Neither market not state

1 / 82
About This Presentation
Title:

Neither market not state

Description:

Instability manifestly rose as role of government reduced by deregulation, globalisation. Abject failure of 'transition to market' in ex-socialist Europe/Russia ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:48
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 83
Provided by: steve1315

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Neither market not state


1
Neither market not state
  • In praise of the mixed economy

2
The failure of ideology
  • Both great ideologies of the 20th century failed
  • Collapse of socialism
  • Superficial success of capitalism, but
  • Instability manifestly rose as role of government
    reduced by deregulation, globalisation
  • Abject failure of transition to market in
    ex-socialist Europe/Russia
  • Imminent financial crisis in USA
  • Theoretical underpinnings of ideologies
  • Marxian economics
  • Neoclassical economics
  • Must both contain fatal flaws
  • Starting from the Right

3
The failure of free market ideology
  • At basic level, neoclassical theory supports free
    market over any other system of production
    distribution
  • Nuances at higher levels of theory, but core
    message normally implemented by governments,
    agencies (IMF, World Bank)
  • Removal of all subsidies, income supports
  • Deregulation of all industries
  • Privatisation of all assets
  • Free market in financial instruments
  • Given practical failures, problems must lie in
    the core

4
The Utilitarian conceit
  • True philosophical font of neoclassicism not Adam
    Smith, but Jeremy Bentham, father of
    Utilitarianism
  • Belief that purpose of life is maximisation of
    pleasure, minimisation of pain
  • Reduction of society to sum of individual
    constituents
  • Belief that purpose of political liberty and free
    market is to create a Greater Happiness
    Machine the market economy

5
The Utilitarian conceit
  • Nature has placed mankind under the governance
    of two sovereign masters, pain and pleasure. It
    is for them alone to point out what we ought to
    do, as well as to determine what we shall do. On
    the one hand the standard of right and wrong, on
    the other the chain of causes and effects, are
    fastened to their throne. They govern us in all
    that we do, in all we say, in all we think every
    effort we can make to throw off our subjection,
    will serve but to demonstrate and confirm it. In
    a word a man may pretend to abjure their empire
    but in reality he will remain subject to it all
    the while. (Bentham 1780)

6
The Utilitarian conceit
  • The community is a fictitious body, composed of
    the individual persons who are considered as
    constituting as it were its members. The
    interests of the community then is, what?the sum
    of the interests of the several members who
    compose it. It is in vain to talk of the interest
    of the community, without understanding what is
    in the interest of the individual.
  • An action then may be said to be conformable to
    the principle of utility when the tendency it
    has to augment the happiness of the community is
    greater than any it has to diminish it. (Bentham
    1780)

7
The Utilitarian conceit
  • Neoclassical economics codified this vision into
    the concepts of utility-maximising consumers,
    facing profit-maximising firms, across the
    mechanism of the free market
  • Equilibrium of the free market guaranteed
    maximisation of pleasure at the minimum cost

If
  • 220 years after Bentham, we know that the
    conditions required for this vision to function
    are impossible to achieve in reality
  • Beginning with consumption

8
The Utilitarian failureDemand
  • Gorman (1953) demonstrated that for aggregation
    of individual demand to lead to well-behaved
    social preferences, two related conditions were
    required
  • All consumers had to have identical tastes
  • Income distribution could not affect the pattern
    of demand
  • The necessary and sufficient condition quoted
    above is intuitively reasonable. It says, in
    effect, that an extra unit of purchasing power
    should be spent in the same way no matter to whom
    it is given. (Gorman 1953)
  • Rediscovered by Sonnenshein, Mantel, Debreu (now
    known as SMD conditions), conditions required for
    consistent aggregation even under Arrow-Debreu
    general equilibrium

9
The Utilitarian failureDemand
  • First, when preferences are homothetic and the
    distribution of income is independent of
    prices, then the market demand function has all
    the properties of a consumer demand function
    Second, with general preferences, even if the
    distribution of income is fixed, market demand
    functions need not satisfy in any way the
    classical restrictions which characterize
    consumer demand functions The importance of the
    above results is clear strong restrictions are
    needed in order to justify the hypothesis that a
    market demand function has the characteristics of
    a consumer demand function. Only in special cases
    can an economy be expected to act as an
    idealized consumer. The utility hypothesis
    tells us nothing about market demand unless it is
    augmented by additional requirements. (Shafer
    Sonnenschein 1982)

