Title: Chapter 3 Perfect Competition
1Chapter 3Perfect Competition
2Outline.
- Firms in perfectly competitive markets
- The Short-Run Condition for Profit Maximisation
- Adjustments in the long run
- Applying the Perfect Competitive Model
3The goal of profit maximisation
- Firms' main objective is to maximise profit.
- ? This assumption is not specific to perfect
competition it is made whatever the type of
market structure that is considered - Economic profit is defined as the difference
between total revenues and total costs. Total
costs include opportunity and implicit costs. - Example A firm produces 100 units of output per
week using 10 units of capital and 10 units of
labour. The capital belongs to the firm. The
weekly price of each factor is 10 per unit and
output sells for 2,5 per unit. - Total revenue per week is 250.
- Total cost is 100 spent on labour (explicit
cost) 100 spent on capital (opportunity cost) - Economic profit is 250 200 50
4The goal of profit maximisation (ctd)
- If the opportunity cost of the resources owned by
the firm are considered as generating a normal
profit, the economic profit is the profit in
excess to this normal profit - Economists assume that the goal of firms is to
maximise profit . - Simplifying assumption
- Numerous challenges
- Idea firms do their best to maximse profit
5The four conditions for perfect competition
- Four conditions
- Firms sell a standardised product
- Firms are price-takers every individual firm
considers the market price as given - Factors of production are perfectly mobile in the
long run - Firms and consumers have perfect information
- Do they make sense?
- In most cases, strictly speaking NO
- But can tell us something
6Outline.
- The Short-Run Condition for Profit Maximisation
- Adjustments in the long run
- Applying the Perfect Competitive Model
7Maximising profit in the short run
- Example Assume that a firm is characterised by
the short-run total cost curve we saw in Chapter
2. - This firm experiences first increasing and then
decreasing returns to is variable input. - Assume that it can sell its product at a price P0
18/unit. - One characteristic of the competitive firm is
that it considers the market price as given . - So, the total revenue of the firm is given by
- TR P0.Q
- The profit of the firm is given by
- P TR TC
8Maximising profit in the short run (ctd1)
- The firm's problem is to maximise profit
- P TR TC P0.Q - TC
- First-order condition
- Second-order condition
9Maximising profit in the short run (ctd2)
- The firm maximises its profit when choosing a
level of production such that its marginal
revenue is strictly equal to its marginal cost
10The shut-down condition
- The market price must exceed the minimum value of
the average variable cost. Otherwise the firm
will do better, in the short-run, if shutting
down . - Under perfect competition, the average revenue
is - If P0 is lower than the minimum of the average
variable cost curve, losses are minimum if the
firm shuts down
11The shut-down condition (ctd1)
12The shut-down condition (ctd2)
- The 2 rules
- (i) price equals marginal cost on the rising
portion of the marginal cost curve and - (ii) price must exceed the minimum value of the
average variable cost curve - define the short-run supply curve of the
perfectly competitive firm. - Note that
- For P below the minimum of the AVC, the firm will
supply 0 output - For P between the minimum of the AVC and the
minimum of the ATC, the firm will provide
positive output - In this range of prices, the firm will lose money
(make negative profits) because - (P ATC).Q P lt 0
- But covers its variable costs and even makes some
money on top of it - (P AVC).Q gt 0
13The short-run competitive industry supply
- For any given level of price, it is the sum of
the amounts that firms are willing to supply at
this price. - When firms are identical
- If each firm has a supply curve Qi a b.P
- If there are n firms in the industry
- The total industry supply is just
- Q n Qi n.a n.b.P
14The short-run competitive industry supply (ctd)
- For an industry composed of 2 firms
15The short-run competitive equilibrium Positive
Profits
16The short-run competitive equilibrium Negative
profits
17Efficiency of the short-run competitive
equilibrium
- Competitive markets result in allocative
efficiency, i.e. they fully exploit the
possibilities for mutual gains through exchange
18The producer surplus
- The firm's gain compared with the alternative of
producing nothing (DP) is - DP (P ATC).Q - (-FC)
- Producer surplus
- P (ATC FC/Q).Q P AVC.Q
- because AVC ATC FC/Q
- It is the difference between what the firm
actually gets (P.Q) and the minimum it was
requiring to supply a positive output (AVC.Q)
19The producer surplus (ctd)
20The aggregate producer surplus on the market
21Outline.
- Adjustments in the long run
- Applying the Perfect Competitive Model
22 The long-run market equilibrium
- In the long run, all inputs are variable so that
a firm will choose to go out of business if it
cannot earn a "normal" profit in its current
industry - In the long run
- If firms in an industry make positive economic
profits, other firms are going to enter this
industry. This will drive the market price down
because supply is going to increase. - If firms make negative profits, the opposite
movement will take place.
23 The long-run market equilibrium (ctd)
24Allocative Efficiency
- This long-run market equilibrium has a number of
nice efficiency properties - The equilibrium price is equal to the long-run
and short-run marginal cost so that all
possibilities for mutually beneficial trade are
exhausted. - All producers earn only a normal rate of profit.
- ? All these properties define what is called
allocative efficiency.
25The long-run competitive industry supply curve
26Changing input prices and long-run supply
- So far, we have assumed that input prices did not
vary with the amount of output produced - However, for a number of very large industries,
the amount of inputs purchased constitutes a
substantial share of the market - When this happens, the price of inputs increases
as output rises. This generates a pecuniary
diseconomy. - In this case, the long-run curve is upward
sloping even if individual LAC curves are
U-shaped - These are called increasing cost industries
27Increasing cost industries
28Decreasing cost industries
- In some cases, an increase in the volume of
output may reduce the price of inputs. - This is the case if the increase in the demand
for the input creates an incentive for innovation
resulting in lower production costs for those
inputs (e.g. computers). - In this case there is a pecuniary economy and the
long-run industry supply curve is downward
sloping. - These are called decreasing cost industries.
29The elasticity of supply
- The price elasticity of supply is the percentage
change in supply in response to a given change in
prices
30The elasticity of supply (ctd)
- So, it can be re-written as
- In the short-run the supply curve is upward
sloping so that the elasticity of supply will be
positive. - For industries with a long-run horizontal supply
curve, the elasticity is infinite.
31Outline.
- Applying the Perfect Competitive Model
32The perfect competitive model to what extent is
it useful (useless)?
- No industries strictly satisfy the 4 conditions
of perfect competition - Still, it may be a useful tool, in particular
because its long-run properties apply in a large
number of industries - Exampledecrease in the number of small family
farms which are increasingly replaced by large
corporate ones.
33Corporate and Family Farms
34Price support policies
- In this particular case, resource mobility is far
from being perfect. - Many farmers are strongly attached to their land
- ? Programs supporting the price of agricultural
products - These programs have failed miserably
35The failure of price support programs
36Changes in the EC policy
- As a way of protecting the long-term viability of
family farms the agricultural price support could
not have been more ill-conceived. - More efficient ways to aid family farmers would
have been a reduction in income taxes or even,
more directly, cash grants. - This is actually what the European Commission has
realised recently. - "Severing the link between subsidies and
production (usually termed decoupling) will
enable EU farmers to be more market-orientated.
They will be free to produce according to what is
most profitable for them while still enjoying a
required stability of income".