Matthew Lebo - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 70
About This Presentation
Title:

Matthew Lebo

Description:

... wait, Democrats and ... is the percentage of the House won by Democrats (differenced by 0.54) ... Democrat Unity -17.21 (1.46) -10.54 (1.57) -21.53 ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:45
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 71
Provided by: gizema
Category:
Tags: lebo | matthew

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Matthew Lebo


1
  • Matthew Lebo
  • Stony Brook University
  • ITV Seminar
  • Ohio State University
  • Friday April 28, 2006

2
Strategic Party Government Party Influence in
Congress 1789-2000
  • Matthew Lebo
  • Stony Brook University
  • Adam J. McGlynn
  • Stony Brook University
  • Gregory Koger
  • University of Montana

3
When are parties in Congress influential?
  • There is a great deal of historical variation in
    the influence of parties.
  • Sometimes parties are weak and seem to fit
    Krehbiels Wheres the Party description.
  • Sometimes they are strong enough to coerce
    members to cast votes that endanger their
    reelection.

4
Why does the influence of Congressional parties
vary?
  • Prevailing answer is Conditional Party Government
    (CPG).
  • Ideology or preferences is the key.
  • A party is strengthened when members ideologies
    become more aligned.
  • Or, when the ideological distance between the
    parties grows.

5
Conditional Party Government
  • Congressional parties should be most influential
    when two internally cohesive parties disagree on
    a wide range of issues.
  • Members will then delegate more authority to
    party leaders.
  • Party influence varies across issues and contexts
    (Froman and Ripley 1965), over time (Cooper and
    Brady 1981), or both (Rohde 1991).

6
WEAK
7
Getting Stronger...
8
Stronger...
9
STRONG
10
STRONGER
WEAKER
11
Some problems with the CPG model
  • What are party labels beyond ideological groups?
  • If this is all there is to parties, would we
    expect parties to mean anything to legislators?
  • What is the interplay between influence and
    elections?
  • Parties do not operate in a vacuum what about
    the competition between the parties?

12
  • Key criticism of CPG by Krehbiel If party
    leaders are only active on a subset of issues
    that already unite party members, what marginal
    effect do they have on policy outcomes?
  • Cox and McCubbins (1993, 2005) stress that
    parties are most interested in electoral victory.
  • Parties work together to enhance their reputation
    and their common label.
  • Strategic Party Government build on both the CPG
    model and the Cox and McCubbins focus on
    elections.

13
Strategic Party Government
  • Actors Legislative Parties
  • Ultimate Goal Maximize seat share
  • Proximate Goal Win important votes.
  • Challenge Choose party strength and effort to
    maximize legislative victories. 
  • But Dont be too strong!

14
  • Parties try to win elections by winning
    legislative contests.
  • This is an assumption we test.
  • Parties that lose votes look bad for several
    reasons.
  • So, to win legislative contests, parties engage
    in multiple activities (e.g. vote-buying, agenda
    shaping)
  • This is the untested assumption of our model.
  • These attempts by parties to increase their
    influence are costly.
  • Why?

15
  • 1. Opportunity cost effort spent to win one
    contest makes winning other contests more
    difficult. Also detracts from other areas of
    legislating and dealing with constituents.
  • 2. As legislators delegate more power to their
    leaders, they lose the ability for
    credit-claiming.

16
  • 3. Most importantly, we should expect that a
    legislators default voting position is in line
    with her constituents. Being pulled away from
    that vote means being pulled away from her
    constituents. Come election time, this could cost
    her reelection.
  • (Carson (2005) for example, finds that increased
    party unity increases the probability that a
    quality challenger will emerge.)

17
Thus, we build upon Conditional Party Government
with
STRATEGIC
Party Government
  • Parties want electoral successes.
  • To do this, they want to win legislative
    contests.
  • But, they must be mindful, coercing stronger
    party unity can pull a legislator from her
    district and can be costly come election time.

18
  • So, parties want to be strong, but not for its
    own sake just strong enough to win.
  • And what determines how strong they need to be to
    win?
  •  
  • The opposition its relative size and strength.

19
What we do
  • Test 2 major aspects of SPG alongside CPG
  • 1. That a (or the) major determinant of party
    influence is the strategic interaction of the two
    major parties over time.
  • 2. That increased party influence can be
    electorally damaging.