10
The Utilitarian failureDemand
  • Benthams aggregation thus impossible
  • Society cannot be reduced simply to the sum of
    its individual constituents
  • If we are to progress further we may well be
    forced to theorise in terms of groups who have
    collectively coherent behaviour. Thus demand and
    expenditure functions if they are to be set
    against reality must be defined at some
    reasonably high level of aggregation. The idea
    that we should start at the level of the isolated
    individual is one which we may well have to
    abandon. (Kirman 1989)
  • As well as failing aggregation, neoclassical
    vision of consumer practically flawed too

11
The Utilitarian failureDemand
  • Samuelsons revealed preference failed
    experimental tests (Battalio et al. 1977, Sippel
    1997)
  • Subjects routinely breached axioms of revealed
    preference
  • Computational theory indicates whycurse of
    dimensionality
  • Proper modelling of behaviour may have to
    consider
  • Class behaviour (c.f. Kirman 1989)
  • Relationships between consumers
  • Ethical aspects of human behaviour
  • Psychological hierarchy of needs
  • Neoclassical theory useless as guide to behaviour

Skip details
12
The Utilitarian failureDemand Details
  • Combinations A and B give same level of
    satisfaction

Biscuits
  • Combination C gives higher level than A or B

A
  • Combination D gives lower level than A or B
  • Just one wee problem

C
B
D
Bananas
  • Indifference curves no more observable than
    angels dancing on heads of medieval pins. So

13
The Utilitarian failureDemand Details
  • X Initial budget line

Budget Y A clearly better than B
Bananas
  • Consumer chooses A when A B both affordable

Y
  • A must lie on higher indifference curve

A
  • Rational consumer should always prefer A to B

B
X
Biscuits
Why?
  • But in experiments they dont do this! Sometimes,
    they choose B instead of A

14
The Utilitarian failureDemand Details
  • 121 combinations

Bananas
  • Some you ignore

10
9
  • Others you cant

8
7
  • 10 pairs
  • 10 additions
  • 10 comparisons
  • Easy!
  • But

6
5
4
3
2
1
Biscuits
0
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
15
The Utilitarian failureDemand Details
  • Every additional commodity considered adds
    another dimension. With no more than 10 units of
    each
  • 2 commodities, 100 combinations(actually 121)
  • 3 commodities, 1,000 combinations
  • 4 commodities, 10,000 combinations
  • 30 commodities
  • how many combinations?

16
The Utilitarian failureDemand Details
  • 1,000,000,000,000,000,000,000,000,000,000!
  • If budget obviously ruled out 99.9 of these
  • If each evaluation took 1 billionth of a second
  • Process would complete after 32 billion years
  • Maximum (est.) age of universe 20 billion years
  • Individual would take 1.6 times age of known
    universe to make utility maximising choice of
    just 30 commodities
  • Maximising utility in typical supermarket (1,000
    different items) doesnt bear contemplation
  • let alone millions of products in modern economy
  • Instead, intelligent partitioning of commodity
    space vital

17
The Utilitarian failureDemand Details
  • Individual tastes no longer a given but vital
    economic issue
  • Explains individual partitioning of commodity
    space
  • Selling new products requires movement of this
    space
  • Marketing, advertising thus essential economic
    activities if new products are to be sold
  • Co-evolution of products and tastes an essential
    aspect of economic development and
  • Novelists would tell us individual utility
    maximiser are sociopaths (see John Fowles, The
    Collector)

18
The Utilitarian failureSupply
  • Numerous critiques derived from Sraffa 1926,
    Sraffa 1960, show neoclassical theory of
    production untenable
  • Sraffa 1960 heterogeneity and industry-specific
    nature of capital equipment leads to perverse
    effects
  • Increased rate of profit may lead to increased
    use of capital intensive production methods
  • Inverts neoclassical causation
  • Rather than rate of profit depending on the
    amount of capital, measured amount of capital
    depends on the rate of profit
  • Sraffa 1926
  • Marshallian vision of the market requires
    co-existence of mutually incompatible assumptions

