Title: Facult des sciences de lagriculture
1Keep it Down An Experimental Test of the
Truncated Uniform Price Auction
- Faculté des sciences de lagriculture
- et de lalimentation
- Université Laval
Maurice Doyon Daniel Rondeau Richard Mbala
2009 NAREA Workshop on Experimental Methods in
Environmental, Natural Resource, and Agricultural
Economics
2Outline
- Context
- Research objectives
- The truncated uniform price auction
- Experimental design
- Results
- Closing remarks
3Context
- Since 1972, Canadian egg producers are required
by law to hold a production permit (quota) for
the laying hens they own. - Supply control generates oligopoly rents and
makes individual transferable quota highly
valuable. - In the egg industry (as in other agricultural
quota markets such as milk and chicken),
prevailing conditions tend to provide sellers
with a distinct advantage and tend to yield high
quota prices.
4Context
- High quota prices are a concern for Quebecs egg
producers for two central reasons. - Large sums of money are capitalized into this
non-productive asset (Boots et al 1997, Alvarez
et al 2006). - Detrimental to a renewal of the industry, making
it difficult for young individuals to become
producers. - No official market exist for laying hens and a
few feed suppliers have become de facto quota
brokers - Feed suppliers have an informational advantage
and purchase much of the available quota and tie
its resale to exclusive long terms input
contracts
5Context
- It is within this context that the Quebec
Federation of Egg Producers decided to create a
centralized market institution for quota trading.
- The objective of the Federation is to implement a
market mechanism that fosters efficient trading
of a relatively low volume of units and provides
the strongest possible protection against
aggressive oligopoly pricing emerging from a
small number of sellers when demand substantially
outstrips supply.
6Objectives
- Doyon and Rondeau (2006) explored various market
designs that could potentially meet the
prerogatives of Quebec egg producers. - They concluded that a truncated Uniform Price
Auction (UPA) has interesting characteristics
that should be tested. - Therefore, the objective of this study is to test
the effect of the truncation rule on market
price, buyers and sellers bids, the number of
unit traded and economic efficiency
7Truncation rule
- Uniform price auctions are efficient since they
ensure that buyers with the highest subjective
valuations for goods obtain those goods and, in
exchange, sellers receive returns that
approximate the totality of this value (Ausubel
and Cramton 2002, Khrisna 2002). - Any intervention aimed at modifying the outcome
of a uniform price auction is likely to reduce
the efficiency of that auction - Doyon et al. (2008) have explored modifying a
UPA with a tax on units offered but not sold and
excluding highest bidders and offers from the bid
and asks schedules. Experimental results indicate
that they achieved little price reduction at the
expense of important loss of efficiency
8Truncation rule
- Under the T-UPA, both buyers and sellers are
invited to submit bids and asks consisting of the
number of units they wish to buy or sell, and the
price at which they are prepared to buy or sell
respectively. - While multiple units are involved, a restriction
is imposed that participants can only submit a
single bid or ask - The intersection of the bid and ask curves
determines the quantity that will be supplied to
the market. In standard UPA, the units to be sold
are those starting with the lowest asking price
on the supply curve, moving sequentially up to
the intersection of the bid and ask functions.
This rule is not changed in presence of the
truncation rule.
9Truncation rule
- Whereas a standard UPA simply allocates the units
in decreasing order of bid price, the T-UPA
favors bidders on extra-marginal units. - Bidders are declared eligible to purchase some of
the traded units as long as their bid price is
equal or greater than the price asked by the
seller of the last unit (the unit at the
intersection of the bid and ask curves). - In a reversal of normal rules, the units are sold
in priority to bidders who submitted the lowest
price bids rather than the highest
10Truncation rule
G
11Experimental design
- Two sets of experiments were conducted to compare
the impact of the T-UPA against the UPA. In all
cases, the underlying design and parameters were
identical across all experiments. - In all sessions, the market was made up of seven
buyers and five sellers who kept the same role
for a total of thirty periods of market
interaction with each other. - Subject could visually determine that there were
twelve participants in the market, but were not
told how many were buyers and sellers - All information on quantities and reserve prices
(induced values) was private and confidential
12Experimental design
- The subjects task in each round was to submit a
bid or ask containing two piece of information
1) the number of units offered (seller) or sought
(buyer) and 2) the price they were prepared to
transact at. - At the end of each period, each individual
privately received their personal results in the
form of the number of units he/she transacted,
the market clearing price and their personal
profits. - The first six periods of this experiment were
unpaid practice rounds. Each of these periods
implemented different vectors of market
parameters (individual quantities and reserve
prices), allowing participants to familiarize
themselves with their task, the operations of the
computer interface and the impact of their
decisions
13Experimental design
- The experiment then proceeded with three sets of
eight periods each, generating real earnings.
