EXPERIMENTAL RESEARCH ON MANAGEMENT ACCOUNTING - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 42
About This Presentation
Title:

EXPERIMENTAL RESEARCH ON MANAGEMENT ACCOUNTING

Description:

Emerging practices. Practices currently prohibited by laws or regulations. Practices not implemented due to competition, fad, fashion, self selection. 18 ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:138
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 43
Provided by: stev56
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: EXPERIMENTAL RESEARCH ON MANAGEMENT ACCOUNTING


1
EXPERIMENTAL RESEARCH ON MANAGEMENT ACCOUNTING
  • Michael D. Shields
  • Michigan State University
  • 2005

2
OUTLINE
  • EXAMPLES
  • INTRODUCTION
  • IMPORTANT FEATURES OF MA EXPERIMENTS
  • READING LIST

3
1. EXAMPLES
  • Most experiments in MA test hypotheses from
    economics and/or psychology about individual or
    small group cognition (judgments, decisions)
    and/or motivation (effort, learning,
    performance).
  • Some experimental studies investigate issues
    related to bargaining/negotiating, cross-cultural
    psychology, and personality.
  • Next slides provide summaries of five studies.

4
Chow (1983)
  • Do budgets and compensation contracts influence
    individuals choice of contracts and performance?
  • Innovative study that provided the foundation for
    many experimental studies on incentive
    contracting, participative budgeting, performance
    measurement, and management audits (see Young and
    Lewis 1995).
  • Independent variables
  • Budget difficulty average or difficult
  • Compensation contract fixed pay, piece rate,
    budget based
  • Budget setting compensation contract and budget
    difficulty is self selected or imposed
  • Dependent variables
  • Choice of compensation contract and individual
    performance

5
  • H1 Result When budgets are imposed, budget
    difficulty and compensation contract have
    additive effects on performance, controlling for
    performance capability.
  • Highest performance with difficult budget and
    piece rate, and lowest performance with average
    budget and fixed pay.
  • Result consistent with goal setting theory
    (additive) but not agency theory (interaction).
  • H2 Result When individuals select their own
    compensation contract (fixed pay or budget
    based), they select based on their skill.
  • Individuals with higher skill select contracts
    that have more budget-based incentives,
    consistent with agency theory.

6
Luft (1994)
  • Does the choice of compensation contract depend
    on whether incentives are labeled as a bonus or
    penalty?
  • 80 base 20 bonus if P gt B or 80 base if P lt
    B
  • 100 base if P gt B or 100 base - 20 penalty if
    P lt B
  • Economic analysis treats both contracts as
    equivalent ( expected pay), but most people
    prefer the bonus contract.
  • Economically, but not psychologically,
    equivalent.
  • Non-monetary payoffs Bonus has connotations of
    approval and reward, which many people receive
    utility from.
  • Prospect theory People realize more subjective
    disutility from a realized loss (penalty) than
    from a lost gain (bonus).
  • Implicit contract Contract sets an implicit base
    pay level, which determines future base pay.
    People prefer higher base pay because it implies
    higher future base pay levels.

7
  • H1 Employees will be more likely to choose an
    incentive contract with a given set of payoffs
    for performance relative to a budget when the
    incentive is labeled a bonus rather than a
    penalty.
  • Result prediction
  • Responses to post-experiment questions indicate
    that most people explain their choice by 1 or
    more of the 3 explanations.
  • H2 When employees judgments about their past
    performance is dependent on their memory, their
    preference for a bonus over a penalty incentive
    contract increases with experience.
  • People encode and retrieve from memory
    experiences that are more memorable (e.g., big
    / payoffs) because they create strong emotions.
    As people gain experience, they are more likely
    to remember their big positive emotional
    experiences (e.g., receiving a bonus), which then
    creates preferences for bonus over penalty
    incentive contracts.
  • Result prediction.

8
Vera-Munoz (1998)
  • Does the use of opportunity costs in
    resource-allocation decisions depend on
    individuals accounting knowledge and decision
    context, controlling for their analytical
    ability?
  • Financial accounting focuses on sunk, not
    opportunity, costs. When in a business context,
    individuals with financial accounting knowledge
    will activate this knowledge and focus their
    attention on information associated with it.
  • H1 Number opportunity costs ignored in making
    resource-allocation decisions in a business
    context increases with financial accounting
    knowledge.