Skip Sraffa
19
The Utilitarian failureSupply
  • Marshallian vision of the market requires
  • Independence of supply and demand curves
  • Presence of fixed factor of production
  • Sraffa 1926 argued
  • Former valid when industry defined narrowly
    (e.g., wheat, pin factory), but then fixed
    factor assumption generally untenable
  • a (small) increase in its production is
    generally met much more by drawing 'marginal
    doses' of the constant factor from other
    industries than by intensifying its own
    utilisation of it thus the increase in cost will
    be practically negligible (Sraffa 1926)

20
The Utilitarian failureSupply
  • Broad definition (e.g., labour, agriculture)
    makes assumption of fixed factors tenable, but
    then changes in this industry affect all others,
    feedback to itself, hence supply and demand not
    independent
  • If in the production of a particular commodity a
    considerable part of a factor is employed, the
    total amount of which is fixed or can be
    increased only at a more than proportional cost,
    a small increase in the production of the
    commodity will necessitate a more intense
    utilisation of that factor, and this will affect
    in the same manner the cost of the commodity in
    question and the cost of the other commodities
    into the production of which that factor enters
    the modification in their price will not be
    without appreciable effects upon demand in the
    industry concerned. (Sraffa 1926)

21
The Utilitarian failureSupply
  • Product is horizontal or falling marginal
    costrestoring vision of classical school of
    thought
  • In normal cases the cost of production of
    commodities produced competitively ... must be
    regarded as constant in respect of small
    variation in the quantity produced. And so, as a
    simple way of approaching the problem of
    competitive value, the old and now obsolete
    theory which makes it dependent on the cost of
    production alone appears to hold its ground as
    the best available. (Sraffa 1926)
  • Sraffas theoretical argument confirmed by
    numerous empirical studies

22
The Utilitarian failureSupply
  • Andrews, Bishop, Downie, Eiteman, Eiteman and
    Guthrie, Haines, Hall Hitch, Lee, Means,
    Tucker, the Oxford Economic Research Group,
    (see Lee 1998 for full details), Blinder et al
    1998
  • average costs of production declined as output
    rose
  • marginal costs were always well below their
    average costs, and substantially smaller than
    marginal revenue, and
  • concept of a demand curve (and therefore its
    derivative marginal revenue) was simply
    irrelevant.

23
The Utilitarian failureSupply
  • Businessmen viewed the economists concepts of
    perfect competition and monopoly as virtual
    nonsense and the product of the itching
    imaginations of uninformed and inexperienced
    armchair theorizers. (Lee 1998, citing Tucker)
  • Over 89 per cent of respondents indicated that
    marginal costs either declined or stayed
    constant with changes in output (sometimes
    involving discrete jumps). Finally, only four of
    200 enterprises had both elastic demand curves
    and increasing marginal costs. (Downward Lee
    2001, reviewing Blinder)
  • Fixed costs appear to be more important in the
    real world than in economic theory. (Blinder)

24
The Utilitarian failureSupply
  • The practical reason as to why
  • Engineers design factories so as to cause the
    variable factor to be used most efficiently when
    the plant is operated close to capacity. Under
    such conditions an average variable cost curve
    declines steadily until the point of capacity
    output is reached. A marginal cost curve derived
    from such an average cost curve lies below the
    average cost curve at all scales of operation
    short of capacity, a fact that makes it
    physically impossible for an enterprise to
    determine a scale of operations by equating
    marginal cost and marginal revenues. (Eiteman
    1947)
  • And additional theoretical reasons

25
The Utilitarian failureSupply
  • Marshallian theory of the firm mathematically
    unsound
  • Perfect competition condition of PriceMarginal
    Cost is not an equilibrium
  • Competitive market equilibrium price identical to
    monopoly
  • Monopoly/Perfect competition welfare comparison
    only tenable with constant marginal cost, but
    then model of perfect competition becomes
    indeterminate

26
The Utilitarian failureSupply
  • One presumed condition of perfect competition
    (that demand curve facing individual firm is
    horizontal dP/dq0) long ago easily shown to be
    invalid (Stiglitz 1957 8, n. 31)
  • So
  • Continuing, PMC is easily shown to not be an
    equilibrium, both logically and empirically

Over to Mathematica
Skip summary of results
27
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • Given linear demand and supply (for simplicity
    w.l.o.g.)
  • And standard definitions of Total Revenue,
    Profit, alleged profit maximising levels of
    output
  • Test alleged monopoly equilibrium
  • Enigmatic concise confirmation
  • Perfect competition equilibrium
  • Is true if and only if