20
Hypotheses
  • SPG
  • Party influence will be determined by the level
    of influence of the other party.
  • This is so strong that the two parties level
    of unity will be in a long-run equilibrium.
  • As party size increases, party influence will
    decrease.
  • Winning legislative contests will improve a
    partys electoral fortunes.
  • Increasing party influence will hurt a partys
    electoral fortunes.

21
Hypotheses
  • CPG 
  • Party influence will increase as the two
    parties diverge ideologically.
  • Party influence will increase as a party is
    more ideologically cohesive.

22
How we do it
  • Using Congressional Roll Call and election data
    from 1789-2000.
  • Doing so for both the House and the Senate.
  • Applying dynamic modeling techniques to SPG as
    well as CPG, a dynamic theory that has never been
    tested as such.

23
Key findings
  • Party Unity
  • - is directly linked to winning votes.
  • - varies strongly with opposition unity.
  • - is in a long-term equilibrium relationship
    between the parties (fractionally
    cointegrated)
  • - all the above is true in both chambers and
    when controlling for ideology and issue agenda
    effects.

24
Key findings II
  • Parties gain seats as the percentage of party
    votes they win increases.
  • - House and Senate
  • Parties lose seats as their level of party voting
    unity increases.
  • - House and Senate since the 17th Amendment

25
In sum
  • Influence as a double-edged sword
  •       Winning votes helps electorally but
  •       Party Unity costs seats
  • Central Claim
  •     A both a relative surplus of unity and a
    relative deficit are costly, parties seek to
    match each others effort.
  • Auxiliary Claim
  •       Activity level also varies with party
    size. The larger the party, the easier it is to
    win without effort.

26
Measures
  • Influence Yearly mean of party members unity
    scores the of times they vote with their
    party on party votes.
  • Sources of Unity Preferences, plotting strategy
    together, agenda manipulation, media relations,
    vote-buying/arm-twisting.

27
Two sets of models
  • First, the dependent variable is voting cohesion.
  • Second, the dependent variable is size of
    delegation.

28
(No Transcript)
29
(No Transcript)
30
But wait, Democrats and Republicans in 1789?
  • Democrats are opponents of the Washington
    administration, the (Jeffersonian) Republican
    party, supporters of Andrew Jackson, and members
    labeled Democrat or Independent Democrat,
    using Kenneth Martis (1989) coding.
  • Republicans are supporters of the Washington
    Administration, Federalists, pro-Adams and
    anti-Jackson factions, Whigs, and members labeled
    Republicans and Independent Republicans by
    Martis.

31
CPG Variables
  • Ideological cohesion within parties and
    ideological distance between the parties.
  • DW-NOMINATE scores in two dimensions.
  • The 1st dimension is liberal-conservative which
    covers most votes.
  • The 2nd deals mostly with slavery in the 19th
    century North/South issues generally.
  • Standard deviation of each NOMINATE dimension for
    each party gives us ideological cohesion for
    each.
  • Absolute difference between the scores of the
    median members of each major party gives
    inter-party differences.

32
(No Transcript)
33
Time Series Properties
  • We want to be sure our variables are stationary.
    That is, do they return to a constant mean or do
    they exhibit strong persistence?
  • Good reason to expect that they possess elements
    of both and are fractionally integrated.

34
  • Grangers aggregation theorem
  • Yj,t aj Yj,t-1 et where aj ß(0,1) and ejt
    N(0,s2)
  • At time t each legislative seat j will rely on
    its previous value to a different extent,
    depending upon aj
  • Such a series will be composed of long, but not
    perfect memory.
  • This makes perfect sense for us since the
    dynamics of each seat may be unique.
  • For some seats, the legislator changes. For
    others, behavior may evolve differently over
    time.

35
  • ARFIMA models defined as
  • So, we expect tests of the fractional
    differencing parameter, d, should be between 0
    and 1.
  • We do find this for our unity series as well as
    our ideological series.To avoid threats to
    inference, we need to use fractional differencing
    for all of our variables.
  • That is, difference each by its own value of d
    before estimating our models.

