Title: Chapter 5 The Consumption Decision
1Chapter 5The Consumption Decision
2Assumption of Rationality
- There are over 100 million households in the
United States choosing millions of different
types and brands of goods daily. - Economists assume all of them are rational!
- This is not so farfetched.
- Rationality simply means not wasting resources.
3The Budget Constraint
- A consumer has only so much income to spend.
- A budget constraint gives all of the combinations
of two goods the consumer can buy if she spends
all of her income. - The budget constraint shows the opportunity set
for the consumer given the prices and the
consumer's income.
4Intercepts and the Slope of the Budget Constraint
(a)
- Intercepts
- x-intercept M/pX, the most X a consumer can
buy. - y-intercept M/pY, the most Y a consumer can
buy. - The slope of the budget constraint -pX/pY.
5Intercepts and the Slope of the Budget Constraint
(b)
- The slope of the budget constraint shows the
trade-off a consumer faces. - If pX 2 and pY 1, then 2 Ys trade for 1 X
- The slope of the budget constraint is Px/Py
-2/1 -2. - The ratio of the relative prices, the trade-off
between X and Y, and the slope are all the same.
6What Happens to Consumption When Income Changes
(a)
- Changes in income shift the budget constraint
parallel to the original, because the slope,
which is the price ratio, is unchanged.
7What Happens to Consumption When Income Changes
(a) (cont.)
- If income increases, the budget constraint shifts
out from the origin, parallel to the old budget
constraint. - The increase in income makes consumers better
off. - Consumers opportunity set expands and they can
buy more goods. - If income decreases, the budget constraint shifts
in toward the origin, parallel to the old budget
constraint.
8What Happens to Consumption When Income Changes
(b)
- When income increases, consumers choose a new
point on a new budget constraint farther from the
origin. - The point they choose depends on their own tastes
or preferences. - When income rises, the consumption of most goods
rises - These are normal goods.
- When income rises, consumption of some goods
falls - These are inferior goods.
9What Happens to Consumption When Income Changes
(c)
- Income elasticity of demand sensitivity of
demand to changes in income. - Income elasticity of demand ?Qd /?income.
- Income elasticity for normal goods 0.
- Income elasticity for inferior goods
- The income elasticity of luxuries (movies,
restaurant meals) is high. - The income elasticity of necessities (car
repairs, clothing, furniture) is low.
10Table 8.1 Some Income Elasticities of Demand
Source H. S. Houthakker and Lester D. Taylor,
Consumer Demand in the United States (Cambridge,
Mass. Harvard University Press, 1970).
11How Households of Different Incomes Spend Their
Money
12Choosing a Point on the Budget Constraint
Individual Preferences (a)
- At which point on the budget constraint will an
individual choose to buy? - Depends on the individual's preferences for the
goods. - Few people choose extreme points
- Only pizza and no shoes, or only shoes and no
pizza. - If we get too much of one thing, we get a little
bored with it. - We like variety and diversity.
- Most consumers choose a point on the budget
constraint between the x-intercept and the
y-intercept.
shoes
shoes,
shoes
13Choosing a Point on the Budget Constraint
Individual Preferences (b)
- The consumers choice depends on how they value
the two goods. - When making decisions people look at the marginal
value. - Example Pizza and shoes
- The consumer considers the value of an additional
pair of shoes. - He compares this to the opportunity cost of an
additional pair of shoes - If he buys one more pair of shoes, how many
pizzas must he do without? - If the value of an additional pair of shoes the
cost of an additional pair of shoes, the consumer
buys an additional pair of shoes.
14Deriving Demand Curves
- Use the budget constraint to derive a consumer's
demand curve. - Suppose the price of good X rises pX.
- Geometrically there are two effects
- The budget constraint is steeper slope -pX/pY.
- The budget constraint rotates toward the origin,
so the consumer loses some area of the
opportunity set.
15The Income Effect of a Price Change
- When the price of X rises, pX ?, consumers lose
purchasing power, or real income. - The opportunity set shrinks so the consumer is
poorer. - Because she is poorer, she will change her
consumption of good X. - If X is a normal good, she buys less X.
- If X is an inferior good, since she has been made
poorer by the price increase, she buys more X.
16The Substitution Effect of a Price Change
- When the price of X rises, pX ?,
- The good X is relatively more expensive compared
to good Y. - The consumer substitutes away from good X toward
good Y. - This effect is represented by the steepness of
the new budget constraint.
17Putting the Income and Substitution Effects
Together for a Normal Good
- When pX ?, total change in demand for X ? due
to the substitution effect ? due to the income
effect. - If X is a normal good, the total demand for X
falls. - The substitution effect
- The consumer substitutes away from the relatively
more expensive X. - The income effect
- The price rise reduces real income, so the
consumer demands fewer normal goods such as X.
18Putting the Income and Substitution Effects for
an Inferior Good
- Suppose X is an inferior good.
- When the price of X rises, pX ?, the total demand
for X falls. - The substitution effect
- The consumer substitutes away from the relatively
more expensive X. - The income effect
- The price rise reduces real income, so the
consumer demands more of an inferior good such as
X. - The income effect offsets (partially) the
substitution effect, however, the income effect
is small. - The substitution effect dominates and total
demand for good X falls when pX rises for an
inferior good. - Note goods so inferior that the income effect
outweighs the substitution effect and total
demand increases when the price rises are Giffen
goods (these are very rare).
