Title: COS 444 Internet Auctions: Theory and Practice
1COS 444 Internet AuctionsTheory and Practice
Spring 2009 Ken Steiglitz
ken_at_cs.princeton.edu
2Bidder collusion
- Of course, in general, bidders want to reduce
competition, the seller wants to increase
competition - Weve seen examples on eBay of hypothetical
implicit bidder collusion (Rasmusen 2006), and
likely seller shill bidding - Collusive bidding may be easier in multi-item
auctions - P. Cramton J.A. Schwartz, Collusive bidding in
the FCC Spectrum Auctions, J. Regulatory
Economics, 1999, describe (highly) probable
collusion in simultaneous ascending price
auctions for FCC licenses (analogous to English
for multiple items).
3- Code bids use the trailing digits of the bid
(often multi-millions of dollars) to tell other
bidders on which licenses to bid or not bid.
Oftentimes, a bidder (the sender) would use these
code bids as retaliation against another bidder
(the receiver) who was bidding on a license
desired by the sender. The sender would raise the
price on some market the receiver wanted, and use
the trailing digits to tell the receiver on which
license to cease bidding.
Cramton Schwartz 1999
4(No Transcript)
5- Here is their disclaimer
- Disclaimer For this analysis, we show that
several bidders apparently used signaling to
coordinate on - license allocations. This apparent signaling
may be coincidental. The claims we make
concerning a - bidders signaling are based on circumstantial
evidence, and though we may attach some meaning
to help - explain certain patterns of bidding, this
meaning should be taken as our hypothesis only.
We make no - claims concerning the actual intent of the
bidders.
Cramton Schwartz 1999
6From
a first-hand account of more explicit collusion
7- Marks Co. were kings of the book ring.
They were one of the five leading firms of
antiquarian booksellers who never bid against
each other in the auction rooms. One member of
the ring would be allowed to buy a book for a
nominal sum, say 100. As soon as the auction was
over the five conspirators would hurry to their
nearest safe-house usually a Lyons tea shop
and conduct a private auction. If one of them
bought the book for 500, the 400 profit would
be divided in cash amongst the other four. This
process was called a knock-out, and Frank Doel
once blew an entire operation.
Between Silk and Cyanide, Leo Marks, Harper
Collins, London, 1998.
nota bene
a post-auction knock-out
8- A famous heart specialist names Evan
Bedford instructed him to bid up to 300 for an
edition of Harveys De Motu Cordis, the earliest
printed book on the circulation of the blood,
which was coming up for auction at Hodgsons. Too
busy with his own Hartley Street salesroom to
attend the auction himself, he telephoned Frank
at home late at night demanding to know why the
book had been sold to another dealer for 200
when hed authorized Frank to bid three. Frank
confided that it had been sold in the knock-out
for 600. The irate physician immediately
undertook to have the whole question of the book
ring raised in the House of Commons, which caused
cardiac arrest amongst its five participants.
Between Silk and Cyanide, Leo Marks, Harper
Collins, London, 1998.
9See Cassady 1967 for lots of details about real
ring operations
- He describes post-auction knockouts, the ring
holds a private sale to liquidate the goods and
divide them among ring members. (p. 180). Notice
that the knock-out is an example where the
utility of a buyer includes some utility of the
seller---since each prospective buyer has a stake
in the sellers revenue. - Organizing a ring is often a very complex
operation. - Mentions that in sale of timber rights by U.S.
govt. collusion is common these sales have
strong common-value features, similar to spectrum
auctions. - Mentions Australian wool trade---the most complex
buyer collusion known to Cassady. (p. 187) One
buyer belonged to thirteen two-member and
thirteen three-member rings.
