Chapter 23 Competitive Equilibrium - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

Chapter 23 Competitive Equilibrium

Description:

Definition of competitive equilibrium ... After giving a definition of general equilibrium we demonstrate with point wih several examples. ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:103
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 28
Provided by: vesnapra
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Chapter 23 Competitive Equilibrium


1
Chapter 23Competitive Equilibrium
  1. Partial Equilibrium
  2. General Equilibrium
  3. Pareto Optimality

2
Partial Equilibrium
This segment of the course introduces the concept
of competitive equilibrium. First we define
competitive equilibrium, price taking behavior
and market clearing, within a single market, and
compare the predictions of competitive
equilibrium with the solution to a limit order
market. Then we demonstrate with several
examples how competitive equilibrium can be
applied to multiple markets. We discuss why,
under fairly wide ranging conditions, that
competitive equilibrium yields an optimal
allocation of resources, and last, illustrate by
way of examples, the distorting effects of taxes
and subsidies.
3
Definition of competitive equilibrium
  • In microeconomics you learned that a competitive
    equilibrium describing market behavior has two
    defining properties
  • Traders take the price as given. Each trader
    chooses only the quantity he or she wishes to
    trade at that price.
  • Markets clear. There are neither unfilled orders
    by demanders nor unanticipated inventory
    accumulation by suppliers.

4
Partial equilibrium
  • Consider the following market for a stock.
  • There are a finite number of player types, say
    I. Every player belonging to a given player type
    has the same asset and money endowment, and the
    same private valuation.
  • Players belonging to type i are distinguished
    by their initial endowment of money mi and the
    stock si, as well as their private valuation of
    the stock vi. Thus a player type i is defined by
    the triplet (mi, si, vi).

5
Using supply and demand curves to derive
competitive equilibrium
  • To derive the competitive equilibrium, compute
    the demand for the asset minus the supply of the
    asset (both as a function of price), otherwise
    known as the net demand for the asset.
  • This is found by computing the individual net
    demands for the asset, and then aggregating
    across players.
  • The competitive equilibrium price is determined
    by setting the net demand for the asset to zero.

6
Individual optimization in a competitive
equilibrium
  • In a competitive equilibrium with price p the
    objective of player i is to pick the quantity of
    good traded, denoted qi, to maximize the value
    of his or her portfolio subject to constraints
    that prevent short sales (selling more stock than
    the the seller holds) or bankruptcy (not having
    enough liquidity to cover purchases).
  • The value of the portfolio of player i is

7
Constraints in the optimization problem
The short sale constraint is
The solvency constraint is
These constraints can be combined as
8
Solution to the individualsoptimization problem
The solution to this linear problem is to
specialize the stock if vi exceeds p, specialize
in money if p exceeds vi, and choose any feasible
quantity q if vi p. That is
and
9
Market demand
  • Summing across the individual demands of players
    we obtain the demand across players curve D(p).
  • Let 1 . . . be an indicator function, taking a
    value of 1 if the statement inside the
    parentheses is true, and 0 if false. Then, the
    demand from those players who wish to increase
    their holding of the stock is
  • As p falls the number of players with valuations
    exceeding p increases. Thus D(p) declines in
    slanting steps. The top step has height
    maxv1,v2, . . . ,vI and a typical step length
    is mi/p.

10
Market supply
  • Summing over the individual supply of each player
    we obtain the aggregate supply curve S(p), the
    total supply of the asset from those players who
    want to sell their shares, as a function of price
  • Following the same reasoning as on the previous
    slide, the supply curve is actually a step
    function which increases from minv1,v2, . . .
    ,vI, where the steps have variable length of si.

11
Indifferent traders
  • This only leaves stockholders whose valuation vi
    p, who are indifferent about how much they
    trade. They are equally well off selling up to
    their endowment si versus buying up to their
    budget constraint mi/p
  • The next step is to those prices for which there
    is excess supply, which we denote by p. Then we
    derive those prices for which there is excess
    demand, denoted p-.
  • The set of competitive equilibrium are the
    remaining prices.

12
Solving for competitive equilibrium
This only leaves stockholders whose valuation vi
p, who are indifferent about what they trade
The competitive equilibrium price pe is the
unique solution in p found by equating the
difference between demand and supply to the
quantity traded by those who are indifferent
about how much they trade
13
Example
  • To make matters more concrete, suppose there are
    10 players, with private valuations that take on
    the integer values from 1 to 10.
  • Suppose the third player (with valuation 3) is
    endowed with 2 units of the stock, the first and
    second have one unit, and everybody else has 12
    to buy units of the asset.
  • We also assume that everyone has the same access
    to the market, and can place limit or market
    orders.