28
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • Consider impact of perturbation of dq from
    monopoly profit maximisation point on profit
  • Profit changes by clearly negative amount,
    whatever sign of dq

Productnegative
  • Consider impact of perturbation of dq from
    perfect competition profit maximisation point on
    profit
  • Profit changes by

29
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • Neoclassical micro assumes no feedback from
    individual firm to market price
  • But feedback necessary if market demand curve
    downward sloping
  • Feedback affects all firms
  • aggregate effect sums to same behaviour as single
    firm given valid identical cost curves
  • Intuitive interpretation of results
  • why should a large number of rational agents
    reach a different conclusion to a single rational
    agent, given same data?
  • Empirical interpretation consider Friedman
    argument

30
The Utilitarian failureSupply
  • Excellent predictions would be yielded by the
    hypothesis that the billiard player made his
    shots as if he knew the complicated mathematical
    formulas , could make lightning calculations
    from the formulas, and could then make the balls
    travel in the direction indicated by the
    formulas. Our confidence in this hypothesis is
    not based on the belief that billiard players,
    even expert ones, can or do go through the
    process described it derives rather from the
    belief that, unless in some way or other they
    were capable of reaching essentially the same
    result, they would not in fact be expert billiard
    players. (Friedman The methodology of positive
    economics)

31
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • Simulation of an industry with
  • Fixed linear demand curve
  • Constant marginal cost (see later for rising MC)
  • Given number of firms
  • Each firm starts with randomly determined output
    level
  • Each firm varies own output by randomly
    determined amount (ive or -ive)
  • If new level of profit higher, keeps changing
    output in same direction
  • Otherwise, changes in opposite direction

Miltons Pool Hall
Skip summary of results
32
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • Model 1 simple mechanism
  • Firm always changes output by same amount
  • Model 2 (slightly more) sophisticated mechanism
  • Firm tries randomly determined amount, with range
    of random variable falling each iteration
  • In both cases, output and price converge to
    monopoly level (MCMR), not perfect
    competition level (PMC), regardless of number
    of firms
  • Market definitions monopoly price 80, PC
    price 50

33
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • Random initial amounts

No. of firms
Calculate profits
Random adjustments
Calculate new profits
Work out direction of change
For 50 iterations
Make directed random adjustments of diminishing
size
34
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
Market converges to monopoly price regardless of
number of firms
35
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • With constant marginal cost
  • Number of firms makes no difference
  • output converges to monopoly level, not perfect
    competition
  • With rising marginal cost?
  • Market definitions monopoly price 90, PC
    price 80

36
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • Price appears to converge to PC level for gt 1 firm
  • But
  • Are cost functions the same?

37
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • Apparent difference in behaviour illusory
  • Difference in output level price due to
    difference in cost functions
  • An aggregation problem

38
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • Number of firms does make a difference, but
  • cause is difference in total cost functions, not
    MRMC for monopoly, PMC for PC
  • Supply aggregation (so that MC for monopoly
    identical to sum of MC for PC) only possible with
    horizontal marginal cost

39
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • Monopoly/PC welfare comparison requires identical
    MC curves, otherwise

Price
Ppc
Pm
Demand/Price
Marginal Revenue
Qpc
Qm
Quantity
40
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • WLOG, consider n PC firms employing x workers
  • MC derived from MP
  • Identity of MC requires identity of MP
  • Therefore TP can only differ by a constant
  • Constant zero if variable factor is labour
  • So we have
  • n competitive firms
  • f PC production function
  • g monopoly production function

Euler's equation
41
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • Differentiate w.r.t. n

Consider ratio
Substitute
42
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • Integrate w.r.t. u
  • Take exponentials
  • So g a straight line
  • Consider f
  • f same straight line
  • Differentiate marginal product a constant,
    therefore marginal cost a constant

43
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • Only supply curve for which sum of marginal cost
    curves of small firms identical to marginal cost
    curve of single firm is constant identical
    marginal cost
  • Static profit maximisation (with identical MC
    curves) occurs where PgtMC, MCMR for both
    monopoly and competitive industries
  • Neoclassical theory of the firm thus
  • logically flawed
  • devoid of content
  • Contradictions self-evident once you know to
    look
  • Inconsistent individual firm and aggregate
    results
  • PC firms forego producer surplus at PMC

