Approaches to modelling poverty dynamics - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 39
About This Presentation
Title:

Approaches to modelling poverty dynamics

Description:

the latest fashion in poverty research, which searches after duration and movement ... its ability to replicate the poverty patterns emerging from the data' ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:184
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 40
Provided by: Step68
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Approaches to modelling poverty dynamics


1
Approaches to modelling poverty dynamics
  • Stephen P. Jenkins
  • (ISER, University of Essex)

2
Whats changed over the last decade?
  • the latest fashion in poverty research, which
    searches after duration and movement ... However
    none of the recent work on the dynamics of
    poverty gives cause to assume that the structures
    of poverty uncovered here by cross-sectional
    analysis would be any different to those found
    by dynamic analyses. (Mary Daly, The Gender
    Division of Welfare. The Impact of the British
    and German Welfare States. CUP, 2000)
  • Is this view sustainable any more?

3
Whats changed over the last decade? (ii)
  • Policy giving more emphasis to dynamic
    perspectives
  • Spread from USA to Europe and elsewhere
  • E.g. UK
  • In the past, analysis has focused on static,
    snapshot pictures of where people are at a
    particular point in time. Snapshot data can lead
    people to focus on the symptoms of the problem
    rather than addressing the underlying processes
    which lead people to have or be denied
    opportunities. To understand why peoples life
    chances differ, it is important to look for the
    events and experiences which create opportunity
    and those which create barriers, and to use this
    as a focus for policy action. (HM Treasury,
    1999)
  • NB (UK) Income mobility mostly linked with
    intergenerational movements (equality of
    opportunity), and poverty dynamics with
    short-run movements

4
Whats changed over the last decade? (iii)
  • Changes in nature and availability of panel data
    sets, e.g.
  • SOEP, BHPS growing maturity ( waves)
  • SLID, HILDA, SoFIE new panels
  • ECHP 19942001 for EU12
  • EU-SILC 2004/5 (4-year rotating panel for
    EU254)
  • US PSID since 1999, biannual with retrospective
    fill-in ( now less used)
  • US SIPP quarterly rotating panel to be replaced
    by DEWS in 2009 (annual data collection perhaps
    with admin record linkage)
  • Developing countries increasing number of panels
    (see e.g. JDS 2000)
  • Administrative record data (mainly Nordic
    countries)
  • UKHLS

5
Whats changed over the last decade? (iv)
  • Supplementation of official statistics on poverty
    and income distribution with information about
    dynamics
  • UK HBAI includes Low Income Dynamics chapter
    based on BHPS Opportunity for All. ( times poor
    over 4-year period, ignoring censoring events
    and transitions)
  • EU ECHP-based statistics
  • EU Laeken indicators
  • Some use of social exclusion indicators (in
    EU), but continued focus on needs-adjusted HH
    income
  • Substantial body of new academic research
  • See later

6
Main substantive lessons learnt?
  • Movement out of low income population turnover
  • Importance of spell repetition
  • Falling (back) into poverty, not only climbing
    out, and thence
  • Persistence total time spent poor over a period
  • Differential vulnerability of particular groups
    to persistent poverty
  • E.g. GB Single female pensioners, lone-parent
    families, workless households, and people in the
    social rented sector, were more likely to
    experience persistent low income than other
    groups (LID 19912004, Table 8.1)
  • ? Past poverty may directly effect Pr(poor), cet.
    par.?
  • Results about duration dependence and state
    dependence
  • Policy has been most influenced by simpler
    analyses?

7
The main research questions
  • These have been, and continue to be,
  • What are the poverty experiences?
  • Length of poverty spells spell repetition time
    poor over a period, and
  • How these differ for different groups
  • What are the determinants of observed outcomes,
    and the roles of
  • Observed characteristics (may be time-varying,
    and/or environmental)
  • Unobserved characteristics
  • Duration dependence and state dependence
  • Multivariate regression models useful for
    addressing both

8
Multivariate modelling approaches
  • 0. Bane-Ellwood trigger event transition
    cross-tabs
  • chronic poverty (averaged income) models
  • hazard regression models
  • binary dependent variable dynamic random effects
    panel models
  • Markovian transition models
  • covariance structure models of income
  • dynamic microsimulation models of component
    processes
  • All 6 developed in other contexts, and now
    applied to income/poverty appropriate?
  • Income multiple income sources multiple people
  • Dynamics changes in income sources changing
    household composition