36
  • We do not just want to estimate the coefficient
    between these two.
  • Remember this hypothesis
  • This is so strong that the two parties levels
    of unity will be in a long-run equilibrium.
  • Equilibrium suggests that any random shock that
    separates the series will be short-lived.
  • The series will return to equilibrium through
    error correction.
  • Take Yt a ß Xt et
  • Measure effect of ECMt-1 Yt-1 - a ß Xt-1

37
  • This is how me measure Cointegration two or
    more non-stationary series can be combined to
    create a stationary one.
  • Fractional cointegration relaxes this so that
    cointegration exists if some combination of the
    variables has simply a lower level of
    integration.
  • Cointegration is a useful way to study
    action-reaction relationships.

38
  • So we are interested in whether Republican unity
    will affect Democratic unity contemporaneously
    and whether movements away from each other are
    short-lived due to error correction.
  • Test of Cointegration show that Republican unity
    and Democrat unity are cointegrated in each of
    the House and Senate.
  • Thus, error-correction mechanisms are appropriate
    in the models that follow.
  • Here come the tables

39
Table 1 Strategic Party Voting in the House
1789-2000 ARFIMA Model of Yearly
Data_______ Independent I.V. Differenced
by Coefficient p Variable (1-B)d , d
(s.e.)________________________
Constant 0.585 .223 (0.479) Republic
an Unity 0.78 0.510 .000 (0.062) FECM
0.54 -0.328 .000 (DemUnity
RepUnity)t-1 (0.065) Democratic
Size 0.75 -0.311 .000 (0.086) Democra
tic Majority 1.00 -0.221 .893 (1.650) Id
eological Distance N. 1st 1.10 -2.614 .816
(11.204) Ideological Distance N. 2nd
0.69 -9.909 .978 (4.883) Dem.
Ideological Cohesion 1.12 -32.971 .115 NOMINA
TE 1 (27.443) Dem. Ideological Cohesion
0.86 -37.868 .022 NOMINATE
2 (18.645) Dem. Ideological Cohesion
0.86 -73.187 .000 NOMINATE
2t-1 (16.537) Democrat Unityt-2 0.69 0.166 .
001 (0.054) ________________________
____ Durbin Watson Statistic 1.92 Centered R2
0.47 N209 Significant at .05 level,
Significant at .01 level, Significant at .001
level (all one-tailed tests).
40
Table 2 Strategic Party Voting in the Senate
1789-2000 ARFIMA Model of Yearly
Data_____________ Independent I.V. Differenced
by Coefficient p Variable (1-B)d, d
(s.e.) ________________________ Constant 0.615
.191 (0.469) Republican
Unity 0.70 0.337 .000 (0.056) FECM
0.43 -0.539 .000 (DemUnity
RepUnity)t-1 (0.100) Democratic
Size 0.91 -0.370 .000 (0.083) Democra
tic Majority 1.00 5.715 .000 (1.603)
Ideological Distance N. 1st 0.95 7.058 .185
(7.859) Ideological Distance N. 1stt-2
0.95 20.695 .005 (7.870) Ideological
Distance N. 2nd 0.80 2.246 .300 (4.278)
Dem. Ideological Cohesion 1.12 0.256 .510
NOMINATE 1 (21.211) Dem. Ideological Cohesion
1.12 -54.423 .003 NOMINATE
1t-3 (19.886) Dem. Ideological Cohesion
0.81 -48.456 .000 NOMINATE
2 (12.020) Rep. Ideological Cohesion
0.77 22.732 .013 NOMINATE
2 (10.186) Democrat Unity t-1 0.69 0.148 .042
(0.085) Democrat Unity
t-2 0.69 0.129 .013 (0.057)
Durbin Watson Statistic2.09, Centered R2 0.47,
N208 Significant at .05 level, Significant
at .01 level, Significant at .001 level (all
one-tailed tests).
41
What do they tell us?
  • Relationship between the Parties is the dominant
    explanation for changes in unity over time.
  • What does the ECM tell us?
  • Democratic size is very significant also.
  • CPG variables are OK at times, not great.
  • Any questions at this point?

42
  • So, parties exert more or less influence on their
    members in order to compete with their
    opposition.
  • Why?
  • Because winning votes helps them come election
    time.
  • So why dont they try for perfect unity?
  • Because if would pull legislators away from their
    districts.
  • Really?