44
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • Conventional welfare comparison of monopoly to PC
    has monopoly producing to maximum profit, but PC
    producing past that point in the aggregate
  • PC output past point where market MC market MR
    must be produced at a loss, yet no loss shown at
    firm level

?
?
45
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • Producer surplus shows the fallacy
  • Collective gain in producer surplus from reducing
    output from PMCgtMR to PgtMRMC obvious

P
S
Loss
q
PgtMC
?p
Gain
PMC
?p
?q
D
Qe
Qe-DQ
Q
  • Loss of order ?p??q
  • Gain of order ?p?q
  • Loss could only equal gain if ?p
    infinitevertical supply curve
  • PMC only possible with individually and
    collectively irrational behaviour

46
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • Models of PC and monopoly identical at firm level
  • Sole difference is presence of market marginal
    revenue curve in monopoly, absence in PC

Perfect competition
P
S
P gt MRMC
PMC
D
MR
  • But market MR curve exists independent of number
    of firms in industry

Qe
Qe
P
Monopoly
MC
  • Only way to get MRP at firm level is for it to
    apply at industry level (horizontal market demand
    curve)

P gt MRMC
D
  • PC theory based on equating infinitesimals to zero

MR
Qe
47
The Utilitarian failureSupply Details
  • Supply and demand analysis not viable
  • supply curve cant be constructed
  • can only show point of supply for given
    (aggregate) MC and given demand
  • increase in demand could lower market price

Monopoly, etc.
Perfect Competition
  • Minimum of 3 curves needed to determine
    price/quantity

MarginalCost
marginalcost
S1
s2
s1
S2
d2
d1
supplycurve
D2
D1
MR2
MR1
48
The Utilitarian failureSupply
  • Welfare ideals unachievable
  • equality of marginal benefits to marginal costs
    impossible even under perfect competition
  • all market structures will have marginal benefits
    gt marginal costs in profit maximising equilibrium
  • market outcomes will not maximise social benefits
  • How to interpret price-taking behaviour?
  • Firms may take market price as given, but
  • price does not equate price and marginal cost
  • instead reflects markup in that industry
  • For viable firms, price will exceed marginal cost
  • LongConclusion
  • ShortConclusion
  • But at least MCMR rule maximises profit, right?
  • Wrong

49
The Utilitarian failureSupply
  • Neoclassical profit maximising formulas (as well
    as being mathematically erroneous for PC!)
    derived by
  • holding time constant
  • partitioning time into market/short period/long
    period
  • analysing profit maximisation as ordinary
    differential problem
  • Solving first order optimisation problem
  • But profit is a function of time, area, as well
    as quantity

50
The Utilitarian failureSupply
  • Neoclassical logic
  • Profit a function of quantity
  • Price decreasing and cost increasing functions of
    quantity
  • Maximise profit by setting marginal revenue equal
    to marginal cost
  • Mathematical logic
  • Profit at least a function of quantity and time
  • quantity also a function of time
  • Dynamic goal maximisation of rate of growth of
    profit

51
The Utilitarian failureSupply
  • Rate of growth of profit is
  • This is MR-MC
  • Substituting
  • Under what circumstances will setting MRMC
    maximise the rate of growth of profit?
  • Is this condition relevant to a dynamic economy?
  • No, it is the definition of a static one

No way!
  • Are the values of MR and MC relevant to the
    conditions for maximising the rate of growth of
    the rate of profit?

52
The Utilitarian failureSupply
  • Even assuming that the rate of growth of the rate
    of profit is monotonic, the rate of change of the
    rate of growth of profit is zero where (courtesy
    of Mathematica)
  • No mathematician in her right mind would advise a
    firm to manage this function!

53
The failure of ideology
  • Numerous other logical flaws in neoclassical
    theory (see Debunking Economics)
  • Theory cannot support ideology derived from it
  • Free market is provably not an ideal distribution
    and production management system
  • But neither was central planning
  • Apart from obvious political failings (no
    withering away of the State!), centrally
    planned economies
  • Innovated far less than mixed-market economies
  • Grew more slowly
  • Queues acted as supply constraint mechanism
  • Some Marxian predictions re capitalism also
    failed
  • No apparent tendency for rate of profit to fall
  • No the collapse of communism, but disintegration
    of State socialism