9
  • H2 Number opportunity costs ignored by
    individuals who have a high level of financial
    accounting knowledge when making resource
    allocation decisions is larger in a business than
    in a personal context.
  • Results predictions.
  • Study illustrates a negative consequence of
    having financial accounting knowledge when making
    business decisions.
  • Curse of knowledge It is difficult not to use
    knowledge that is activated by context (cue)
    regardless of whether that knowledge is relevant
    to a decision.

10
Frederickson, Peffer and Pratt (1999)
  • Does an individuals experience in making
    decisions under a performance-evaluation system
    influence how he or she evaluates others
    decisions?
  • Experience under performance evaluations based on
    outcomes (decisions) will direct attention toward
    outcomes (decision inputs/processes), causing
    outcomes (decisions) to be salient in knowledge
    representations.
  • Frequency of outcome feedback reinforces
    outcome-based knowledge representations.
  • Under outcome-based evaluations, outcome feedback
    reinforces a causal link between outcomes and
    evaluations.
  • Under decision-based evaluations, outcome
    feedback is of no use in assessing decision
    performance, reinforcing the absence of a causal
    link between outcomes and evaluations.

11
  • H Influence of outcome feedback on performance
    evaluations is an interactive function of
    experience with decision- or outcome-based
    performance evaluations and outcome feedback
    frequency.
  • Relative size of the expected influence of
    outcome feedback on evaluations, from smallest to
    largest
  • Experience w/ decision evaluations and frequent
    outcome feedback
  • Experience w/ decision evaluations and infrequent
    outcome feedback
  • Experience w/ outcome evaluations and infrequent
    outcome feedback
  • Experience w/ outcome evaluations and frequent
    outcome feedback.
  • Dependent variable difference in the performance
    evaluation of a decision in which the decision
    outcome is reported to be gt or lt a performance
    standard.
  • If decision outcomes do not affect performance
    evaluations, then there is no difference in
    evaluations as decision outcomes vary.
  • Results support hypothesis.

12
Luft and Shields (2001)
  • Does an individuals subjective prediction
    performance about future profits arising from a
    current-period intangibles expenditure depend on
    whether the expenditure is expensed or
    capitalized?
  • Individuals study accounting data to learn the
    expenditure-profit relation and then make
    predictions about how similar expenditures will
    affect future profits.
  • Learning is less effective when an expenditure is
    expensed because expensing signals no expected
    future-profit effect, which focuses attention and
    hence learning on the contemporaneous relation
    rather than the lagged relation.
  • Expense implies a negative relation between
    current expense and current profit. If expect
    negative relation, then focus less attention on
    learning the positive relation between current
    expense and future profit, resulting in a less
    accurate estimate of the magnitude of the lagged
    relation.

13
  • H Individuals profit predictions will be less
    accurate and consistent, and their consensus and
    self-insight will be lower, when expenditures on
    intangibles are expensed than when they are
    capitalized.
  • H Individuals cognitive model will less match
    the optimal (statistical) model when expenditures
    on intangibles are expensed than when they are
    capitalized.
  • H In predicting profits, individuals will
    underweight the significant lagged effect of
    intangibles expenditures on future profits more
    when expenditures are expensed than capitalized.
  • Results consistent with all hypotheses.

14
2. INTRODUCTION
  • DEFINITION OF EXPERIMENT
  • DISTINCTIVE FEATURES OF EXPERIMENTS
  • BENEFITS OF EXPERIMENTS
  • COSTS OF EXPERIMENTS
  • VALIDITY OF EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE

15
A. DEFINITION
  • EXPERIMENT MANIPULATES INDEPENDENT VARIABLES
    (IVs) and OBSERVES (MEASURES) their EFFECTS on
    DEPENDENT VARIABLES (DVs).

16
B. DISTINCTIVE FEATURES OF EXPERIMENTS
  • Manipulation of IVs
  • Random assignment of people to treatments (i.e.,
    levels of IVs)
  • Control of variables other than the IVs DVs

17
C. BENEFITS OF EXPERIMENTS
  • Controlled tests of theory performance
    predictions, process validity, boundary
    conditions, assumptions.
  • Experiments are especially valuable when theories
    make conflicting predictions and/or empirical
    evidence is mixed.
  • High internal validity Control for the effects
    on the DV of all variables except the IV.
  • Provide policy input on preferred practices and
    standards.
  • Ex ante experiments for policy makers.
  • Provide evidence on practices that are not
    currently implemented.
  • Emerging practices
  • Practices currently prohibited by laws or
    regulations
  • Practices not implemented due to competition,
    fad, fashion, self selection.