43
Table 3 The Electoral Effects of Party Unity and
Party Success on Democratic Chamber Share U.S.
House of Representatives_________________________
__________________________________
  Independent Coefficient (s.e.) p Variable
  Constant -1.992 (1.731) .253   Dem
ocratic Party Unity in Previous
Congress -0.245 (0.110) .014   Democratic Win
Rate in Previous Congress 7.500 (4.176) .038   M
idterm Election with GOP President 9.984 (2.474)
.000   Midterm Election with Dem.
President -5.760 (2.296) .007   Presidential
Election with Democratic Win 5.016 (2.348) .018
  1822 Election -33.425 (8.720) .000
The dependent variable is the percentage of
the House won by Democrats (differenced by
0.54). Significant at .05 level,
Significant at .01 level, Significant at
.001 level (all one-tailed tests).   Durbin
Watson Statistic 1.91 Centered R2 0.35 N104
44
Table 4 The Electoral Effects of Party Unity and
Party Success ARFIMA Models of the U.S.
Senate Independent 1st 66th
Congress Variable Coefficient (s.e.) p_____
  Constant -2.343 (2.708)
.391 Democratic Party Unity 0.011 (0.140)
.935 in Previous Congress  Democratic Win Rate
23.015 (6.680) .001 in Previous
Congress  Midterm Election 5.646 (3.895)
.076 with GOP President  Midterm Election
-5.480 (3.355) .054 with Dem.
President  Presidential Election
5.536 (3.572) .063 with Democratic
Win  Democratic Sizet-3 0.081 (0.121) .502
__________________________________________________
_____________________________   Durbin Watson
Statistic 2.16 Centered R2 0.23 N 62
The dependent variable is the percentage of the
Senate won by Democrats (differenced by 0.78).
Significant at .05 level, Significant at .01
level, Significant at .001 level (all
one-tailed tests).
45
Table 4 The Electoral Effects of Party Unity and
Party Success ARFIMA Models of the U.S.
Senate Independent 67th 106th
Congress Variable Coefficient (s.e.) p_____
  Constant -4.222 (1.591) .012
Democratic Party Unity -0.346 (0.163)
.021 in Previous Congress  Democratic Win
Rate 10.837 (3.897) .004 in Previous
Congress  Midterm Election 8.880 (2.311)
.000 with GOP President  Midterm Election
-8.072 (2.388) .001 with Dem.
President  Presidential Election
9.713 (2.395) .000 with Democratic
Win  Democratic Sizet-3 -0.317 (0.128)
.018 ___________________________________________
____________________________________   Durbin
Watson Statistic 1.81 Centered R2
0.55 N 40 The dependent variable is the
percentage of the Senate won by Democrats
(differenced by 0.78). Significant at .05
level, Significant at .01 level,
Significant at .001 level (all one-tailed tests).
46
Table 4 The Electoral Effects of Party Unity and
Party Success ARFIMA Models of the U.S.
Senate Independent 72nd 106th
Congress Variable Coefficient (s.e.) p_____
  Constant -2.185 (1.928) .267
Democratic Party Unity -0.593 (0.193)
.002 in Previous Congress  Democratic Win
Rate 14.347 (4.284) .001 in Previous
Congress  Midterm Election 6.862 (2.597)
.007 with GOP President  Midterm Election
-8.081 (2.369) .001 with Dem.
President  Presidential Election
7.723 (2.671) .004 with Democratic
Win  Democratic Sizet-3 -0.350 (0.137)
.008 ___________________________________________
____________________________________   Durbin
Watson Statistic 1.90 Centered R2
0.56 N 35 The dependent variable is the
percentage of the Senate won by Democrats
(differenced by 0.78). Significant at .05
level, Significant at .01 level,
Significant at .001 level (all one-tailed tests).
47
Electoral Consequences of Winning Votes
  • In the House For each additional 10 of the
    votes the Democrats win, they will win a 0.75
    greater share (3.4 seats) in the next Congress
    (/- 0.69, plt.05).
  • In the Senate
  • From 1931 to 2000 a 10 increase in the portion
    of party votes won by Democrats is followed by a
    1.43 gain in seat share.
  • In the indirectly elected Senate a 10 increase
    in win rate associated with a 2.3 increase in
    seat share.
  • So, the importance is declining with the
    introduction of the 17th Amendment.