54
The failure of centrally planned ideology
  • Again, problems must lie in the core of Marxian
    theory the labour theory of value
  • Commodities exchange at their value
  • Value normally labour-time taken to produce
    them
  • includes LT in machinery, as per Ricardo
  • Ability to work a commodity under capitalism
    Labour-power
  • Labour-time needed to produce labour-power
    subsistence wage
  • Capitalist buys Labouractual work
  • Say 5 hours work needed to produce subsistence
    bundle
  • Actual work lasts say 10 hours
  • Difference is surplus value source of profit

55
The failure of the labour theory of value
  • Why is labour only source of new value?
  • Explanation based on unique aspects of labour
    with respect to all other commodities
  • Only commodity with difference between
    commodity and commodity-power
  • A corollary if labour only source of value, then
    capital merely contributes stored labour-value to
    product
  • However useful a given kind of raw material, or
    a machine, or other means of production may be,
    though it may cost 150, or, say 500 days'
    labour, yet it cannot, under any circumstances,
    add to the value of the product more than 150.
    Capital I p. 199
  • contribution of machine equivalent to its
    depreciation

56
The failure of the labour theory of value
  • Failures of this approach well-known
  • Insoluble transformationthough Western Marxists
    keep trying (poor boys)
  • latest spin Kliman et al TSS Temporal Single
    System
  • Efforts doomed to failure because labour theory
    of value contradicts Marxs fundamental
    philosophy
  • Prior to writing Grundrisse, Marx eschewed
    dialectical philosophy in economic analysis
  • But while writing Grundrisse, chance re-read of
    Hegel (courtesy Otto Brauer, from memory) led
    Marx to fuse dialectics with classical economics

57
The failure of the labour theory of value
  • Marxs dialectics not standard thesisantithesis
    synthesis mumbo-jumbo (actually Fichtes
    approach)
  • Instead, a philosophy of change
  • All entities situated in society
  • Society brings some aspects of entity to the fore
  • Other aspects of entity relegated to background
  • But entity is unity of foreground and background
  • Social treatment generates dialectical tension,
    which can
  • Transform the entity
  • And/or society itself
  • Still sound like mumbo-jumbo?

58
Marx without the LTV a new classicism
  • Application of dialectics to the commodity
  • "Is not value to be conceived as the unity of
    use-value and exchange value? In and for itself,
    is value as such the general form, in opposition
    to use-value and exchange value as particular
    forms of it? OREF 210
  • Capitalism brings exchange-value to fore, pushes
    use-value into background (accumulation of money
    wealth the aim of the game, not utility
    maximisation)
  • Price based on Exchange-value (EV)
  • Use-value (UV) irrelevant to price, as for
    Ricardo
  • But dynamic tension between UV EV. UV not
    irrelevant to economics

59
Marx without the LTV a new classicism
Application to centralunity in capitalism,
thecommodity
General principle
CapitalistSociety
Use-Value
Exchange-Value
Commodity
Dialectical Tension
Applied to economics...
60
Marx without the LTV a new classicism
  • EV of work brought to fore EV of worker
    subsistence wage
  • UV of worker in background irrelevant to wage
  • But UV of worker ability to produce commodities
    for sale
  • Gap between (objective, quantitative) UV and EV
    of worker is source of surplus-value (SV)
  • The past labour that is embodied in the labour
    power, and the living labour that it can call
    into action the daily cost of maintaining it,
    and its daily expenditure in work, are two
    totally different things. The former determines
    the exchange value of the labour power, the
    latter is its use-value. Capital I, 199

61
Marx without the LTV a new classicism
CapitalistSociety
Foreground Exchange-Value determines
(subsistence) wage
Background Use-Value (ability to produce
commodities for sale)
Labor
Dialectical Tension a source of surplus value
62
Marx without the LTV a new classicism
  • Problem
  • previous explanation of surplus used things which
    make labour unique amongst commodities
  • new explanation uses things which labour has in
    common with all other commodities
  • Characteristics of exchange-value, use-value as
    perceived by the buyer
  • independence of exchange-value from use-value
    when determining price
  • As Marx puts it