9
Bane-Ellwood trigger event transition cross-tabs
  • Not multivariate, but arguably informative about
    the proximate drivers of transitions
  • B-E (1986), Jenkins (2000), Jenkins Rigg
    (2001) mutually-exclusive hierarchical
    classification of demographic and income source
    events
  • Jenkins Rigg (2001), Jenkins Schluter (2003),
    Valletta (2006), DWP (annual) non-mutually-exclus
    ive classifications
  • Key results (US, UK, Canada, Germany)
  • Demographic events more relevant to entries than
    exits
  • Labour market events very important, but (a) not
    just HH heads, and (b) mixture of changes in
    employment and earnings

10
Chronic poverty (averaged income) models
  • Chronic poverty longitudinally-averaged income
    below the poverty line (Rodgers Rodgers, 1993)
  • Transitory variations and measurement errors
    smoothed out, so get a view of permanent income
    level
  • Can people smooth in practice? Differences in
    borrowing capacities by income?
  • Over what period to average? (And balanced panel
    issues?)
  • Examples
  • Jalan Ravallion (1997) Hill Jenkins (2001)
  • Cross-national differences in prevalence and in
    correlates (HH characteristics, events) Kuchler
    Goebel (2003) Valletta (2006)

11
(Discrete time) Hazard regression models
  • Most commonly-used approach
  • Single spell models of exit and of re-entry
  • e.g. Oxley et al. (2000), Finnie Sweetman
    (2003), Fouarge Layte (2005), Jenkins Rigg
    (2001), and others
  • Multi-state multiple-transition models with
    unobserved heterogeneity (mixture hazard models)
  • e.g. Stevens (1999), Devicienti (2001), Jenkins
    Rigg (2001), Hansen Wahlberg (2005), Biewen
    (2006), Fertig Tamm (2007)

f(eid) g(d) ??Xid ?i
f(.) logit, probit or cloglog link d
elapsed duration
Exit hazard Re-entry hazard
f(rid) g(d) ??Xid ?i
Bivariate distribution of unobserved effects ?i,
?i , approximated by finite number of mass points
associated probabilities
12
Hazard regression models (2)
  • Mixture models non-trivial to estimate and derive
    predictions from (but some technology
    diffusion)
  • Hard to find more than small number of mass
    points
  • Initial conditions issue also arises, but no
    example yet where able to fit model
    satisfactorily with it
  • Identification issues generally with relatively
    short panels e.g. duration dependence versus
    frailty (J R 2001)
  • Provides estimates of covariate effects, duration
    dependence (? state dependence), and can derive
    predicted/simulated time in poverty over a period
    given entry

13
Binary dependent variable dynamic random effects
(DRE) panel models
  • Developed esp. in unemployment dynamics
    literature inter alia Heckman (1981),
    Arulampalam et al. (2001), Stewart (2007)
  • Poverty applications include Biewen (2004),
    Hansen et al. (2006), Poggi (2007)
  • Pr(yit 1 yi,t1, , zi, ci) ??(zit? ?
    yi,t1 ci)
  • yit 1 if i is poor at t, 0 otherwise (yi0
    initial value)
  • zi vector of exogenous variables
  • ci unobserved individual effect
  • State dependence summarized by ?

14
DRE models (2)
  • Initial conditions is main statistical issue
    addressed to date correlation between yit1 and
    ci
  • Heckman (1981) approximate the distribution of
    initial value conditional on z, c integrate out
    jointly with other periods (non-trivial, but see
    Stewart 2006)
  • Wooldridge (2005) model the distribution of the
    unobserved effect c conditional on the initial
    value yi0 and exogenous variables z (can use
    standard software)
  • Reduce potential correlations between
    unobservable individual effects and error using
    time-averaged z as well (Chamberlain-Mundlak
    idea)
  • Emphasis on estimates of APEs (via ? ) and ?
  • No predictions of poverty experience (but one
    could)
  • Attrition not usually addressed

15
Markovian transition models
  • Model entry and exit probabilities using
    endogenous switching model (e.g. Cappellari
    Jenkins, 2004)
  • yit (yit1)?1? (1yit1)?2?zit1 (?i
    ?it)
  • plus equations for endogenous selections
    estimated jointly
  • Simplified dynamics (relative to hazard models),
    but
  • Can account for multiple endogenous selection
    effects (e.g. panel attrition, non-response,
    initial conditions) by modelling jointly with
    main process
  • Covariate effects vary with last years poverty
    status (no state dependence if ?1 ? ?2 cf. ? ?
    0)
  • Can derive spell duration predictions easily