48
Effects of Party Influence
  • House
  • Each additional point of Unity costs the
    Democrats just under 0.25 in their share of the
    House (roughly 1.13 seats out of 435) in the next
    Congress.
  • Senate
  • For the period 1931 to 2000, a 1 increase in
    party unity is associated with a .593 decrease
    in chamber seat share (i.e. .593 seats in a
    100-seat Senate).
  • And of course, party unity helps win legislative
    contests

49
Table 5 Predictors of Democratic Defeats on
Party Votes Pooled Logit Models by Party
Status, House Senate
SENATE HOUSE Independent
Democratic Majority
Democratic Minority
Democratic Majority Democratic
Minority Variable
Coefficient (SE)
Coefficient (SE)
Coefficient (SE) Coefficient (SE)

(z) (z) (z)
(z)
_________ Constant 19.91
(2.37) 12.65 (1.86) 22.29 (3.14)
11.15 (1.59) 8.39 6.79
7.09 7.02 Democrat
Unity -17.21 (1.46) -10.54 (1.57) -21.53 (2.63)
-12.63 (1.46) -11.82
-6.77 -8.18
-8.67 Republican Unity 13.63 (1.30) 14.90
(1.62) 15.36 (1.67) 16.44
(1.97) 10.46 9.19
9.18 8.33 Democratic
Size -0.35 (0.04) -0.29 (0.04) -0.38 (0.05)
-0.24 (0.04) -8.02
-7.84 -7.07 -6.21 Democratic
President -0.97 (0.53) 0.37 (0.43) 0.01
(0.29) -0.71 (0.61)
-1.81 0.86 0.05 -1.16
_______________________________________________
______________________ N 13013 11347 15245 10
198 Prob gt .00 .00 .00 .00 Pseudo
0.72 0.67 0.77 0.67 Log Pseudo-Likelihood -
2315.12 -2069.45 -2213.56 -1926.73  
Significant at .05 level, Significant at .01
level, Significant at .001 level (all
one-tailed tests). Robust standard errors are
clustered by Congress.
50
Conclusions
  • Winning votes helps parties electorally.
  •  
  • But, doing so is costly if it requires parties to
    exert influence.
  •  
  • This keeps parties level of unity in a long-run
    equilibrium.
  • The behavior of the parties is not merely
    conditional on their ideology, it is strategic.

51
Next steps
  •  
  • Move to the individual-level.
  • Midwest 2006 with Jamie Carson and Greg Koger.

52
  • Table 6. House Incumbents Share of the Two-Party
    Vote, 1956-2004
  • 1972-2004
    1956-2004
  • Coefficient Standardized
    Coefficient Standardized
  • (robust s.e.) Coefficient
    (robust s.e.) Coefficient
  • Ideological extremism 0.79 (2.685)
    .015 -1.365 (2.122) -.025
  • District partisanship 0.302(0.061)
    .379 0.435 (0.052)
    .531
  • Quality challenger -3.493(0.535)
    -.160 -5.563 (0.449)
    -.237
  • Spending gap -1.986(0.340) -.396
    --- ---
  • Freshman -0.976 (0.319) -.054
    -1.695(0.317) -.086
  • Presidential approval -.002 (.065)
    -.002 0.004 (0.058)
    .004
  • Midterm election -2.458 (1.351) -.180
    -3.140(1.314)
    -.214
  • In party -2.191 (1.342) -.119
    -2.972(1.153) -.152
  • Party unity -0.103(0.024) -.168
    -0.072(0.024) -.112
  • Constant 55.159(3.511) 50.348(3.036)
  • N 4843 7802

53
Does the nature of the equilibrium relationship
change over time?
  • APSA 2006 with Greg Koger.
  •  
  • ECM model
  •  
  •  
  • Assumption is a constant.
  •  
  • It captures the speed of error correction with a
    single value.

54
But, what if we allow it to vary over time?
  • Adapting the Dynamic Conditional Correlation
    model of Engle (2002) to the ECM case gives us
    Dynamic Error Correction.