63
Marx without the LTV a new classicism
  • The circumstance, that on the one hand the daily
    sustenance of labour power costs only half a
    day's labour, while on the other hand the very
    same labour power can work during a whole day,
    that consequently the value which its use during
    one day creates, is double what he pays for that
    use, this circumstance is, without doubt, a piece
    of good luck for the buyer, but by no means an
    injury to the seller Capital I 163 Every
    condition of the problem is satisfied, while the
    laws that regulate the exchange of commodities,
    have been in no way violated. Equivalent has been
    exchanged for equivalent. For the capitalist as
    buyer paid for each commodity its full value.
    He then did what is done by every purchaser of
    commodities he consumed their use-value.
    Capital I 189

64
Marx without the LTV a new classicism
  • Surplus now derived by considering things labour
    has in common with all other commodities
  • Same analysis must now be applied to machinery
  • Marx fudges this in Capital, appears to prove
    that capital cannot create surplus value using
    use-value/exchange-value analysis
  • in the labour process the means of production
    transfer their value to the product only so far
    as along with their use-value they lose also
    their exchange-value. They give up to the product
    that value alone which they themselves lose as
    means of production. However useful a given kind
    of raw material, or a machine, or other means of
    production may be, though it may cost 150 yet
    it cannot, under any circumstances, add to the
    value of the product more than 150. Capital I
    196-199

65
Marx without the LTV a new classicism
  • In fact Marx contradicts own logic. Properly,
    this is
  • Use-value quantitative in MCM circuit
    Exchange-value and use-value are intrinsically
    incommensurable magnitudes (Marx 1867)
  • EV of machine cost of production UV of machine
    ability to produce commodities for sale
  • As with worker, gap between UV EV machine a
    source of SV. Contradicts LTV
  • Contribution of machine to output exceeds
    depreciation
  • It also has to be postulated that the
    use-value of the machine significantly (sic)
    greater than its value i.e. that its devaluation
    in the service of production is not proportional
    to its increasing effect on production. Marx
    1857 in Grundrisse p. 383

66
Marx without the LTV a new classicism
CapitalistSociety
Foreground Exchange-Value (pricecost of
production)
Background Use-Value (ability to produce
commodities for sale)
Machinery
Dialectical Tension a source of surplus value
67
Marx without the LTV a new classicism
  • Many consequences for Marxian economics
  • Transformation Problem disappears
  • Higher K/L ratio doesnt mean lower surplus to
    investment ratio
  • Mathematical critiques of Labour Theory of Value
    (Steedman, Bose, Roemer etc.) supported
  • No tendency for rate of profit to fall
  • Higher machine/labour ratio has no necessary
    impact on surplus, but may alter aggregate demand
    (ability to turn surplus into profit)
  • No inevitability of socialism
  • No Marxian justification for socialism instead,
    a philosophical foundation for the mixed economy

68
Marx without the LTV a new classicism
  • Numerous additional dialectics to base derivation
    of source of surplus
  • Dialectic of wage commodity/non-commodity
    aspects of labour, value of labour the minimum
    wage
  • Dialectic of money commodity/non-commodity
    aspects, value of money/assets set by expected
    use-valueDialectic of innovation new product
    both commodity/non-commodity
  • Supports Austrian view of innovation
  • Far more complex dynamic evolutionary vision of
    capitalism than either neoclassicism or labour
    theory of value

69
An application Minskys FIH
  • Conventional basis for Minskys Financial
    Instability Hypothesis a non-traditional reading
    of Keynes
  • Formalised by Goodwin (1967) into Lokta-Volterra
    predator-prey model of cyclical growth
  • High wageslow investment
  • Low investmentlow growth
  • Low growthrising unemployment
  • Rising unemploymentfalling wage demands
  • Falling wage demandsincreased profit share
  • Increased profit sharerising investment
  • Rising investmenthigh growth
  • High growthhigh employment
  • High employmentHigh wages cycle continues
  • Mathematically, we get

70
An application Minskys FIH
Skip Details
  • In fact, Minskys perspective more easily derived
    from dialectical Marx
  • Existence of surplus a given
  • Income distribution dynamics core to cyclical
    nature of capitalism (c.f. Chapter 25 model)

71
An application Minskys FIH
  • a rise in the price of labor resulting from
    accumulation of capital implies accumulation
    slackens in consequence of the rise in the price
    of labour, because the stimulus of gain is
    blunted. The rate of accumulation lessens but
    with its lessening, the primary cause of that
    lessening vanishes The mechanism of the process
    of capitalist production removes the very
    obstacles that it temporarily creates. The price
    of labor falls again to a level corresponding
    with the needs of the self-expansion of capital,
    whether the level be below, the same as, or above
    the one which was normal before the rise of wages
    took place To put it mathematically, the rate of
    accumulation is the independent, not the
    dependent variable the rate of wages the
    dependent, not the independent variable. (Marx
    1867 580-581)