19Utility
- The benefits derived from consuming are called
utility (happiness). - One cannot compare the utilities of different
people. - One cannot say, "You are happier than I am."
- However one can say, "You would be willing to pay
more than I would for some good."
20Willingness to Pay
- Economists use willingness to pay as a
criterion to measure utility or happiness. - Marginal utility how much extra utility or
happiness a consumer receives from one additional
unit of the good. - Marginal willingness to pay how much the
consumer will pay for the next unit. - Marginal willingness to pay is a way of
measuring, in dollars, marginal utility. - As a consumer buys more sweaters, each successive
sweater provides less additional utility - Diminishing marginal utility.
- Successive increments of a good eventually become
less desirable. - The willingness to pay for additional units also
diminishes.
21Willingness to Pay (cont.)
SWEATERS
SWEATERS
22Maximizing Utility (a)
- This says the consumer receives more utility per
dollar from consuming good X than good Y. - She should buy more X and less Y.
- If she buys more X, MUX falls due to diminishing
marginal utility. - If she buys less Y, MUY increases.
23Maximizing Utility (b)
- Since MU p for all goods, it must be the case
that for all goods, - MUX/pX MUY/pY MUz/pz.
- These ratios say that if the consumer is
maximizing her utility then the extra utility per
dollar must be equal for all goods. - To see why this must be the case, suppose that
these equalities do not hold - MUX/pX MUY/pY.
- This says the consumer receives more utility per
dollar from consuming good X than good Y. - She should buy more X and less Y.
- If she buys more X, MUX falls due to diminishing
marginal utility. - If she buys less Y, MUY increases.
24Consumer Surplus (a)
- Consumer surplus measures consumers' total
happiness in dollar terms. - Consumer surplus uses the willingness to pay
criterion. - Consumer surplus is the difference between what
the consumer is willing to pay and what they
actually pay. - This difference represents the "savings"
consumers receive because the market price is
lower than what they are willing to pay. - Consumer surplus represents the total bargain
consumers receive from buying a good at a price
less than what they would be willing to pay.
25Consumer Surplus (b)
- Consumer surplus is the area under the demand
curve out to the equilibrium quantity and above
the price consumers actually pay.
26Loss of Consumer Surplus
- When the price rises, consumer surplus falls for
two reasons. - Fewer goods are bought, so fewer consumers
receive consumer surplus the price willingness
to pay for those consumers who leave the market. - Consumers who continue to buy the product receive
less consumer surplus since they "save" less due
to the higher price. - The loss of consumer surplus measures how much
the worse off consumers are due to the price
increase.
27Consumer Surplus and a Price Floor
28Consumer Surplus and Taxes
- Taxes on goods tend to increase the price of the
good being taxed. - The loss of consumer surplus measures the total
harm of the tax to consumers.
29The Basic Model of Consumer Choice
- The basic model of the theory of consumer choice
provides powerful insights into the behavior of
consumers and suppliers. - It is not without its critics and criticisms.
30Criticisms of the Basic Model
- Few consumers make economic decisions by
consciously examining budget constraints and
computing marginal utility. - True but irrelevant
- It is like saying a physicist's explanation of
how billiard balls travel cannot be correct
because the players do not work out the equations
beforehand. - Consumers do not really know what they want.
- True
- Judging by their purchases, many consumers seem
to have ill-formed and unstable preferences. - Consumers lack complete information about prices,
and hence cannot know their budget constraints. - The interaction of preferences and prices may
make a person's decision process very complex
e.g., the price of an object may influence a
person's attitude toward it.
31Behavioral Economics
- Combines the insights of psychology and economics
to study how people make choices. - Should base theory of consumption on how people
actually choose. - Laboratory experiments are often used.
32Insights of Behavioral Economics (a)
- Endowment effects possessing something can alter
preferences of owner - Experiment mugs randomly distributed to college
students - very few were traded when in
principle around half should have been. - Experiment college students were given either a
lottery ticket or 2 and could trade them not
very many did.
33Insights of Behavioral Economics (b)
- Loss Aversion related to endowment effects
- People seem particularly sensitive to loss.
- A person with 1,100 who loses 100 feels worse
than a person with 900 who finds 100.
34Insights of Behavioral Economics (c)
- Status Quo Bias
- A reference level of consumption is important.
- The first person had a reference level of 1,100,
the second had a reference level of 900. - The difference between actual consumption and
reference level consumption is important. - Why?
- An accustomed standard of living
- Keeping up with the Jones
- The basic consumption model -- the level of
consumption matters
35Tendency for People to Accept the Default Option
- When 401(k) retirement participation is automatic
very few people opt-out. - Default option is not to participate, a smaller
proportion opt-in - U.S. medical drug benefit for seniors
- Default was sign up
- By mid-2004 only 10 of seniors had signed up.
36Implications of Behavioral Economics
- The simple model of consumer choice is
incomplete. - Do we need to change basic ideas?
- No. People still respond to incentives.
- Demand curves still slope downward.
- Behavioral Economics shows that people have a
greater reluctance to change than the basic model
predicts. - May be the reason not all mutually beneficial
trades are made.
37Beyond the Basic Model
- While there are valid critiques of the basic
consumption model they only show that the model
is not complete. - The model is still useful.
- By being explicit about our assumptions, we can
know which ones (if any) are not valid in a
particular instance.