16
Markovian transition models (2)
  • Maximum Simulated Likelihood estimation rather
    than integrating out as in DRE (but technology
    diffusion)
  • Transition parameters identified by changes
    between one wave and the next (as for DRE
    models), but variance of random effect in the
    main transition equation not identified (cf.
    DRE). Do we need it?
  • (C J 2004) Endogenous selections non-ignorable
    but neglecting to control for endogeneity of
    initial poverty status is more problematic than
    neglecting to control for endogeneity of
    retention

17
Covariance structure models of income
  • Models of the longitudinal covariance structure
    of income, from which results about poverty
    dynamics are derived
  • Mens earnings Lillard and Willis (1978), ,
    Meghir Pistaferri (2004) references to
    poverty!
  • Household income and poverty dynamics Duncan
    (1983), Duncan and Rodgers (1991), Stevens
    (1995), Devicienti (2001), Biewen (2005)
  • log(Iit) Zi? Xit? uit
  • uit ??t?i ?t?it
  • ?it ??it1 ??it ???it1
  • ? cov(uit, ujs)

Example
Permanent Transitory
ARMA(1,1)
18
Covariance structure models (2)
  • Estimates provide information about the roles of
    permanent and transitory shocks to income (but
    simple interpretation complicated when
    year-specific weights used)
  • Many labour market and demographic events not
    well characterised by models characterisation of
    income shocks?
  • Same process applies to rich and poor alike (cf.
    previous models)
  • Attrition and other endogeneous selections
    usually ignored

19
Covariance structure models (3)
  • With (log)normality, the model can be used to
    predict poverty transition probabilities, and
    thence poverty sequences over a period, but
    simulations relatively difficult (some
    technology diffusion)
  • Beauty contest covariance structure versus
    mixture hazard models Stevens (1999) Devicienti
    (2001) both models produce fairly similar
    predictions, but for the population as a whole
    the variance-components models seemed to perform
    worse in terms of its ability to replicate the
    poverty patterns emerging from the data

20
Dynamic microsimulation models
  • Aim at structural model of underlying dynamic
    processes which determine earnings, and the
    earnings associated with their process outcomes.
    From these, income and poverty status are derived
  • Aassve, Burgess, Dickson Propper (2005) re GB
  • 5 simultaneous hazards estimated jointly birth,
    union formation, union dissolution, employment
    and non-employment
  • Poverty status assigned stochastically depending
    on mean Pr(poor) in each 5-outcome combination of
    states
  • Burgess and Propper (CEPR, 1998) model poverty
    dynamics amongst a sample of American women aged
    20-35 years from the National Longitudinal Survey
    of Youth (NLSY)

21
Dynamic microsimulation models (ii)
  • 3 life-course dimensions considered marriage,
    fertility, work.
  • State in each year summarised by an m, k, l
    combination. m married or not k has kids or
    not l working or not. Each state has an
    associated distribution of earnings
  • hazard model of Pr(marital partnership formation)
  • hazard model of Pr(marital partnership
    dissolution)
  • bivariate probit of probability of having a child
    and probability of working
  • earnings functions per state (conditional on
    selection into state)
  • earnings function for a spouse
  • Income mixture model (sum of probabilities of
    being in a state ? earnings associated with
    state), and hence
  • poverty status

22
Dynamic microsimulation models (iii)
  • All dynamics arise via the dynamics of the
    component processes
  • E.g. no state dependence of poverty per se
  • Derive predictions for poverty by simulation of
    the underlying processes (not of income per se)
  • We argue that this indirect approach to
    modelling poverty is the right way to bring
    economic tools to bear on the issue (Aassve et
    al. 2005)
  • Endogeneous selections identification
    robustness generally ?
  • Very complicated and time-consuming. Is the
    pay-off from this more structural approach
    worthwhile?