14
Aggregate supply
  • At prices above 1, the first player will supply
    a unit, at prices above 2 the second player will
    supply a unit, and at prices above 3, the third
    player will supply 2 units.
  • Define q as any (integer) quantity between 0 and
    4, and p as a positive real number, the supply
    function is

15
Aggregate demand
  • If the price p exceeds 5, the players with
    valuations greater than p will demand one unit,
    if p lies between 3.3 and 5, the players with
    valuations above p will demand 2 units each, if p
    is between 2.5 and 3.3 the players with
    valuations above p will demand 4 units each, and
    so on
  • Therefore the demand for the good as a function
    of prices above 2.5 is

16
Competitive equilibrium price
  • In this example, there is a competitive
    equilibrium at any price between 6 and 7.
  • Note that at prices above 7, demand shrinks by
    one unit since only 3 buyers wish to purchase a
    unit, But at any price below 6, five units are
    demanded in aggregate.

17
Competitive equilibrium as a tool for prediction
  • An advantage from assuming that markets are in
    competitive equilibrium is that they are
    relatively straightforward to analyze.
  • For example, deriving the properties of a Nash
    equilibrium solution to a trading game is
    typically more complex than deriving the
    competitive equilibrium for the game.

18
Comparing competitive equilibrium with the
solution to trading games
  • In limit order markets players choose prices and
    quantities, not just quantities.
  • Moreover there is no presumption in limit order
    markets that every trade will take place at the
    same price, whereas in models of competitive
    equilibrium this is a premise.
  • When does competitive equilibrium approximate the
    outcome of the Nash equilibrium solution to a
    trading game?

19
Similarities with competitive equilibrium
  • The trading mechanism we discussed last lecture
    is self financing, and satisfies the
    participation and incentive compatibility
    constraints.
  • If the number of players is odd, the mechanism
    mimics the price and resource allocation of a
    competitive equilibrium!
  • If the number of players is even, this mechanism
    approaches the competitive equilibrium price and
    quantities as the market share of the trades made
    by each player declines.

20
General Equilibrium
The definition of competitive equilibrium we
provided for a single market for a single market
can readily be extended to multiple markets.
After giving a definition of general equilibrium
we demonstrate with point wih several examples.
21
General equilibrium
  • The definition of competitive equilibrium extends
    to multiple markets.
  • Suppose traders live in an economy where there
    are a total of I markets. A competitive
    equilibrium is a price an I-1 dimensional price
    vector, such that when the traders take this
    price vector as given and choose their respective
    allocations to individually maximize their
    objective functions subject to their budget
    constraints that limits their expenditures, all
    markets clear.

22
Production in the goods and services sector
  • Consider an economy where firm owners maximize
    their value by selling a good called housing,
    which is produced using two inputs, wood and,
    clay and labor.
  • The firms adopt the same production technology.
    Denote the output of firm j by yj and the three
    inputs by x1j, x2j and x3j.
  • There is a fixed amount of raw materials
    distributed throughout the population that are
    traded on the three markets.

23
Differential products
  • In the previous examples several suppliers
    competed with each other by selling exactly the
    same product.
  • We now consider how well competitive equilibrium
    predicts outcomes in assignment and matching
    problems, where goods are not perfect substitutes
    for each other.
  • Some examples include the labor market, where
    companies recruit job applicants, professional
    sportsmen with their teams, graduating high
    school students with their teams, and the housing
    market.

24
Valuations
We consider two ways of calculating the value of
the match to the buyer. It is 1. the product
of the indexed values of the market. 2. The
sum of the two markets
25
Pareto Optimality
The final section in this chapter discusses why,
under fairly wide ranging conditions, that
competitive equilibrium yields an optimal
allocation of resources, and concludes by
illustrating the distorting effects of taxes and
subsidies.
26
Optimality of competitive equilibrium
  • The prisoners dilemma illustrates why games
    reach outcomes in which all players are worse off
    than they would be in one of the other outcomes.
  • Notice that in a competitive equilibrium is a
    single the potential trading surplus is used up
    by the traders. It is impossible to make one or
    more players better off without making someone
    else worse off.
  • This important result explains why many
    economists recommend markets as a way of
    allocating resources.

27
Distortions from taxation and regulation
  • The last part of this segment segment analyzes
    the role of the government in affecting market
    outcomes.
  • We focus on one areas of government intervention
    through taxes and subsidies on trade.
  • We modify our previous example of trade. For
    example, how would a sales tax levied on
    consumers affect market supply and demand?
  • What about a production tax levied on suppliers?
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com