10Bidder rings (Graham Marshall 1987)
- Stylized facts
- They exist and are stable
- They eliminate competition among ring members
yet ensure ring member with highest value is not
undercut - Benefits shared by ring members
- Have open membership
- Auctioneer responds strategically
- Try to hide their existence
11- Graham Marshalls theoretical model
Second-price pre- auction knockout (PAKT) - IPV, risk neutral
- Value distributions F, common knowledge
- Identity of winner price paid common knowledge
- Membership of ring known only to ring members
12- Pre-auction knock-out (PAKT)
- Appoint ring center, who pays P to each ring
member, P to be determined below - Each ring member submits a sealed bid to the ring
center - Winner is advised to submit her winning bid at
main auction other ring members submit only
meaningless bids - If the winner at the sub-auction (sub-winner)
also wins main auction, she pays
13- If sub-winner wins main auction, she pays
- Main auctioneer P SP at main auction
- Ring center d max P - P , 0 , where P
SP in PAKT - Thus If the sub-winner wins main auction, she
pays in total the SP among all bids (which would
have happened without the ring) - and the profit is passed along to the ring center
14(No Transcript)
15- The quantity d is the amount stolen from the
main auctioneer, the booty - The ring center receives and distributes
- Ed sub-winner wins main auction
- ? so his budget is balanced, in expectation
- Each ring member receives
- P Ed sub-winner wins main auction/K
16Bidder rings
- Graham and Marshall prove
- Truthful bidding in the PAKT, and following the
recommendation of the ring center is a SBNE
weakly dominant strategy (incentive compatible) - Voluntary participation is advantageous
(individually rational) - Efficient (buyer with highest value gets item)
-
- In fact, the whole thing is equivalent
to a Vickrey auction
17Bidder rings
- Main auctioneer responds strategically by
increasing reserves or shill-bidding - Graham Marshall also prove that
- Optimal main reserve is an increasing function of
ring size K - Expected surplus of ring member is a decreasing
function of reserve prices - Expected surplus of ring member is an increasing
function of ring size K - so
best to be secretive
18Bilateral trading mechanismsMyerson
Satterthwaite 83
- An impossibility result
- The following desirable characteristics of
bilateral trade (not an auction) - efficient
- incentive-compatible
- individually rational
- cannot all be achieved simultaneously!
19Bilateral trading mechanisms
- The setup
- one seller, with private value v?1 , distributed
with density f1 gt 0 on a1 , b1 - one buyer, with private value v?2 , distributed
with density f2 gt 0 on a2 , b2 - risk neutral
- Notice not an auction in Riley
Samuelsons class!
20Bilateral trading mechanisms
- Outline of proof We use a direct mechanism (p,
x), where - p (v1 , v2 ) prob. of transfer to
buyer - x (v1 , v2 ) expected payment to
seller
21Bilateral trading mechanisms
- Similarly and symmetrically
22Bilateral trading mechanisms
- Incentive-compatible means
- Individually rational means
- Ex post efficient means
23Bilateral trading mechanisms
- Incentive-compatible means
- Individually rational means
- Ex post efficient means
no incentive to lie about vs
participation does not entail expected loss
object is sold iff buyer values it more highly
24Bilateral trading mechanisms
- Main result If
- then no incentive-compatible individually
rational trading mechanism can be (ex post)
efficient. - Furthermore,
- is the smallest lump-sum subsidy to achieve
efficiency.
25Proof steps
- Part 1 incentive-compatible and individually
rational implies - Part 2 ex post efficient implies
-
contradiction!
min. Eprofit of seller min. Eprofit of buyer
26Bilateral trading mechanisms
- Example Shows
- f i gt 0 is necessary
- discrete probs.
buyer
seller
Only profitable transaction is 1?3
27Bilateral trading mechanisms
- Claim sell at price 2 if both are willing,
else no trade is incentive compatible,
individually rational, and efficient. - Incentive compatible truthful reporting is an
equilibrium (check) - Individually rational Eprofit gt0
- Efficient trade occurs only when v1ltv2
28Auctions vs. Negotiations Bulow Klemperer 96
Simple example IPV, uniform Case 1) Optimal
auction optimal mechanism with one buyer.
