Title: Uninsured money funds can also hedge such risks. ... A
1Deposit Insurance, Bank Regulation, and Financial
System Risks
by George Pennacchi Department of
Finance University of Illinois
FDIC - JFSR Conference on Emerging Risks in
Banking and Financial Services, September 22-23
2005
2Summary of the Paper
- The paper has three main parts
- Empirical evidence is presented that FDIC
insurance is necessary for banks to hedge
liquidity shocks. Uninsured money funds can also
hedge such risks. - Under-priced deposit insurance has led to
excessive expansion of the safety net. Reforms
that set insurance premiums to be actuarially
fair would create incentives for banks to take
excessive systematic risks. - An alternative insurance plan may preserve the
ability to hedge liquidity shocks but mitigate
the incentive for systematic risks.
3Prior Research on Banks and Liquidity Risks
- Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein (2002) note that
(demand) deposits and loan commitments are
similar cash-management services. - Providing them together conserves liquid assets
needed to support both transactions. This
synergy is greatest if deposit inflows tend to
coincide with commitment draw-downs. - Gatev and Strahan (2005) (GS) present empirical
evidence that during 1988 - 2002, banks
experienced deposit inflows and increased loans
at times of liquidity shocks as proxied by the
commercial paper - Treasury bill spread. - Similarly, Gatev, Schuermann, and Strahan (2005)
show that during the 1998 liquidity crisis, banks
with the most loan commitments experienced the
greatest deposit inflows.
4Hedging Liquidity and Deposit Insurance
- Is this beneficial correlation between loans and
deposit flows an inherent feature of banks or is
it due to deposit insurance? - Similar to GS (2005), I estimate vector
auto-regressions (VARs) to test whether an
innovation to the commercial paper spread Granger
- causes growth in various bank assets and
deposits. - In addition to replicating tests during the
recent period of 1988 to 2004, I also estimate
VARs using banking and market interest rate data
from the NBER Macro-History Database for the
pre-FDIC period of 1920 to 1933.
5(No Transcript)
6(No Transcript)
7Deposit Insurance is Critical for Bank Hedging
- This evidence is consistent with deposit
insurance being vital to banks ability to hedge
liquidity risks. Today, investors view (de
facto) insured deposits as a safe haven during
flights to quality. - Prior to 1933, banks feared deposit withdrawals
and held 99 of all commercial paper to meet
deposit outflows. - Unlike today, prior to the FDIC it was rare for
banks to offer formal loan commitments. - Is there another financial intermediary that can
hedge liquidity shocks? I re-run VARs but use
the growth rate of money market mutual fund
(mmmf) shares as the dependent variable.
8(No Transcript)
9MMMFs Also Experience Inflows Following Liquidity
Shocks
- Investors view mmmfs (especially institutional
ones) as safe havens following market-wide
liquidity shocks. - Indeed, mmmfs may be a primary conduit that
purchases banks large time deposits (CDs)
following liquidity shocks. - Investor confidence in mmmfs is consistent with
Gorton and Pennacchi (1993) who find that mmmf
shares do not decline following defaults on
individual firms commercial paper.
10Governments Have Difficulty Pricing Insurance
- Stiglitz (1993) argues that a government deposit
insurer faces political constraints that limit
its ability to charge market-based deposit
insurance premiums - The difficulties government has in assessing
risk, and that citizens face in evaluating the
governments performance on this score, provide
an opportunity for granting huge hidden
subsidies. - Since 1996, over 90 of all banks have paid
nothing for deposit insurance, undoubtedly
representing a huge subsidy.
11Free Lunches
- Recent examples of excessive expansion of the
safety net - Promontory Interfinancials CDARS network allows
banks to swap lt 100,000 chunks of large CDs to
skirt the 100,000 FDIC limit, allowing insurance
for a 20 million deposit. - The 1999 GLB Act allowed brokerage firms to
affiliate with insured banks and convert
customers sweep accounts from mmmfs into
FDIC-insured deposits. - Crane and Krasner (2004) estimate that 350
billion is in FDIC-insured deposits that would
have been in retail mmmfs. A shift of 50 to 100
billion per year is forecast for 2005 and 2006. - From 2000-2005, MMDAs grew at a 16.4 annual
rate while shares of retail mmmfs declined at a
3.0 annual rate.
12Actuarially Fair Premiums to the Rescue?
- Most FDIC (2000, 2001) proposals to reform
insurance pricing and Basel II capital
requirements fail to distinguish between
systematic versus idiosyncratic risks. - But deposit insurance is inherently systematic
bank failures tend to be greater during business
cycle downturns. - The model in Kupiec (2004) shows that Basel II
provides incentives for banks to take excessive
systematic risks. - I use a similar model to show that if insurance
premiums equal expected losses (actuarially
fair), then banks continue to have incentives to
take excessive systematic risks.
13Subsidizing Financial Instability
- Operationally, a bank can identify procyclical
investments by choosing those loans, loan
commitments, or selling credit protection swaps
that have the highest spreads or fees for a given
probability of loss. - In equilibrium, this subsidization of systematic
risk can magnify the amplitude of business
cycles. FDIC losses will occur when federal
budget deficits are highest.
14An Alternative Insurance Plan
- Motivated by the empirical evidence that money
funds experience inflows following liquidity
shocks, I model a money fund whose assets are
uninsured bank CDs and/or finance company paper. - The model shows that if a government provides
actuarially fair insurance for this money fund
rather than bank deposits, the incentive for
systematic risk is mitigated. - Intuition Total and systematic risk is less by
insuring a portfolio of CDs (money fund) versus
insuring a single CD (bank).
15(No Transcript)
16Affiliation Can Preserve Information Capital
- An insured money fund could operate as a bank
affiliate that issues insured deposits
collateralized by money market debt. - Checking account information that reduces a
lenders monitoring costs can be preserved.
Mester, Nakamura, and Renault (2003). - Bank credit information may be used by the fund
to select CDs and commercial paper. Massa and
Rehman (2005). - Government regulation of insured money funds is
far less costly and complex. Too-big-to-fail
bailouts would be less likely. - Following liquidity shocks, insured money funds
would allocate inflows to credit-worthy banks and
finance companies who, in turn, would extend
credit to firms (under loan commitments).
17Conclusions
- Risks that are large and systematic are difficult
for a private institution to insure. Pooling
them does not eliminate systematic risk that can
bankrupt a private insurer. - Thus, a government may insure systematic risks,
but political constraints limit its ability to
charge systematic risk premia. - As a result, the subsidization of systematic risk
creates moral hazard that can worsen business
cycles. - The proposed money fund-based insurance system is
not radical. Prior to FDIC insurance, banks held
the vast majority of money market securities,
similar to the money funds of today.