18
E. COSTS OF EXPERIMENTS
  • Abstraction or simplification of the natural
    ecology can affect inferences that are made
  • Experiments are generally bad for testing point
    predictions (but good for testing directional
    predictions).
  • Experiments are generally bad for exploratory
    investigations (lower external validity).
  • Limited ability to collect additional data after
    the experiment.
  • Creating some experimental settings is expensive.

19
F. VALIDITY OF EXPERIMENTAL RESULTS
  • Results of lab experiments and field research in
    organizational psychology have same sign of
    effects but sometimes differences in magnitudes
    of effects
  • participative decision making, goal setting,
    feedback, financial incentives, job performance,
    and job satisfaction.
  • Differences in intra-method results are as large
    as differences in inter-method results.
  • For these variables, the substantive conclusions
    or policy implications based on either research
    method are similar.
  • Locke. 1986. Generalizing From the Laboratory
    to Field Settings.

20
3. IMPORTANT FEATURES OF MA EXPERIMENTS
  • THEORY
  • REALISM
  • CONTEXT
  • PEOPLE
  • INCENTIVES

21
A. THEORY
  • Comparative advantage of experiments is testing
    theories predictions
  • 2 common theoretical perspectives in MA
    experiments
  • Economics theories about domains (tasks,
    contexts) (e.g., production functions, cost
    functions, market structures)
  • Asymmetric information, communication, value of
    information, incentives, learning, market
    structure, risk preferences
  • Psychology theories about individuals in domains
    (preferences, beliefs, ability, effort)
  • Judgment and decision, communication, learning,
    motivation, negotiation, group dynamics

22
ATTRIBUTES OF GOOD THEORY IN EXPERIMENTAL MA
RESEARCH
  • Captures important features of MA and its
    environment. Since MA is context (institution,
    task) specific, it is important to show how MA
    and non-MA are related (interaction).
  • Externally valid the proposed concepts and
    causal relations must be believable and capture
    important features of MA that generalize beyond
    the specific experimental setting.
  • Theory, not data, generalize.
  • Stated as general as possible but still accounts
    for the conceptual relation to be tested.
  • States expected causal relations, usually in
    terms of directional differences, and not point
    predictions, for generalizability.

23
B. REALISM
  • Swieringa and Weick (1982)
  • How realistic should MA experiments be?
  • Realistic enough to test the theory with high
    external and internal validities and high
    research realism (engage and motivate people).
  • How much mundane realism should be included?
  •  
  • Cost of experiments can be their "artificiality"
    because of
  • people surrogation (accountants and managers who
    have
  • no experience with the task in an experiment
    students)
  • task surrogation (abstract, simplified, mundane).

24
HOW MUCH TASK REALISM?
  • Tendency in designing experimental tasks to want
    to make them as real as possible, but unnecessary
    mundane realism creates complexity which can
    reduce internal and statistical- conclusion
    validities.
  •  
  • If want mundane realism, then how decide which
    stimuli in the natural ecology to include?
  • Fly on the wall, water cooler, drapes, picture on
    desk?
  •  
  • Do not include (mundane) realism merely to mimic
    natural environments, but rather because it makes
    the experiment a more valid test of the theory.
  • Internal, external, construct, and
    statistical-conclusion validities.
  •  
  • If a less realistic experimental setting
    increases the validity of the experiment, then be
    less realistic.

25
OPTIMAL LEVEL OF TASK REASLISM DEPENDS ON PURPOSE
OF EXPERIMENT
  • Testing theory artificiality can be beneficial
    as it provides a basis for valid tests of
    hypotheses by controlling for the effects of
    other variables.
  • Experimental psychology typically requires more
    realistic settings because variables in theories
    (e.g., judgment, knowledge, attitude) are related
    to peoples' prior experiences (education,
    training, work).
  • Experimental economics frequently provides less
    realistic settings because its focuses on how
    people make decisions using information and
    incentives given in an experiment.
  •  
  • Testing settings that do not exist in natural
    environments (due to self-selection, competition,
    regulation, law, fad, fashion) research tasks
    will by definition be artificial.

26
REALISTIC or ARTIFICIAL IVs?
  • Realistic or artificial values of the IVs?
  • Realistic values usually are near the mean of an
    IVs distribution and thus they are not likely to
    be sufficiently different from each other to
    observe (measure) their effect.
  • Artificial values (extremes of distribution,
    present/absent) create stronger effects that are
    more detectable.
  •  
  • Realistic or artificial relations between IVs?
  • Realistic relations will frequently have
    significant correlations among the IVs, which
    makes accurately observing the effects of IVs on
    DVs difficult due to multicollinearity.
  • Artificial relations can present participants who
    have knowledge of these relations in natural
    settings with unexpected relations (sign, form,
    magnitude) (i.e., combinations of IVs).