During each set, the same overall vector of
market parameters were kept, but rotated across
participants with each new period.
14Experimental design
15Experimental design
- The experiments were implemented using z-tree and
conducted at the CIRANO laboratory for
experimental economics in Montreal, Canada. - Subjects were university students from all
disciplines recruited via email invitations using
the laboratorys standing list of student
volunteers. - Individuals were randomly assigned to their role
of buyer or seller. They received oral
explanations and instructions. - Sessions lasted approximately 90 minutes and
participants received between 18 and 50,
(including a 5 show up fee).
16Results
17Results-Transaction Prices
- Result 1 The uniform transaction price under the
T-UPA allocation rule is significantly lower than
under the UPA rule.
18Results-Number of Units Traded
- Result 2 The T-UPA results in a smaller number
of units traded than the UPA allocation rule
19Results-Market Efficiency
- Result 3 For the experimental conditions
implemented in this study, the T-UPA captures 15
points of percentage less of the potential gains
from trade than the UPA
20Results-Market Efficiency
- Two factors contribute to the loss of efficiency.
- First, is the loss associated with a sub-optimal
number of units traded already noted - Second, the misallocation of units to
extra-marginal buyers and sellers. - Result 4 Units defined as extra-marginal based
on the underlying distributions of reserve prices
are more likely to be traded in the T-UPA auction
and contribute significantly to lowering the
efficiency of the market rule.
21Results-Market Efficiency
- For the regular UPA, and across all markets in
the dataset, only 1.05 of the 5,507 units
exchanged in our experiments were extra-marginal
on the demand side. - In contrast, this proportion climbs to 10.3 of
the 5,542 units traded in the T-UPA. - This confirms that the T-UPA rule provides
significant opportunities for less efficient
buyers to purchase units
22Results-Buyer Behavior
- Result 5 Buyers submit significantly lower bids
in the T-UPA than in the UPA
23Results-Seller Behavior
24Results-Seller Behavior
- the T-UPA produced much less volatility in Model
B and substantially reduced average sellers bids
to reach 174, a value in line with the other
Models.
25Closing remarks
- The truncated rule significantly reduces market
clearing price. It does so by significantly
reducing buyers bids and by reducing the asking
price of sellers in extreme market conditions,
when sellers have shown an ability to exercise
market power in a standard uniform price auction.
- In situation of large excess demand and wide
difference between the reserve prices of the
marginal buyer and seller, the truncated rule was
able to dramatically reduce the ability of
sellers to push the equilibrium price up. - This is an important finding since this type of
conditions underlying thin markets such as quota
market in agricultural sectors or in other sector
could benefit from this type of market design.
26Closing remarks
- However, reduction in market clearing price and
the ability to mitigate market power of sellers
in certain market conditions come to a cost. - This cost is a drop in the number of units
transacted and an undesirable allocation of some
units to buyers who value them less than some
excluded participants. These combined effects
result in a loss of efficiency in the order of
15 in average in our experiment.
27Closing remarks
- Nevertheless, these results compare
advantageously with the modifications to the
uniform price auction market tested by Doyon et
al (2008). - To reach a mere 5 reduction in market clearing
price, 50 of the unit traded and 52 point
percentage in efficiency were sacrificed. - In Model B, a 51 reduction over the non
competitive market price is obtained in exchange
of a loss 4 in the number of unit traded and an
efficiency loss of 19 points percentage.
28Closing remarks
- These differences could be explained by the
flexibility of the truncated rule, as opposed to
an exclusion rule as tested by Doyon et al
(2008). - While the exclusion would be fixed and would
always be blindly applied, the truncation rule
does not apply in the absence of excess demand
and its effect is modulated with the level of
excess demand.
29Closing remarks
- Nevertheless, efficiency losses are significant.
- Impact on long term competitivity of the Quebec
egg production sector? - However, it represents a sizeable improvement
over current practices, where a large portion of
the gains from trade are likely captured by feed
suppliers - Efficiency loss should be seriously considered
and weighted against the perceived benefits of
lower market prices before implementing a
truncated uniform price auction in the field. - First real auction, based on our design was
realized June 1st
30Questions ?
Maurice Doyon Professor Department of
Agricultural Economics and Consumer Science Laval
University Email maurice.doyon_at_eac.ulaval.ca