Title: Chapter 23 Competitive Equilibrium
1Chapter 23Competitive Equilibrium
- Partial Equilibrium
- General Equilibrium
- Pareto Optimality
2Partial Equilibrium
This segment of the course introduces the concept
of competitive equilibrium. First we define
competitive equilibrium, price taking behavior
and market clearing, within a single market, and
compare the predictions of competitive
equilibrium with the solution to a limit order
market. Then we demonstrate with several
examples how competitive equilibrium can be
applied to multiple markets. We discuss why,
under fairly wide ranging conditions, that
competitive equilibrium yields an optimal
allocation of resources, and last, illustrate by
way of examples, the distorting effects of taxes
and subsidies.
3Definition of competitive equilibrium
- In microeconomics you learned that a competitive
equilibrium describing market behavior has two
defining properties - Traders take the price as given. Each trader
chooses only the quantity he or she wishes to
trade at that price. - Markets clear. There are neither unfilled orders
by demanders nor unanticipated inventory
accumulation by suppliers.
4Partial equilibrium
- Consider the following market for a stock.
- There are a finite number of player types, say
I. Every player belonging to a given player type
has the same asset and money endowment, and the
same private valuation. - Players belonging to type i are distinguished
by their initial endowment of money mi and the
stock si, as well as their private valuation of
the stock vi. Thus a player type i is defined by
the triplet (mi, si, vi).
5Using supply and demand curves to derive
competitive equilibrium
- To derive the competitive equilibrium, compute
the demand for the asset minus the supply of the
asset (both as a function of price), otherwise
known as the net demand for the asset. - This is found by computing the individual net
demands for the asset, and then aggregating
across players. - The competitive equilibrium price is determined
by setting the net demand for the asset to zero.
6Individual optimization in a competitive
equilibrium
- In a competitive equilibrium with price p the
objective of player i is to pick the quantity of
good traded, denoted qi, to maximize the value
of his or her portfolio subject to constraints
that prevent short sales (selling more stock than
the the seller holds) or bankruptcy (not having
enough liquidity to cover purchases). - The value of the portfolio of player i is
7Constraints in the optimization problem
The short sale constraint is
The solvency constraint is
These constraints can be combined as
8Solution to the individualsoptimization problem
The solution to this linear problem is to
specialize the stock if vi exceeds p, specialize
in money if p exceeds vi, and choose any feasible
quantity q if vi p. That is
and
9Market demand
- Summing across the individual demands of players
we obtain the demand across players curve D(p). - Let 1 . . . be an indicator function, taking a
value of 1 if the statement inside the
parentheses is true, and 0 if false. Then, the
demand from those players who wish to increase
their holding of the stock is
- As p falls the number of players with valuations
exceeding p increases. Thus D(p) declines in
slanting steps. The top step has height
maxv1,v2, . . . ,vI and a typical step length
is mi/p.
10Market supply
- Summing over the individual supply of each player
we obtain the aggregate supply curve S(p), the
total supply of the asset from those players who
want to sell their shares, as a function of price
- Following the same reasoning as on the previous
slide, the supply curve is actually a step
function which increases from minv1,v2, . . .
,vI, where the steps have variable length of si.
11Indifferent traders
- This only leaves stockholders whose valuation vi
p, who are indifferent about how much they
trade. They are equally well off selling up to
their endowment si versus buying up to their
budget constraint mi/p
- The next step is to those prices for which there
is excess supply, which we denote by p. Then we
derive those prices for which there is excess
demand, denoted p-. - The set of competitive equilibrium are the
remaining prices.
12Solving for competitive equilibrium
This only leaves stockholders whose valuation vi
p, who are indifferent about what they trade
The competitive equilibrium price pe is the
unique solution in p found by equating the
difference between demand and supply to the
quantity traded by those who are indifferent
about how much they trade
13Example
- To make matters more concrete, suppose there are
10 players, with private valuations that take on
the integer values from 1 to 10. - Suppose the third player (with valuation 3) is
endowed with 2 units of the stock, the first and
second have one unit, and everybody else has 12
to buy units of the asset. - We also assume that everyone has the same access
to the market, and can place limit or market
orders.