23
Evaluating (empirical) modelling approaches
  • Trade-offs between 3 general criteria (Jenkins
    2000)
  • Fit the past and provide predictions /simulations
  • Goodness of fit and other specification issues
  • Appropriate focus estimating parameters versus
    drawing out relevant implications of estimates
  • Be structural
  • Descriptive associations versus connections with
    underlying dynamic processes in labour and other
    markets, household formation and dissolution,
    etc.
  • Be practical
  • Useful results in reasonable time (DWP versus
    RAE)
  • technology diffusion helps
  • More specific issues an assortment discussed
    now

24
1(a) Discretisation on LHS
  • Is poverty really a distinct discrete state?
  • So, use models with income as the depvar? But
  • Poverty line an arbitrary cut-off?
  • Sensitivity analysis using different low income
    cut-offs doesnt quite address the point
  • A way of introducing non-linearities?
  • Stevens (1999) reference to non-linearities
    (rich versus poor) in context of hazard models of
    poverty
  • Stewart Swaffield (1999) characterise low pay
    probit in terms of a general linear model of
    earnings
  • Fuzzy poverty approaches have not proved hugely
    fruitful IMHO, especially when for dynamics

25
1(b) Discretisation on RHS
  • State dependence is it plausible that past
    poverty (0/1 variable) has a distinct causal
    effect?
  • Stories explaining SD in incomes mostly refer to
    labour market SD e.g. in unemployment
  • More plausible that any effects of past income
    might be more graduated?
  • Cf. Cappellari Jenkins (2004) variation on
    Markovian model with multiple categories on RHS
    (poor 4 non-poor categories)
  • C J finding results about the importance of
    GSD were not driven by neglect of heterogeneity
    among the non-poor

26
2. Measurement error misclassification
  • Long-standing view that income data are
    error-ridden perhaps more at bottom than at top
  • Move 0.50 above line treated the same as 50
    move above
  • Ad hoc adjustments e.g. require a transition to
    require gt10 change above/below line
  • Chronic poverty approach smoothes out transitory
    error
  • Covariate structure approach puts measurement
    error into transitory component
  • Are measurement errors classical? Most
    unlikely!
  • systematically associated with other factors,
    asymmetrically distributed, correlated over time?
  • PSID validation study data errors negatively
    correlated with true level of earnings

27
2. Measurement error misclassification (ii)
  • Glaring gap in knowledge about measurement error
    properties of HH income (and lack of suitable
    validation sources?)
  • Few clear cut theoretical results about impacts
    of measurement error (classical or not) in
    non-linear models
  • Several articles explore error-ridden continuous
    RHS vble
  • Hausman et al. (1998) misclassification in LHS
    vble leads to error in logit/probit (cf. errors
    in eqn case)
  • Gustafson and Le (2002) dichotomisation of cts
    RHS vble can sometimes reduce errors-in-variables
    bias

28
2. Measurement error misclassification (iii)
  • Latent class models as a means to correct for
    measurement error in poverty dynamics?
  • Breen Moisio (JEI 2004) latent mover-stayer
    Markov model of transition table
  • because the state of poverty is poorly measured,
    much of what appears to be change is, in fact,
    error in classifying respondents mobility in
    poverty transition tables is over-estimated by
    between 25 and 50 percent if measurement error is
    ignored
  • Identification assumptions (see their article)
  • Is poverty status really a latent class?
  • More fruitful to look at income and error process
    and relate to actual income poverty line?

29
3. Explanatory variable specification
  • RHS vbles in most multivariate regressions models
    are expressed in levels (e.g. workers,
    household size) not as events (cf. B-E approach)
    why not?
  • Might improve Fit? And make more structural?
  • Leads to problems of simultaneity and endogeneity
    (see below)?
  • NB Stevens (1999) reported insignificant event
    effects if levels also included (but issue of
    empty cells?)
  • If events relevant, what dating is appropriate
    simultaneous, one year lag, two year lag, or all
    of above ?

30
3. Explanatory variable specification (ii)
  • Time-varying RHS variables raise problems for
    simulations of poverty spells (need to specify
    time paths of these unless endogenised)
  • NB implausible to fix many levels variables too
    when doing simulations
  • Should any individual-level covariates be used as
    RHS variables when modelling poverty?
  • Cf. age of HH head versus age of person
  • Poverty is defined in terms of HH income

31
3. Explanatory variable specification (iii)
  • The strict exogeneity assumption in DRE models
  • Feedback effects If yt1 affects z, then, in
    the equation for yt, a correlation is induced
    between z and error term, and hence bias in
    parameter estimates
  • Similar problem arises in Markov and hazard
    models
  • Biewen (2004) extensive discussion, and
    estimation of a DRE model with feedback on
    employment status, whether lives alone (and
    comparison with pooled panel probit model etc.).
    Stat. sig. effects found
  • General problem? Are feedback effects plausible?

