work with a
single formula.
61
Application Saving for College Tuition
  • Assume that you want to send your newborn child
    to a private college (when he gets to be 18 years
    old). The tuition costs are 16000/year now and
    that these costs are expected to rise 5 a year
    for the next 18 years. Assume that you can
    invest, after taxes, at 8.
  • Expected tuition cost/year 18 years from now
    16000(1.05)18 38,506
  • PV of four years of tuition costs at 38,506/year
    38,506 PV(A ,8,4 years) 127,537
  • If you need to set aside a lump sum now, the
    amount you would need to set aside would be -
  • Amount one needs to set apart now
    127,357/(1.08)18 31,916
  • If set aside as an annuity each year, starting
    one year from now -
  • If set apart as an annuity 127,537
    A(FV,8,18 years) 3,405

62
Valuing a Straight Bond
  • You are trying to value a straight bond with a
    fifteen year maturity and a 10.75 coupon rate.
    The current interest rate on bonds of this risk
    level is 8.5.
  • PV of cash flows on bond 107.50 PV(A,8.5,15
    years) 1000/1.08515 1186.85
  • If interest rates rise to 10,
  • PV of cash flows on bond 107.50 PV(A,10,15
    years) 1000/1.1015 1,057.05
  • Percentage change in price -10.94
  • If interest rate fall to 7,
  • PV of cash flows on bond 107.50 PV(A,7,15
    years) 1000/1.0715 1,341.55
  • Percentage change in price 13.03

63
III. Growing Annuity
  • A growing annuity is a cash flow growing at a
    constant rate for a specified period of time. If
    A is the current cash flow, and g is the expected
    growth rate, the time line for a growing annuity
    looks as follows

64
Present Value of a Growing Annuity
  • The present value of a growing annuity can be
    estimated in all cases, but one - where the
    growth rate is equal to the discount rate, using
    the following model
  • In that specific case, the present value is equal
    to the nominal sums of the annuities over the
    period, without the growth effect.

65
The Value of a Gold Mine
  • Consider the example of a gold mine, where you
    have the rights to the mine for the next 20
    years, over which period you plan to extract
    5,000 ounces of gold every year. The price per
    ounce is 300 currently, but it is expected to
    increase 3 a year. The appropriate discount rate
    is 10. The present value of the gold that will
    be extracted from this mine can be estimated as
    follows

66
IV. Perpetuity
  • A perpetuity is a constant cash flow at regular
    intervals forever. The present value of a
    perpetuity is-

67
Valuing a Consol Bond
  • A consol bond is a bond that has no maturity and
    pays a fixed coupon. Assume that you have a 6
    coupon console bond. The value of this bond, if
    the interest rate is 9, is as follows -
  • Value of Consol Bond 60 / .09 667

68
V. Growing Perpetuities
  • A growing perpetuity is a cash flow that is
    expected to grow at a constant rate forever. The
    present value of a growing perpetuity is -
  • where
  • CF1 is the expected cash flow next year,
  • g is the constant growth rate and
  • r is the discount rate.

69
Valuing a Stock with Growing Dividends
  • Southwestern Bell paid dividends per share of
    2.73 in 1992. Its earnings and dividends have
    grown at 6 a year between 1988 and 1992, and are
    expected to grow at the same rate in the long
    term. The rate of return required by investors on
    stocks of equivalent risk is 12.23.
  • Current Dividends per share 2.73
  • Expected Growth Rate in Earnings and Dividends
    6
  • Discount Rate 12.23
  • Value of Stock 2.73 1.06 / (.1223 -.06)
    46.45

70
What are bonds?
  • A borrowing arrangement where the borrower issues
    an IOU to the investor.

Time
0
Price
Coupon Payments Coupon Rate x FV/ 2 Paid
semiannually
1
Investor
Issuer
2
.
.
Face Value (FV)
T
71
Bond Pricing
  • A T-period bond with coupon payments of C per
    period and a face value of F.
  • The value of this bond can be computed as the sum
    of the present value of the annuity component of
    the bond plus the present value of the FV, where
    is the present value of an
  • annuity of 1 per period for T periods, with a
    discount rate of r per period.

72
Bonds with semi-annual coupons
  • Normally, bonds pay semi-annual coupons
  • The bond value is given by
  • where the first component is, once again, the
    present value of an annuity, and y is the bonds
    yield-to-maturity.

73
Bond Pricing Example
  • If F 100,000 T 8 years the coupon rate is
    10, and the bonds yield-to-maturity is 8.8,
    the bond's price is computed as

  • 106,789.52

74
The Relation between Bond Prices and Yields
  • Consider a 2 year, 10 coupon bond with a 1000
    face value. If the bond yield is 8.8, the price
    is 50 1000/(1.044)4 1021.58.
  • Now suppose the market bond yield drops to 7.8.
    The market price is now given by 50
    1000/(1.039)4 1040.02.
  • As the bond yield drops, the bond price rises,
    and vice-versa.

75
Bond Prices and YieldsA Graphic View
76
Bond Yield MeasurementDefinitions
  • Yield to MaturityA measure of the average rate
    of return on a bond if held to maturity. To
    compute it, we define the length of a period as 6
    months, and then calculate the internal rate of
    return per period. Finally, we double the
    six-monthly IRR to get the bond equivalent yield,
    or yield to maturity. This is more commonly used
    in the marketplace.
  • Effective Annual YieldTake the six-monthly IRR
    and annualize it by compounding. This measure is
    less commonly used.