14Aggregate supply
- At prices above 1, the first player will supply
a unit, at prices above 2 the second player will
supply a unit, and at prices above 3, the third
player will supply 2 units. - Define q as any (integer) quantity between 0 and
4, and p as a positive real number, the supply
function is
15Aggregate demand
- If the price p exceeds 5, the players with
valuations greater than p will demand one unit,
if p lies between 3.3 and 5, the players with
valuations above p will demand 2 units each, if p
is between 2.5 and 3.3 the players with
valuations above p will demand 4 units each, and
so on - Therefore the demand for the good as a function
of prices above 2.5 is
16Competitive equilibrium price
- In this example, there is a competitive
equilibrium at any price between 6 and 7. - Note that at prices above 7, demand shrinks by
one unit since only 3 buyers wish to purchase a
unit, But at any price below 6, five units are
demanded in aggregate.
17Competitive equilibrium as a tool for prediction
- An advantage from assuming that markets are in
competitive equilibrium is that they are
relatively straightforward to analyze. - For example, deriving the properties of a Nash
equilibrium solution to a trading game is
typically more complex than deriving the
competitive equilibrium for the game. -
18Comparing competitive equilibrium with the
solution to trading games
- In limit order markets players choose prices and
quantities, not just quantities. - Moreover there is no presumption in limit order
markets that every trade will take place at the
same price, whereas in models of competitive
equilibrium this is a premise. - When does competitive equilibrium approximate the
outcome of the Nash equilibrium solution to a
trading game?
19Similarities with competitive equilibrium
- The trading mechanism we discussed last lecture
is self financing, and satisfies the
participation and incentive compatibility
constraints. - If the number of players is odd, the mechanism
mimics the price and resource allocation of a
competitive equilibrium! - If the number of players is even, this mechanism
approaches the competitive equilibrium price and
quantities as the market share of the trades made
by each player declines.
20General Equilibrium
The definition of competitive equilibrium we
provided for a single market for a single market
can readily be extended to multiple markets.
After giving a definition of general equilibrium
we demonstrate with point wih several examples.
21General equilibrium
- The definition of competitive equilibrium extends
to multiple markets. - Suppose traders live in an economy where there
are a total of I markets. A competitive
equilibrium is a price an I-1 dimensional price
vector, such that when the traders take this
price vector as given and choose their respective
allocations to individually maximize their
objective functions subject to their budget
constraints that limits their expenditures, all
markets clear.
22Production in the goods and services sector
- Consider an economy where firm owners maximize
their value by selling a good called housing,
which is produced using two inputs, wood and,
clay and labor. - The firms adopt the same production technology.
Denote the output of firm j by yj and the three
inputs by x1j, x2j and x3j. - There is a fixed amount of raw materials
distributed throughout the population that are
traded on the three markets.
23Differential products
- In the previous examples several suppliers
competed with each other by selling exactly the
same product. - We now consider how well competitive equilibrium
predicts outcomes in assignment and matching
problems, where goods are not perfect substitutes
for each other. - Some examples include the labor market, where
companies recruit job applicants, professional
sportsmen with their teams, graduating high
school students with their teams, and the housing
market. -
24Valuations
We consider two ways of calculating the value of
the match to the buyer. It is 1. the product
of the indexed values of the market. 2. The
sum of the two markets
25Pareto Optimality
The final section in this chapter discusses why,
under fairly wide ranging conditions, that
competitive equilibrium yields an optimal
allocation of resources, and concludes by
illustrating the distorting effects of taxes and
subsidies.
26Optimality of competitive equilibrium
- The prisoners dilemma illustrates why games
reach outcomes in which all players are worse off
than they would be in one of the other outcomes. - Notice that in a competitive equilibrium is a
single the potential trading surplus is used up
by the traders. It is impossible to make one or
more players better off without making someone
else worse off. - This important result explains why many
economists recommend markets as a way of
allocating resources.
27Distortions from taxation and regulation
- The last part of this segment segment analyzes
the role of the government in affecting market
outcomes. - We focus on one areas of government intervention
through taxes and subsidies on trade. - We modify our previous example of trade. For
example, how would a sales tax levied on
consumers affect market supply and demand? - What about a production tax levied on suppliers?