Title: Guest Lecture 5 Health
1Guest Lecture 5Health
- Introductory Economics for the Treasury
- Dr. Paul Frijters
- http//econrsss.anu.edu.au/frijters
2Contents
- 1. Basic terms in health.
- 2. Some basic stats and basic issues.
- 3. Market failures in health and broad policy
options.
3Basic terms
- 1. Health care inputs. Self-evident.
- 2. Health care outputs. The direct results of the
inputs, i.e. hospital services, nursing homes,
etc. - 3. Health outcomes. The eventual result of health
inputs, i.e. increased longevity of life and
higher quality of life (Qaly quality-adjusted-lif
e-years).
4.
- 4. Supplier induced demand. The phenomenon that a
higher supply leads to a higher demand. Example
you will get deferred to an eye specialist if and
only if there is one. Without the supply of one,
there is less demand (at the same price) for one. - Underlying reason information asymmetry.
Revisited later.
5.
- 5. Community rating. The principle that private
health insurers cannot base their products on
detailed individual information, but can only
ascertain some general community
characteristics.
6Some basic statistics .
7Health Expenditure
8Money and outcomes .
9Money sources and destination
10Australian Statistics
11Obesity explosion in Australia?
12Basic issues in health
- 1. Rapidly growing health care expenditure in the
whole of the OECD. - 2. Little improvement in terms of longevity in
the last decade. - 3. Many attempts at health care reform in many
different countries.
13Underlying reasons
- For exploding health costs
- - Ageing populations in the OECD due to declining
fertility. - - Medical advancements meaning an expansion of
health goods.
14health costs continued.
- - Increasing incomes in combination with health
being a luxury good (a good whose demand
increases with income). - - Supply-induced demand.
- - Increased legal costs connected to an
increasing fallacy of control (the myth that
risk-free medical service delivery is possible).
15Underlying reasons
- For low longevity return
- - Most services that have high medical pay-offs
have already been implemented (e.g. vaccinations,
clean water supply, car safety belts). - - Many new medical advances target the ills of
old people for whom the benefit in terms of
longevity is small after being saved from X they
often die quickly of something else. - Note a large slice of the increasing health
costs are indeed spent on those very close to
death.
16Underlying reasons
- For the attempts at health care reform
- The spiraling costs.
17Market failures in health
- 0. Large externalities of own health condition on
others. - 1a. People are not capable of assessing their own
health asymmetric information. - 1b. Patients cannot ascertain the quality and
true price of offered products asymmetric
information. - 2. Medical insurers have less information about
the health status of people than themselves
adverse selection and moral hazard. - 3. Increasing returns in collection of health
insurance fees. - 4. Local monopolies in health providers.
180. large externalities of own health
- - individuals will underinvest in preventing own
sickness. - - no private provision of goods with large public
benefits, such as vaccinations, smoking-free
zones. - - overuse of goods with public negative effects.
E.g. overuse of anti-biotics.
19Policy options
- - forced public vaccinations. Various options
refusal of non-vaccinated children at school
refusal of employees or migrants without
vaccinations jail terms for refusal to
vaccinate, etc. - - public provision or organisation of smoking
free zones. - - coordinated limitation of goods with negative
effects.
201. Asymmetric information
- - individuals have no idea how sick they are or
how good the service provider is. - - They will thus either have to use
intermediaries for the missing information or be
lead into excessive demand for services by
materially motivated suppliers.
21Policy response
- - State production of medical monitoring of
patients. This relies on an esprit the corps
amongst the medical assessors (GPs). - Note asymmetric information naturally leads to
widespread use of medical intermediaries. These
are known here as GPs. The question is what their
incentives are for referrals, prescriptions, etc.
22Policy response
- - Increase public availability of medical
information. Means accreditation of medical
services public supply of information about
diseases, medicine, medical services, etc.. - - Increase the possibility and incentive for
self-treatment. - - Use state monopsony power to buy medicine from
private suppliers.
232. Adverse selection in insurance
- - Community rating outlaws the use of individual
information and increases adverse selection. - - the highest risk people will self-select into
insurance. The lowest risk people will not insure
themselves. - Note the fact that private insurance firms will
not ensure the poor is not a market failure. To
ensure the poor is an equity issue, addressed by
private and/or public charity.
242. moral hazard in insurance
- - individuals will not take into account the full
price of activities that are dangerous to their
own health. - - insured individuals face low (or even zero)
costs of using medical services. This makes
medical services a common good (rival but
non-excludable), with a tragedy of the commons as
a result overuse and rationing (waiting lists).
25Moral Hazard and Health Insurance extended
- In terms of the consumer there are two types of
moral hazard relevant to health insurance - - The individual may influence the probability
of falling ill through prevention, which may
amount to a general change in lifestyle - - In the event of illness, the associated
financial loss (cost of treatment) is not
necessarily fixed, since a choice between cheaper
and more expensive treatment may be available
26Empirical Evidence on Moral Hazard
- The most convincing evidence on the effect of
insurance on the demand for health care has come
from the Health Insurance Experiment (HIE)
conducted by the RAND Corporation in the US
(Newhouse, 1974, Manning et al., 1987). - Household were randomly assigned to health care
plans - ranging by the amount of co-payment paid
27(No Transcript)
28Main Conclusions from the study
- Per-capita total expenses on the free health care
plan were 45 higher than those on the plan with
a 95 coinsurance rate. - Outpatient expenses in the free plan were 67
higher than those on the 95 coinsurance plan,
while outpatient visit rates were 63 higher. - The price elasticity for all health care was
found to be between 0.1 and 0.2, that is, a 10
increase in user price will cause demand to fall
by 1 to 2 per cent.
