Industrial Organization or Imperfect Competition - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 32
About This Presentation
Title:

Industrial Organization or Imperfect Competition

Description:

Observe a group signal and charge different prices to different groups ... it difficult to implement (but car dealers and some professionals try to come close) ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:83
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 33
Provided by: JanS161
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Industrial Organization or Imperfect Competition


1
Industrial Organization or Imperfect Competition
  • Univ. Prof. dr. Maarten Janssen
  • University of Vienna
  • Summer semester 2008
  • Week 3 (March 31- April 1)

2
2. Price Discrimination
  • Incentives for price discrimination

Price cost
Price cost
Economic Surplus not appropriated by the seller!
PM
PM
D(p)
D(p)
MC
M
QM
MR
Q
Q
3
Price Discrimination
  • First Degree (or perfect)
  • Personalised pricing
  • Third Degree (group pricing)
  • Observe a group signal and charge different
    prices to different groups
  • Second degree (menu of contracts, versioning)
  • Offer a menu of price-quantity (quality,)
    bundles and let consumers choose

4
First-Degree or Perfect Price Discrimination
  • Practice of charging each consumer the maximum
    amount he or she will pay for each incremental
    unit
  • Permits a firm to extract all surplus from
    consumers

5
First-degree optimal pricing rule
  • P(x) is the inverse demand function
  • When charging for each additional unit x price
    P(x) the firms profit equals
  • Optimisation yields P(x) C(x)
  • Which is the definition of the perfectly
    competitive price
  • Hence, efficient allocation

6
Perfect price discriminationTwo-Part Tariff
Implementation
1. Set price at marginal cost. 2. Compute
consumer surplus. 3. Charge a fixed-fee equal to
consumer surplus.
7
Two-Part Tariff optimal pricing rule
  • Total price for x units T(x) A px, where A is
    fixed fee and p price per unit
  • When consumer buys x units, net utility equals
    U(x) A px.
  • Given T(x), consumer buys x units, where U(x)
    p
  • Participation constraint U(x) A px 0
  • Max A (p-c)x by choosing A and p given
    participation constraint and optimal consumer
    choice
  • Obviously, in the optimum PC binds and we should
    have U(x) p c. Moreover, A U(x) cx

8
Caveats with perfect pricediscrimination
  • Even though it leads to an efficient outcome, is
    it a fair distribution of wealth in the society?
  • In practice, transactions costs and information
    constraints make it difficult to implement (but
    car dealers and some professionals try to come
    close).
  • Arbitrage Price discrimination wont work if
    consumers can resell the good.

9
Third Degree Price Discrimination
  • The practice of charging different groups of
    consumers different prices for the same product
  • Examples
  • Journals, software institutions, individuals,
    students
  • International pricing
  • Physicians rich and poor patients

10
Third Degree Price Discrimination
  • Suppose the total demand for a product is
    comprised of two groups with different
    elasticities, ? 1 lt ? 2
  • Notice that group 2 is more price sensitive than
    group 1
  • Profit-maximizing prices?
  • P1 1/(1 - 1/?1) ? MC
  • P2 1/(1 - 1/?2) ? MC
  • More price sensitive consumers pay lower prices
  • Usually, people with lower incomes (students)
  • Even if firms have no redistribution intention

11
Welfare aspects ofThird Degree Price
Discrimination
- Firms are better off - Low (high) elasticity
consumers are worse (better) off
12
Welfare aspects I Analysis constant MC
  • Without discrimination charge Pm, sell Si Qmi
    Si Di(Pm). Profit p (Pm c) Si Qmi
  • With discrimination charge Pi, sell Qi D(Pi)
    and p Si (Pi - c)Qi
  • ?W Si (Pi - c)Qi - (Pm - c)Qmi
    Si Si(Pi) - Si(Pm),
    where ?W change in welfare because of
    discrimination and Si surplus of group i
  • Note that dSi/dp - Di(p) and d2Si/dp2 - d
    Di(p)/dp gt 0 (surplus is convex)

13
Welfare aspects Analysis II
  • Convexity implies that Si(Pi) - Si(Pm)
    Si(Pm)Pi - Pm - QmiPi - Pm
  • So, ?W Si (Pi - c)Qi - (Pm - c)Qmi Qmi(Pi
    Pm) Si (Pi - c)(Qi - Qm).
  • Also, Si(Pm) - Si(Pi) Si(Pi)Pm - Pi
  • Implying ?W (Pm - c)Si (Qi - Qmi).
  • So, if price discrimination does not result in
    more output being sold, then welfare declines
  • No surprise discrimination leads to marginal
    rates of substitution being different among
    different consumers. Generally, inefficient from
    distributional perspective.

14
Welfare aspects Linear Demand Analysis
  • Qi ai - biPi
  • Straightforward calculations for the
    discrimination case give
  • Pi (ai cbi)/2bi
  • Qi (ai - cbi)/2
  • Without discrimination (assuming all consumers
    are served (buy))
  • Pm (Si ai c Sibi)/2(Sibi )
  • Qm (Si ai - c Sibi)/2
  • As Si (Qi - Qmi) 0, price discrimination does
    not lead to welfare improvement (with linear
    demand), or can it?