55
In RATSStart with tests of d and cointegration
  • House
  • difference hdemco1 / hdemco1d
  • _at_rgser hdemco1d
  • dhat -0.31000 ? 1 0.69
  • dse 0.05893
  • difference hrepco1 / hrepco1d
  • _at_rgser hrepco1d
  •  
  • dhat -0.22000 ? 1 0.78
  • dse 0.05893

56
  • Senate
  • difference demco1 / demco1d
  • _at_rgser demco1d
  •  
  • dhat -0.31000 ? 1 0.69
  • dse 0.05893
  •  
  • difference repco1 / repco1d
  • _at_rgser repco1d
  •  
  • dhat -0.30000 ? 1 0.70
  • dse 0.05893

57
  • House
  • Democratic Unity d 0.69
  • Republican Unity d 0.78
  • Democratic Size d0.75
  • linreg hdemco1 / ecmh
  • constant hrepco1 hdemsize

58
  • Annual Data From 178901 To 200001
  • Variable Coeff Std Error
    T-Stat Signif

  • 1. Constant 43.55239662 4.94289521
    8.81111 0.00000000
  • 2. HREPCO1 0.65426744 0.05861964
    11.16123 0.00000000
  • 3. HDEMSIZE -0.46762610 0.05428008
    -8.61506 0.00000000
  •  
  • difference ecmh / ecmhd
  • _at_rgser ecmhd
  •   gives
  • dhat -0.46000 ? 1 .54

59
  • Senate
  • Democratic Unity d 0.69
  • Republican Unity d 0.70
  • Democratic Size d0.91
  •  
  • linreg demco1 / ecms
  • constant repco1 demsize

60
  • Annual Data From 178901 To 200001
  • Variable Coeff Std Error
    T-Stat Signif

  • 1. Constant 71.22988127 3.55581914
    20.03192 0.00000000
  • 2. REPCO1 0.38390765 0.05286073
    7.26262 0.00000000
  • 3. DEMSIZE -0.67178568 0.04661296
    -14.41199 0.00000000
  •  
  • difference ecms / ecmsd
  • _at_rgser ecmsd
  •  
  • gives
  • dhat -0.57000 ? 1 .43

61
  • So, evidence of cointegration in both the House
    and Senate. Stronger in the Senate.
  •  
  • Next, estimate and then adjust for level of
    fractional integration for each variable in the
    model.
  • Tests of stationarity and estimates of d.

62
Table S1 Yearly Data Descriptive Statistics and
Summary of Stationarity Diagnostic Tests -HOUSE
63
Table S1 Yearly Data Descriptive Statistics and
Summary of Stationarity Diagnostic Tests -SENATE
64
Table S2 Estimates of d obtained from (0,d,0)
models - HOUSE
65
Table S2 Estimates of d obtained from (0,d,0)
models - SENATE
66
In RATS
  • The RGSER procedure estimates Robinsons d.
  • And, the FIF procedure fractionally differences
    the variable.
  • For example
  • difference HMEDMEDN2 / HMEDMEDN2d
  • _at_rgser HMEDMEDN2d
  • dhat -0.31000
  • dse 0.05893
  • _at_fif(d-.31) hmedmedn2d / hmedmedn2df
  • This gives us a variable that is
    level-stationary and can be included safely in
    our models.

67
This is done for all of our variablesIn the
House
  • _at_fif(d-.31) hdemco1d / hdemco1df
  • _at_fif(d-.22) hrepco1d / hrepco1df
  • _at_fif(d-.25) hdemsized / hdemsizedf
  • _at_fif(d.12) hdemsn1sd / hdemsn1sdf
  • _at_fif(d-.04) hdemsn1md / hdemsn1mdf
  • _at_fif(d-.14) hdemsn2sd / hdemsn2sdf
  • _at_fif(d-.22) hdemsn2md / hdemsn2mdf
  • _at_fif(d-.09) hrepsn1sd / hrepsn1sdf
  • _at_fif(d.21) hrepsn1md / hrepsn1mdf
  • _at_fif(d-.17) hrepsn2sd / hrepsn2sdf
  • _at_fif(d.00) hrepsn2md / hrepsn2mdf
  • _at_fif(d.1) hmedmedn1d / hmedmedn1df
  • _at_fif(d-.31) hmedmedn2d / hmedmedn2df