72
An application Minskys FIH
  • Level of output determines employment
  • Differential equation of rate of change of wages
    determines wages
  • Output - Wages determines profits
  • Profits determine investment
  • Investment determines capital
  • Capital determines output

73
An application Minskys FIH
  • End product is
  • System generates cyclical growth, but
  • Omits several stylised fact aspects of capitalism
  • Ignores financial dynamics
  • Easily added (consonant with dialectic Marx) by
    incorporating Minskys FIH vision

74
An application Minskys FIH
  • An economy in historical time
  • A debt-induced recession in the recent past
  • Firms and banks conservative re debt/equity
    ratios, asset valuation
  • Only conservative projects are funded
  • Recovery means conservative projects succeed
  • Success leads to revised expectations
  • Firms and banks revise risk premiums
  • Accepted debt/equity ratio rises
  • Assets revalued upwards
  • Capitalist and financier expectations rise
  • More investment projects proposed

75
An application Minskys FIH
  • Self-fulfilling expectations
  • Decline in risk aversion sets off increase in
    investment
  • Investment expansion causes economy to grow
    faster
  • Asset prices rise, making speculation on assets
    profitable
  • Increased willingness to lend increases money
    supply, enabling riskier investments and
    validating asset speculation
  • Ponzi financiers emerge
  • Cash flow from investments always less than
    debt servicing costs
  • Interest-rate insensitive demand for finance
  • Profits made by selling assets on a rising market

76
An application Minskys FIH
  • Initial profitability of asset speculation
  • reduces debt and interest rate sensitivity
  • drives up supply of and demand for finance
  • market interest rates rise
  • But eventually
  • rising interest rates make many once conservative
    projects speculative
  • forces non-Ponzi investors to attempt to sell
    assets to service debts
  • entry of new sellers floods asset markets
  • rising trend of asset prices falters or reverses

77
An application Minskys FIH
  • Ponzi financiers go bankrupt
  • can no longer sell assets for a profit
  • debt servicing on assets far exceeds cash flows
  • Asset prices collapse, drastically increasing
    debt/equity ratios
  • Endogenous expansion of money supply reverses
  • Investment evaporates economic growth slows or
    reverses
  • Economy enters a debt-induced recession

78
An application Minskys FIH
  • High Inflation?
  • Debts repaid by rising price level
  • Economic growth remains low Stagflation
    (1973-82)
  • Renewal of cycle once debt levels reduced
  • Low Inflation?
  • Debts cannot be repaid
  • Chain of bankruptcy affects even non-speculative
    businesses
  • Economic activity remains suppressed a
    Depression (1929)
  • Big Government?
  • Anti-cyclical spending and taxation of government
    enables debts to be repaid
  • Renewal of cycle once debt levels reduced

79
In praise of the mixed economy
  • Pure free market economy vulnerable to
  • Enormous unjustified income inequalities
  • Massive price/output instabilities
  • In particular
  • Financial instability and
  • Runaway debt-deflation processes
  • Pure command economy liable to
  • Endemic corruption
  • Minimal commercial innovation (Kornai)
  • Slow growth, stagnant incomes (critique of
    Feldman heavy industry emphasis)

80
In praise of the mixed economy
  • Mixed economy
  • Blends strengths of both market and state
  • Counter-cyclical activity of state
  • Attenuates speculative behaviour of private
    sector during boom
  • Supplants diminished corporate cash flows during
    slump
  • But poorly designed market/state system can
    unravel, as with post WWII Bretton-Woods
  • Dangers of excess speculation built into current
    institutional fabric of capitalism
  • Reforms necessary after coming slump

81
The end of ideology?
  • In the 21st century, we need an economics which
    informs, not one which preaches
  • A proper classical theory of economics
  • Supports a balance between market and state
  • Avoids 19th century ideological battles waged and
    lost by both sides in the 20th
  • Foundation for a complex systems view of
    capitalism
  • Agnostic on to where it should/will evolve
  • Its time for the revival of Classical political
    economy

82
www.debunking-economics.com
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)