27
C. CONTEXT
  • What is the context of MA (figure-ground)?
  • What are the distinguishing features of MA
    contexts relative to other contexts?
  • How much MA context should be included in an
    experiment?
  • How operationalize MA context?
  • Four context effects (Haynes and Kachelmeier
    1998)

28
1. Information
  • Adding new context (task)-relevant information
  • Adding nonfinancial to financial performance
    measures can affect judgments and decisions.
  • Adding information can adversely affect judgments
    and decisions due to information overload,
    outcome information, and irrelevant or
    nondiagnostic information.
  • Clarifying meaning of a context (task)
  • Using terms like audit and tax can cause people
    to think about the setting differently (ethics,
    feelings about government, public
    responsibility).
  • People are more likely to violate logic in
    abstract contexts. When context is revealed
    (concrete), people with knowledge about the
    context are less likely to make logical errors.

29
2. Salience Influences Attention
  • Focal
  • order of presentation, location in report
  • Unexpected, unusual, surprising, vivid
  • indicating an expense has future-period profit
    effects
  • Context can influence how people allocate their
    limited attention among information
  • planning vs. control, prediction vs. diagnosis,
    explaining your own vs. others performance
  • Salience induced by context of information
  • performance-report design focuses attention on
    particular parts of a report
  • presenting budget variances as well as budget and
    actual focuses attention on the variance even
    though it is not informative

30
3. Context Affects Motivation
  • Context can highlight consequences of behavior.
  • Framing economically-equivalent outcomes as gains
    or losses affects preferences.
  • Choice of economically-equivalent incentive
    contract depends on whether contract outcome is
    framed as a bonus or penalty.
  • Accountability makes people more vigilant,
    effort-intensive in justifying judgments and
    decisions.
  • Including accountability increases peoples'
    attention and effort if the accountability has
    valued consequences for them.

31
4. Context Affects Memory
  • Context can interact with knowledge in
    individual's memories to affect their judgments
    and decisions.
  • People with context experience can activate their
    knowledge as prompted by the context.
  •  
  • Context provides cues as to what knowledge to
    activate.
  •  
  • Memory effects can be
  • positive (e.g., use more relevant knowledge to
    make judgments and decisions) or
  • negative if context activates the wrong knowledge
    (e.g., typical knowledge for an atypical
    situation).

32
ENHANCE CONTEXT WHEN
  • generic language would be confusing or ambiguous
    (information)
  • attention-directing contextual features are of
    theoretical interest (salience)
  • want to study the influence of motives (ethics,
    pubic responsibility) beyond those characterizing
    the economic task (motivation)
  • 4. individuals' knowledge is consistent with a
    richer context (memory)

33
 USE A NEUTRAL CONTEXT WHEN
  • context cues can mislead more than clarify
    (information)
  • theory assumes individuals will give equal
    attention to all information (salience)
  • contextual motives could bias incentives of
    theoretical interest (motivation)
  • 4. individuals' knowledge either is incapable of
    interpreting a richer context or might result in
    interpreting a context in ways that go beyond the
    concept of interest (memory).

34
CONTEXT and M A
  • Include context features that are expected to
    interact with MA variables.
  • Interaction of MA and non-MA context and MA and
    non-MA knowledge affects judgments and decisions.
  •  
  •  
  • If include context, then give reason related to
    theory why it is included and how context is
    expected to affect the IV and DV.
  • Don't add context just to increase mundane
    realism.
  •  
  • If exclude context, then give reason related to
    theory why a richer context would not be
    desirable.

35
D. PEOPLE
  • Single Person
  • Motivation, communication, judgment and decision,
  • learning, performance, adaptation
  •  
  • Multiple Person
  • Hierarchy superior-subordinate communications
    and
  • negotiations
  • Teams cooperation, performance
  • Horizontal negotiations between subunit managers
  • Markets Information exchange (collusion,
    transfer of
  • asymmetric information), learning, market pricing
  • (assets, audits), market structure

36
PEOPLE SURROGATION
  • Are people within boundary conditions of theory?
  • Dont need random sample of people within
    boundary conditions.
  • Need random assignment of people to treatments.
  • What about using students?
  • Some students are investors and some are or have
    been managers or accountants.
  •  
  • A homogeneous sample (e.g., students) can reduce
    error variance, which increases the power of
    statistical tests.
  •  

37
PEOPLE SURROGATION
  • Key is whether people have the ability,
    knowledge, motivation, and preferences to be good
    surrogates for people in the target population
    you want your theory to generalize to.
  •  
  • Using students or other inexperienced/novice
    individuals is appropriate if the purpose of a
    study is to test how
  • people learn and use information presented in a
    study
  • incentives provided in a study affect behavior
    and performance
  • peoples' general cognitive abilities affect their
    behavior
  •  
  • Using students or other inexperienced/novice
    individuals is not appropriate if the purpose of
    a study is to test how
  • people use their task-related knowledge or
    motivation that they brought to the experiment.