68
Including the ECM
  • The ECM is not level stationary and including it
    is problematic.
  • So, fractionally difference it to create an FECM.
  • linreg hdemco1 / hecm
  • constant hrepco1 hdemsize
  • difference hecm / hecmd
  • _at_rgser hecmd
  • _at_fif(d-.46) hecmd / hecmdf

69
PARTY UNITY MODEL IN THE SENATE Complete
Model linreg demco1df / res constant
demco1df1 demco1df2 repco1df ecmdf1
demsizedf demmajd medmedn1df,
medmedn1df2 medmedn2df demsn1sdf
demsn1sdf3 demsn2sdf repsn2sdf   Linear
Regression - Estimation by Least
Squares Dependent Variable DEMCO1DF Annual Data
From 179301 To 200001 Usable Observations
208 Degrees of Freedom 194 Centered R2
0.470697 R Bar 2 0.435228 Uncentered
R2 0.472670 T x R2 98.315 Mean of
Dependent Variable 0.5266076200 Std Error of
Dependent Variable 8.6295549872 Standard Error of
Estimate 6.4852247086 Sum of Squared
Residuals 8159.2790671 Regression
F(13,194) 13.2707 Significance
Level of F 0.00000000 Log Likelihood
-676.75401 Durbin-Watson
Statistic 2.089672   Variable
Coeff Std Error T-Stat
Signif
1.
Constant 0.61470113
0.46867125 1.31158 0.19121102 2.
DEMCO1DF1 0.14802383
0.08531191 1.73509 0.08431297 3.
DEMCO1DF2 0.12920104
0.05742509 2.24991 0.02557796 4. REPCO1DF
0.33742456 0.05642845
5.97969 0.00000001 5. ECMDF1
-0.53858521 0.09978027 -5.39771
0.00000020 6. DEMSIZEDF
-0.37038971 0.08324465 -4.44941
0.00001449 7. DEMMAJD
5.71546419 1.60297959 3.56553
0.00045729 8. MEDMEDN1DF
7.05784119 7.85931291 0.89802
0.37028662 9. MEDMEDN1DF2
20.69453654 7.86994256 2.62957
0.00923499 10. MEDMEDN2DF
2.24612639 4.27792438 0.52505
0.60014759 11. DEMSN1SDF
0.25611600 21.21053778 0.01207
0.99037823 12. DEMSN1SDF3
-54.42325306 19.88575690 -2.73680
0.00678047 13. DEMSN2SDF
-48.45603348 12.02019459 -4.03122
0.00007968 14. REPSN2SDF
22.73236731 10.18608517 2.23171
0.02677857 ---------------------------------------
-------------------------------
70
Table 3 SUR ARFIMA Models of Agenda Hypothesis
Yearly Data in the House Senate 1789-2000
Independent House Model Senate
Model Variable Coefficient p Coefficient
p Constant 0.657 .159 0.648
.151 Republican Unity 0.447 .000 0.314
.000 (DemUnity RepUnity)t-1
(ECM) -0.332 .000 -0.517 .000 Democra
tic Size -0.312 .000 -0.373
.000 Democratic Majority -1.02 .505 3.862
.004 Ideological Distance N. 1st -4.381
.675 8.049 .136 Ideological Distance N. 1st
t-2 -- -- 23.71 .000 Ideological
Distance N. 2nd -7.472 .097 1.75 .326 Dem.
Ideological Cohesion NOMINATE 1 -41.441
.053 -1.147 .476 Dem. Ideological Cohesion
NOMINATE 1 t-3 -- -- -33.604
.031 Dem. Ideological Cohesion NOMINATE
2 -30.452 .039 -46.29 .000 Dem.
Ideological Cohesion NOMINATE 2t-1 -71.420 .000
-- -- Rep. Ideological Cohesion
NOMINATE 2 -- -- 20.60 .026 Democrat
Unityt-1 -- -- 0.126 .104 Democrat
Unityt-2 0.142 .005 0.078 .140
________________________________________________
__________________________________________________
_
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com