77
Bond Yield Measurement Examples
  • An 8 coupon, 30-year bond is selling at
    1276.76. First solve the following equation
  • This equation is solved by r 0.03. (You will
    see later how to solve this equation.)
  • The yield-to-maturity is given by 2 x 0.03 6
  • The effective annual yield is given by (1.03)2 -
    1 6.09

78
Computing YTM by Trial and Error
  • A 3 year, 8 coupon, 1000 bond, selling for
    949.22
  • Period Cash flow Present Value
  • 9 11 10
  • 1 40 38.28 37.91 38.10
  • 2 40 36.63 35.94 36.28
  • 3 40 35.05 34.06 34.55
  • 4 40 33.54 32.29 32.91
  • 5 40 32.10 30.61 31.34
  • 6 1040 798.61 754.26 776.06
  • Total 974.21 925.07 949.24
  • The bond is selling at a discount hence the
    yield exceeds the coupon rate. At a discount
    rate equal to the coupon rate of 8, the price
    would be 1000. Hence try a discount rate of 9.
    At 9, the PV is 974.21, which is too high. Try a
    higher discount rate of 11, with a PV of
    925.07, which is too low. Trying 10, which is
    between 9 and 11, the PV is exactly equal to
    the price. Hence the bond yield 10.

79
Computing YTM by Trial and Error A Graphic View
80
Coupons and Yields
  • A bond that sells for more than its face value is
    called a premium bond.
  • The coupon on such a bond will be greater than
    its yield-to-maturity.
  • A bond that sells for less than its face value is
    called a discount bond.
  • The coupon rate on such a bond will be less than
    its yield-to-maturity.
  • A bond that sells for exactly its face value is
    called a par bond.
  • The coupon rate on such a bond is equal to its
    yield.

81
Non-flat Term Structures
  • There is an implicit assumption made in the
    previous slide that the annualized discount rate
    is independent of when the cashflows occur.
  • That is, if 100 to paid in year 1 are worth
    94.787 today, resulting in an implicit discount
    rate of (100/94.787 -1) 5.5, then 100 to be
    paid in year 2 are worth (in todays dollars),
    100/(1.055)2 89.845. However, this need not
    be so.
  • Demand and supply for year 1 dollars need not be
    subject to the same forces as demand and supply
    for year 2 dollars. Hence we might have the 1
    year discount rate be 5.5, the year 2 discount
    rate 6 and the year 3 discount rate 6.5

82
Non-flat Term Structures
  • If we now have a 10 coupon FV1000 three year
    bond, which will have cash flows of 100 in year
    1, 100 in year 2 and 1100 in year 3, its price
    will be computed as the sum of 100/(1.055)
    94.787, 100/(1.06)2 89.00 and 100/(1.065)3
    910.634 for a total of 1094.421.
  • We could, at this point, compute the
    yield-to-maturity of this bond using the formula
    given above. If we do this, we will find that
    the yield-to-maturity is 6.439 per annum.
  • This is not the discount rate for the first or
    the second or the third cashflow. Rather, the
    yield-to-maturity must, in general, be
    interpreted as a (harmonic) average of the actual
    discount rates for the different cashflows on the
    bond, with more weight being given to the
    discount rates for the larger cashflows.

83
Yield Curves for Feb. 1-12, 2008
Date 1mo 3mo 6mo 1yr 2yr 3yr 5yr 7yr 10yr 20yr 30yr
02/01/08 1.75 2.10 2.15 2.13 2.09 2.22 2.75 3.13 3.62 4.31 4.32
02/04/08 2.15 2.27 2.22 2.17 2.08 2.23 2.78 3.18 3.68 4.37 4.37
02/05/08 2.22 2.19 2.13 2.06 1.93 2.08 2.66 3.08 3.61 4.32 4.33
02/06/08 2.12 2.10 2.10 2.05 1.96 2.11 2.67 3.08 3.61 4.36 4.37
02/07/08 2.19 2.17 2.13 2.08 1.99 2.21 2.79 3.21 3.74 4.50 4.51
02/08/08 2.24 2.23 2.12 2.05 1.93 2.10 2.69 3.11 3.64 4.41 4.43
02/11/08 2.35 2.31 2.13 2.06 1.93 2.10 2.67 3.09 3.62 4.38 4.41
02/12/08 2.55 2.31 2.12 2.06 1.94 2.13 2.71 3.13 3.66 4.43 4.46
84
Yield Curves for Feb. 1-12, 2008
85
Time Pattern of Bond Prices
  • Bonds, like any other asset, represent an
    investment by the bondholder.
  • As such, the bondholder expects a certain total
    return by way of capital appreciation and coupon
    yield.
  • This implies a particular pattern of bond price
    movement over time.

86
Time Pattern of Bond Prices Graphic View
Assuming yields are constant and coupons are
paid continuously
87
Time Pattern of Bond Prices in Practice
  • Coupons are paid semi-annually. Hence the bond
    price would increase at the required rate of
    return between coupon dates.
  • On the coupon payment date, the bond price would
    drop by an amount equal to the coupon payment.
  • To prevent changes in the quoted price in the
    absence of yield changes, the price quoted
    excludes the amount of the accrued coupon.
  • Example An 8 coupon bond quoted at 96 5/32 on
    March 31, 2008, paying its next coupon on June
    30, 2008 would actually require payment of
    961.5625 0.5(80/2) 981.5625
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com