29Australian Evidence on Moral Hazard
- Savage and Wright (2003, J. Health Economics)
- Moral hazard and adverse selection in
Australian private hospitals 1989-1990 - Study used survey data for around 23,000
households taken from the 1989-1990 National
Health Survey (NHS) - Estimated the effect of having private health
insurance on length of hospital stay
30(No Transcript)
31Policy response to asymmetric inform.
- - Have a state health insurance system for all.
This forces individuals to take up insurance, and
hence implicitly means the low-risk people
subsidise the high-risk ones. This also addresses
the provision-to-the-poor-issue. - - Allow individual information to be used by
private health insurers. - - Introduce costs of health services to the user
own-risk clauses in private insurance own
contribution costs for medicine.
323. Increasing returns to health fee collection
- - this increases the case for having a monopolist
in health fee collection.
334. Local monopolies in health
- - Local GPs are sometimes the sole intermediary
for a geographic district. Especially in remote
areas. - - Local hospitals are the sole service provider
of some services (e.g. emergencies) and are
sometimes the only providers of all services
(remote areas). - - Local nursing\retirement homes are often the
sole providers in the area.
34Policy response
- - State provision of some medical services,
relying on an esprit the sorps and benevolence
(even if you base public sector careers on
outcomes, the person monitoring or setting the
rules must be benevolent). - - Enforce standard service provision and pricing
across service providers. Very difficult to do
because output is hard to measure and both
patients and medical labour are very different
from region to region and organisation to
organisation. - - Create monopsony power on the demand side
(patient unions or, equivalently, health
authorities).
35Important caveat
- For any form of competition to work, information
about the performance of various service
providers would have to be collected and
disseminated. - Although in some countries some information is
collected, virtually everywhere it is kept secret
by the state for fear of public response. - Hence, as a second best option, the enforcement
of standard working practices seems likely to
occur.
36Other policy options to reduce costs
- 1. Change legal liability in healthcare.
- - Limits on the amount that can awarded
(implemented in many countries). - - Transfer of responsibility to the buyer
(reassertion of the caveat emptor rule).
Equivalent to the introduction of honest
mistake principles. - - Penalties for unsuccessful claims (e.g. the
English system of loser-pays-all).
37.
- 2. Cease state insurance of medical procedures
that have too high cost per Qaly. Equivalent
formulation basic insurance packages. - - This happens increasingly in many countries.
- - Politicians often leave the actual choice up to
practitioners for fear of public ridicule of
explicit choices. - Note the rich will then be relatively healthier.
38.
- 3. Effective competition between medical service
providers. - - very difficult because medical providers are
usually local monopolies. - - buying health care services from abroad or
other regions (thus expanding the set of
suppliers) is often politically opposed. - - medical output is very difficult and expensive
to measure (information is a pre-requisite for
markets) ultimately, you rely on the provider to
tell you how he or she performed.
39.
- 4. Restrict the market supply of medical health
services. - - (in Australia and elsewhere) limit the number
of places to learn medicine. Result overpricing
of those services and rationing of training
places. - Note limiting the supply of services without
also controlling the price may not actually
reduce the costs of health to consumers, but
effectively means the state guarantees a cartel
(a monopoly consisting of many coordinating
providers). The recent enforcement of quotas in
universities guarantees the Australian medical
cartel for years to come.
40Conclusion
- 1. The health issue suffers from multiple market
failures at the same time. Its also politically
very sensitive. Nowhere in the OECD is the health
market hence a free market. - 2. Despite many attempts at increasing the use of
market forces, there is not much evidence that
the bang for the buck has been improved
anywhere (the most free market, i.e. the US, is
also the most expensive one without any
noticeable health improvement).
41Continued
- 3. A lot of recent health issues impinge on
personal choices (i.e. declining rates of
physical activity, increased obesity rates, bad
diet choices). Politicians are loathe to truly
interfere with these choices in an obvious way,
i.e. no fat tax, compulsory school and work
exercise, etc. As a result the policy reaction
to these emerging issues has been to largely
ignore them.
42A specific Australian issue
- The tax incentives for private health insurance.
- In 1999, a subsidy was introduced whereby the
government gave a tax credit of 30 towards the
costs of private insurance to users. - The costs of this scheme are close to 3 billion
AUS.
43Incentive effects
- 1. Individuals do not bear the full costs of
purchasing some health goods. Effect they will
use the subsidy to purchase consumer goods that
are only vaguely related to health. This indeed
seems to have happened according to Abelson
(2003, pg. 307 running shoes and gym
membership). - 2. Self-insurance (i.e. having no health
insurance, but simply paying medical services as
need arises) becomes less attractive private
insurance for basic health goods should indeed
increase. Abelson (2003) claims this has not
happened for basic health services.