Pr(yit 1 yi,t1, , zi, ci) ??(zit? ?
yi,t1 ci)
32
4(a) Unit of analysis issues
  • What units should be used as the obs in the
    regressions?
  • All individuals (adults kids)? as in
    descriptive statistics
  • Adults only? As only they generate the income
  • Children only (if studying child poverty)?
  • Fertig and Tamm (2007)
  • Problem of defining/modelling a poverty spell
    consider a child born into a HH where the adults
    have been poor already for 2 years. What is the
    elapsed poverty duration that is relevant to the
    modelling?

33
4(b) Unit of analysis issues
  • Breakdown of the i.i.d. assumption in e.g. hazard
    model context (but also applies in other
    approaches)
  • Mixture models for control for correlations
    between spells for the same individual
    (individual random effect)
  • Or should it really be interpreted as a household
    effect given definition of poverty?
  • But often there are repeated observations from
    the same household at a point in time (since
    poverty defined in terms of the income of the HH
    to which someone belongs)
  • ? Generalize mixture model to incorporate a
    household-specific random effect in addition to
    individual one (as with firm and worker
    individual effects)?
  • But how to do this consistently, given that
    households split/fuse?
  • ? Treat each set of individuals who ever lived
    together during panel as a cluster and use
    sandwich estimator of SEs
  • Cappellari Jenkins (2004), Biewen (2005)

34
4(c) Unit of analysis issues
  • Potential mismatch between timing of incomes
    received and household composition the
    importance of the income reference period
    definition
  • At year t interview, usually ask about the
    incomes over past year of those people present in
    the HH at date of interview
  • If people have left the household between t1 and
    t, then the year t interview does not pick up the
    incomes of the leavers
  • A current income definition reduces mismatch
  • Mismatch complications also exemplified by ECHP
    collected data at t about incomes over calendar
    year prior to interview income reference period
    overlaps with year t1 interview

35
5(a). Discrete panel issues
  • Discrete panel observations but underlying
    poverty spells in continuous time
  • ? Over-estimation of state dependence if poverty
    in consecutive waves represents continuation of
    the same poverty spell?
  • See discussion in DRE models of unemployment by
    Arulapalam et al. (2000), Stewart (2007)

36
5(b). Discrete panel issues
  • Discrete panel observations (grouped duration
    data) but underlying poverty spells in continuous
    time
  • Single spell model of poverty spell length
    sequence OPPPOOP over 7 year panel
  • years at risk of exit for poverty spell 1 3
    or 4? Most analysts use 4 Issue when does
    censoring occur?
  • Multi-state multi-transition models sequence
    OPPPOOP over 7 year panel
  • Poverty spell 1s length 3, followed by 2
    years non-poverty only logically consistent
    definition (as for discrete model)
  • But no natural zero date of entry (assumed that
    beginning of interval coincides with beginning of
    spell)
  • Longer ref income period ? more likely miss short
    spells

37
6. Endogenous selections
  • Initial conditions, panel attrition, employment,
    item non-response
  • Only the first of these given much explicit
    attention in most applications to date
  • By contrast most studies of attrition regarding
    outcome in levels not transitions (JHR special
    issue 1998)
  • Absorbing versus non-absorbing attrition
  • Problems of finding plausible instruments
  • Biewen (2005) uses inverse probability weights
    (for initial selection and retention)
  • What is population represented when pool spells?
  • Assumes ignorability of attrition

38
7. Short panels
  • are here to stay, and so need methods
    appropriate for them
  • rotating panels such as SIPP / DEWS, EU-SILC
  • young panels such as HILDA, SoFIE, UKHLS
  • ECHP (especially given way income defined)
  • Raise issues about extent to which one can
    identify aspects of dynamics reliably
  • covariance structures random effects variance
    duration dependence separately, etc.
  • Greater role for DRE and Markovian models?
  • Greater role for administrative panels? (Unlikely
    for HH income, at least in UK?)

39
Envoi which model?
  • Tensions between the goals of
  • Fitting and predicting
  • Structural versus descriptive
  • Practicality
  • in development and application of models
  • Plus a range of other issues, as mentioned
  • No obvious winner
  • Role of economic theory for empirical modelling
    of poverty?
  • Income versus expenditure versus multiple
    indicators?
  • Frequency of measurement (annual vs. more often)
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com