15
Welfare aspects when some markets are not served
Price Cost
Pb
P
Db(p)
Pa
DaDb
MC
Da(p)
Qa
Qb
Qb
Q
Qa
16
Caveats with third degree pricediscrimination
  • In practice, the seller needs to be able to
    observe the characteristics of different
    consumers.
  • Price discrimination wont work if consumers can
    resell the good (arbitrage) or (successfully)
    pretend to be of a different group
  • Interesting angle to discuss economic aspects
    around the issue of privacy (cf., Google
    internet) price discrimination can only work if
    firms have some information about consumers

17
Second Degree Price Discrimination
  • The practice of offering a menu of contracts
    intended to sort out (screen) consumers of
    different types
  • For example, by setting a two-part tariff T(x)
    A px, where consumers can choose any quantity
    they want
  • Examples
  • Insurance companies, airlines, utilities (water,
    electricity, telephony), etc.

18
Exercise on Price Discrimination in class
  • Consider the model of second degree price
    discrimination with 2V(x) 1-(1-x)2. Show that
    for any linear tariff with T px (with p gt c),
    there is a two-part-tariff T A px such that
    if consumers are offered the choice, then both
    types of consumers and the firm prefer T to T.

19
2nd Degree Price Discrimination at work
Linear two part tariff TA pq Charge p
c Charge fixed fee A CS1(c)
Fixed Fee CS1(c)
20
What is the optimal two-part tariff ?
Preliminary results
  • Two groups of consumers, with utility function
    ?iV(x) T, ?1 lt ?2 and ? (1- ?) consumers of
    group 1 (2)
  • Consumers demand such that p ?iV(x). To make
    demand linear assume 2V(x) 1-(1-x)2 Di(p) 1
    p/?i
  • Si(p) ?iV(Di(p)) A - pDi(p) (?i-p)2/2?i A
  • Define 1/? ?/?1 (1- ?)/?2 harmonic mean
  • D(p) ?D1(p) (1- ?)D2(p) 1 p/?

21
What is the optimal two-part tariff ? II
  • Participation constraints ?iV(x) T 0
  • Obviously if it holds for ?1 then also for ?2
  • Highest fixed fee compatible with group 1 buying
    is A (?1-p)2/2?1
  • Thus, optimal two-part tariff when everyone buys
    has this A and a price p that maximizes ?A
    (p-c)D1(p) (1-?)A (p-c)D2(p) A
    (p-c)D(p)
  • Yields p c / (2 ?/?1) gt c
  • Thus, optimal price per unit is larger than
    marginal cost!
  • and smaller than the monopoly price provided all
    both groups buy at this price, i.e., (c ?2)/2 lt
    ?1

22
Intuition why c lt p
Loss on group 1 consumers
Gain on group 2 consumers
23
Math why c lt p
  • Loss on group 1 (p - c)(p/?1 - c/?1)/2
    (p-c)2/2?1
  • Gain on group 2 (p - c)(p/?1 - p/?2) -
    (p-c)2/2?1
  • Sum is (p - c)(c/?1 - p/?2)
  • Derivative wrt p is positive for p close to c and
    ?2 gt?1

24
Intuition why p lt Pm
  • By reducing p a little bit (starting from Pm)
    reduction on variable profits (p-c)D(p) is only
    of second-order by definition
  • However, increase in consumer surplus (which can
    be extracted) is in order of D1(p) (first-order)

25
Is a linear tariff optimal?
T
T A px
?2V(x) T
?1V(x) T
x
Single crossing property (or sorting condition)
When two indifference curves intersect, group 2s
curve is steeper
26
Incentive Compatibility
  • It is as if monopolist constructed contract
    T1,x1 for group 1 and T2,x2 for group 2
  • Clearly, group 1 does not want to buy contract
    T2,x2 and vice versa, i.e., incentive
    compatible (IC) contract designed for group I
    is bought by group I
  • Viewed in this way, van we design better
    contracts?
  • Especially, because none of the IC constraints is
    binding

27
Monopolist can extract more from group 2 worse
off without effecting group 1
Monopolists indifference curve T cx is constant
28
Optimal contract - graphically
T2
Incentive compatbility implies that one cannot
make group 2 consumers worse off than this
otherwise they switch to group 1 contract
x2
29
Remarks
  • How to get this either just set menu of two
    contracts, or non-linear set of contracts
  • In optimal contract incentive compatibility
    constraint must be binding
  • That is why linear contract is not optimal
  • In optimal contract, indiffernec curve monopolist
    and high demand consumer are tangent group 2s
    consumption is socially optimal (x2 D2(c))

30
Non-linear menu- graphically
31
2nd Degree Price Discrimination at work
Non-linear two-part tariffs still better
Price Cost
Non-Linear two part tariffs Offer menu
A1,p1,A2,p2 Charge p1 gtc A1 CS1(p1
) Charge p2 c A2 A1BCD
P2(Q)
P1(Q)
A1
p1
D
B
C
MC
p2
Q
Q1
Q2
32
Conclusion
  • First degree price discrimination
  • Efficient from TS perspective, but extreme
    distribution of welfare
  • Third degree price discrimination
  • Yields higher profits than single pricing
  • Ambiguous welfare results vis-à-vis monopoly
    pricing (depending on whether or not total output
    increases)
  • Second degree price discrimination
  • Yields higher profits than single pricing
  • Better for all consumers than single pricing
  • Two part-tariffs are also better for all
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com