38
E. INCENTIVES
  • Provide incentives that will motivate people to
    be involved in the research study, but will not
    bias the results research realism.
  •  
  • If a study uses people to perform research tasks
    that are directly related to their everyday jobs,
    then using incentives can distort or interfere
    with the effects of their real-world incentives.
  • Not providing them with incentives can reduce the
    magnitude of IV effects but not alter the
    direction of effects.
  •  
  • If a study uses people to perform research tasks
    that are not the tasks they do in their everyday
    jobs, then using incentives to motivate them is
    appropriate to increase research realism.

39
INCENTIVES
  • What should be the incentive?
  • Monetary or non-monetary?
  • Fixed or performance contingent?
  • Tournament?
  •  
  • If a study is testing for incentive effects, then
    using incentives consistent with those in the
    theory is appropriate.
  • If using incentives is appropriate, then does the
    theory specify how sensitive they should be to
    performance?
  •  
  • Equal expected pay across treatment levels to
    eliminate the magnitude of incentives as a
    competing explanation for results.
  •  
  • In the U.S., the amount of incentive pay ranges
    from 5 to 100 per hour, with the average being
    about 8 to 20 per hour.

40
4. READING LIST
  • Birnberg, J., M. Shields, and M. Young. 1990. The
    Case for Multiple Methods in Empirical Management
    Accounting Research. Journal of Management
    Accounting Research 33-66.
  • Chow, C. 1982. The Effects of Job Standard
    Tightness and Compensation Scheme on Performance
    An Exploration of Linkages. The Accounting
    Review 667-685.
  • Frederickson, J., S. Peffer, and J. Pratt. 1999.
    Performance Evaluation Judgments Effects of
    Prior Experience Under Different Performance
    Evaluation Schemes and Feedback Frequencies.
    Journal of Accounting Research 151-165.
  • Haynes, C. and S. Kachelmeier. 1998. Effects of
    Accounting Contexts on Accounting Decisions A
    Synthesis of Cognitive and Economic Perspectives
    in Accounting Experimentation. Journal of
    Accounting Literature 97-136.

41
  • Libby, R. R. Bloomfield, and M. Nelson. 2002.
    Experimental Research in Financial Accounting.
    Accounting, Organizations and Society 775-810.
  • Locke, E. (Ed.). 1986. Generalizing from the
    Laboratory to Field Settings. Lexington, MA.
    Lexington Books.
  • Luft, J. and M. Shields. 2001. Why Does Fixation
    Persist? Experimental Evidence on the Judgment
    Performance Effects of Expensing Intangibles. The
    Accounting Review 561-587.
  • Luft, J. 1994. Bonus and Penalty Incentives
    Contracting Choice by Employees. Journal of
    Accounting and Economics 181-206.
  • Luft, J. and M. Shields. 2003. Mapping Management
    Accounting Graphics and Guidelines for
    Theory-Consistent Empirical Research. Accounting,
    Organizations and Society169-249.
  • Schepanski, A., R. Tubbs, and R. Grimland. 1992.
    Issues of Concern Regarding Within- and
    Between-Subject Designs in Behavioral Accounting
    Research. Journal of Accounting
    Literature121-150.

42
  • Sprinkle, G. 2003. Perspectives on Experimental
    Research in Managerial Accounting. Accounting,
    Organizations and Society 287-318.
  • Swieringa, R. and K. Weick, 1982. An Assessment
    of Laboratory Experiments in Accounting. Journal
    of Accounting Research, Supplement 56-107.
  • Young, M. and B. Lewis. 1995. Experimental
    Incentive-Contracting Research in Management
    Accounting. in R. Ashton and A. Ashton (Eds.),
    Judgment and Decision Making Research in
    Accounting and Auditing (Cambridge University
    Press).
  • Vera-Munoz, S. 1998. The Effects of Accounting
    Knowledge and Context on the Omission of
    Opportunity Costs in Resource Allocation
    Decisions. The Accounting Review 47-72.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com