Optimal entry value v 1/2 revenue 1/4 Case
2) Two buyers, no reserve revenue 1/3 gt 1/4 ?
One more buyer is worth more than setting reserve
optimally!
29Auctions vs. Negotiations
- Bulow Klemperer 96 generalize to any F,
- any number of bidders
- A no-reserve auction with n 1 bidders
- is more profitable than an optimal (IPV) auction
(and hence optimal mechanism) with n bidders
30Auctions vs. Negotiations
Revenue with optimal reserve, n bidders
Revenue with no reserve, n1 bidders
31Auctions vs. Negotiations
Facts
Why?
Why?
Why?
32Auctions vs. Negotiations
Facts
distribution fctn. of max. of n draws, integrate
only where M 0
distribution fctn. of max. of n1 draws
expected revenue with only one buyer!
33Auctions vs. Negotiations
Now compare revenue in a no-reserve auction with
n1 bidders, and an optimal auction with n
bidders
?
34Rational frenzies and crashes, J. Bulow P.
Klemperer, J. Political Economy, 102, pp. 1-23,
1994.
- Asset markets are volatile! Common wisdom
attributes to irrational behavior, market
imperfections, market failure - This paper offers a model of a simple situation
in which completely rational behavior leads to
frenzies and crashes - Uses IPV auction theory and the RET in a dynamic
setting - An elegant economic idealization makes the point
35The BK 94 game
- K identical units for sale, one seller, KL
risk-neutral potential buyers, each wanting to
buy a single unit - IPVs, drawn from F(v) on 0, vmax
- Buyer derives surplus (v p) from a purchase at
price p
36The simple motivating idea WTP
- Suppose youre in a simple single-item Vickrey
auction with IPVs that are uniform on 0,1, and
you have value v. - You are made a take-it-or-leave-it offer at price
p. Should you accept it?
37The simple motivating idea WTP
- Suppose youre in a simple single-item Vickrey
auction with IPVs that are uniform on 0,1, and
you have value v. - You are made a take-it-or-leave-it offer at price
p. Should you accept it? - Well, if and only if p E(second-price v wins)
- Willingness To Pay
38Dynamics of BK 94 game
- Seller begins offering units at max price vmax
and lowers it until a purchase occurs, at price p - (NEW SALE) When a purchase occurs, every buyer
gets an invitation to purchase 1 unit at price p.
- Either
- (a) (FRENZY) all goods are sold at p ?
game ends - (b) (FRENZY) not all goods are sold at p,
no one is left willing to buy at that price
? then go to 1) and continue lowering price until
another NEW SALE takes place - (c) (EXCESS DEMAND) More buyers want to
buy at price p than there are units remaining.
Then if there are kl bidders offering to buy the
remaining k units, go to 1) and restart the game
with these kl bidders competing for the
remaining k units. All previous sales remain
valid.
39Solution to game
- With k units and (kl) bidders remaining a
symmetric equilibrium strategy is offer to buy
at price p if and only if p ?(v), where
Note that this reduces to Vickrey with one item
and one buyer
40- This follows from a straightforward
generalization of the RET any mechanism selling
K identical items to the bidders with the K
highest values in a unit-demand auction has in
equilibrium the same expected payment conditional
on winning, namely ?(v) (see BK 94). - The interesting dynamics are a consequence of the
shape of ?(v). When k goes down, ?(v) goes up,
and this changes the next threshold drastically
and a bunch of buyers may jump in all at once! -
41Why does ?(v) flatten out dramatically?
42(No Transcript)
43Simulation
K50 , L100
44Term papers due 5pm Tuesday May 12 (Deans Date)
- ? Email me for office hours re term papers
Its been fun!
Neshmet Bark of Osiris, on a bronze drachm of M.
Aurelius, Alexandria, Egypt. E. 2160, 174/5 AD.