Institutional Trading Costs

1 / 57
About This Presentation
Title:

Institutional Trading Costs

Description:

More than 70% of trading in developed markets is done by institutions. ... Block trading is not anonymous (no bagging the street) ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:156
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 58
Provided by: Wer14

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Institutional Trading Costs


1
Institutional Trading Costs
  • Rotman School Distinguished Lecture Series
  • March 2008
  • Ingrid M. Werner
  • Martin and Andrew Murrer Professor of Finance
  • Fisher College of Business, The Ohio State
    University

2
Introduction
  • More than 70 of trading in developed markets is
    done by institutions.
  • A block trade is defined (somewhat arbitrarily)
    as trades gt 10K shares.
  • Block orders (institutional orders) are in
    practice significantly larger.
  • Institutional traders need liquidity!!!
  • The quote size is typically not sufficient to
    satisfy their trading needs.
  • Displaying large order will result in adverse
    price impact.
  • How do you tease out non-displayed liquidity
    without incurring price impact?

3
A Definition of Liquidity
  • A market is liquid if
  • uninformed traders can (Who)
  • quickly (Immediacy)
  • buy or sell (Symmetry)
  • large size (Depth)
  • when they want (Availability)
  • at low transaction cost (Spread)

4
Other Variables Affecting Liquidity
  • Security characteristics
  • Recent trading history
  • Resiliency
  • The trader
  • Informed or uninformed
  • The market structure
  • Competitive or oligopolistic dealers
  • Order- or quote-driven

5
Liquidity is Valuable
  • Liquidity helps traders solve cash flow problems.
  • People and firms will save more and thereby
    decrease corporate costs of capital.
  • Liquidity facilitates hedging strategies.
  • More risks will be shifted between natural
    hedgers and production will be more efficient.
  • Liquidity facilitates risk sharing schemes.
  • More extremely large risky positive NPV projects
    will be undertaken.
  • Positive externalities

6
Measuring Liquidity
  • Quoted spread
  • Effective spread
  • Price impact
  • Depth
  • Trading volume

7
The Search for Liquidity
  • Liquidity is the object of a bilateral search.
  • Buyers search for sellers and sellers search for
    buyers.
  • EBay is perhaps the greatest example of how an
    exchange/market can lower cost of search, and
    hence increase liquidity for sometimes obscure
    items.
  • Exchanges can be thought of as search engines.
  • Trader objectives affect their search strategies.
  • Impatient traders demand liquidity.
  • Passive traders supply liquidity.

8
Who supplies Liquidity?
  • Patient pre-committed traders
  • Buy-side institutions
  • Individual traders
  • Value-motivated traders
  • Individuals
  • Institutions
  • Arbitrageurs
  • Pure arbitrageurs
  • Index enhancement funds
  • Pairs traders
  • Market makers
  • Exchange specialists
  • NASD dealers
  • Scalpers
  • Day traders
  • Upstairs dealers
  • Block positioners
  • Package and program traders

9
Who uses Liquidity?
  • Institutional traders
  • Retail traders
  • Professional traders

10
Institutional Traders and Liquidity
  • The largest challenge facing institutional
    traders (buy-side traders) is finding liquidity.
  • Quotes/order book depth is typically insufficient
    for large traders.
  • Large orders tend to be perceived as informed gt
    displaying large orders may be costly.
  • Recent market developments have contributed to
    diminishing displayed liquidity.
  • Market fragmentation provides additional
    challenges (as well as opportunities) for
    institutional traders.

11
Types of Liquidity
Price
  • Displayed
  • NYSE book, ECNs
  • Dealer quotes
  • Not-displayed at market venue
  • NYSE floor brokers
  • ECN reserve orders
  • Not-displayed at broker-dealers
  • Agency orders held by brokers
  • Not-displayed dealer liquidity

Most liquidity is not displayed
  • Not-displayed at investors
  • Orders at buy-side desks
  • Latent liquidity

Source George Sofianos, Goldman Sachs
Quantity1
12
Dealing with Non-Displayed Liquidity
  • Downstairs trading
  • Split orders over time
  • Split orders across dealers
  • Upstairs trading
  • Upstairs broker/dealer screens traders based on
    information
  • Reputation secures the integrity
  • Repeated interaction
  • Who owns the stock?
  • Bloombergs
  • Thomson Financial
  • Negotiation systems
  • Liquidnet
  • Liquidity quote (Nasdaq)
  • Institutional Express

13
Block trades
  • A block trade is any trade so large that it
    cannot be done easily using standard trading
    procedures.
  • Block trades are often negotiated upstairs
    between block initiators and block liquidity
    suppliers.
  • Block dealers
  • Block brokers

14
The block trading problem
  • Latent demand problem
  • Order exposure problem
  • Price discrimination problem
  • Asymmetric information problem
  • How can you convince a counterpart that you are
    uninformed?

15
Price Reaction to Block Trades
  • The empirical literature has discovered that
    block trades move prices.

Temporary
Block buy
Permanent
Permanent
Block sell
Temporary
16
Easley and OHara (1987)Block Trades
  • Why would informed traders use block trades?
  • Model where trade size is chosen strategically by
    the informed traders.
  • To make it simple, final value is either high or
    low and trade size is either large or small (not
    continuous).
  • Two equilibria arise
  • Semi-separating
  • Zero small trade spread, positive large trade
    spread
  • Pooling
  • Positive small trade spread, positive large trade
    spread
  • The semi-separating equilibrium arises only if
  • The large trade size is large enough
  • There is a low proportion of informed traders

17
Easley and OHara (1987)Block Trades
  • How do market participants revise their beliefs
    based on order flow?
  • Separating equilibrium (Bayesian updating)

No event uncertainty Small sell, block sell,
small trade
Add event uncertainty Small sell, block sell,
small trade
Matches evidence on price-reaction to block trade
in the literature
18
Saar (2001)Asymmetric Reaction to Blocks
  • Why are buys associated with significantly larger
    permanent price impact than sells?
  • Saar (2001) argues that three factors contribute
    to this pattern
  • Mutual funds are reluctant to short sell
  • Mutual funds cannot borrow to invest
  • Mutual funds do stock research and they try to
    diversify
  • Combined, these factors mean that there will be
    more information in stock purchases than sells.
  • Specifically, if stock prices have increased (on
    average this is true), then mutual funds need to
    diversify and they pick stocks based on research
    gt
  • The price impact for buys is larger than for sells

19
Burdett and OHara (1987)Building Blocks
  • Models the search for a counterparties for a
    block trade.
  • Suppose a institutional trader wants sell a large
    block
  • Call a block dealer to negotiate a deal
  • Block dealer may put together a syndicate
  • Other block dealers may start short-selling in
    anticipation of the trade
  • Front-running gt price will be depressed
  • The block dealer sets a commission and a
    commitment price, then searches for a better
    deal.
  • How long should the block dealer search?
  • The longer, the higher the cost of front-running
  • The shorter, the more likely you get a bad deal
  • Model derives the optimal stopping time, at which
    point the block dealer buys the rest on his own
    account
  • Has to sell it in the market at a discount
    (convex in size)

20
Burdett and OHara (1987)Building Blocks
  • The commitment price is the expected value of the
    stock based on all publicly available
    information, which is also equal to the price
    posted by the specialist.
  • The syndication has to result in a higher sell
    price for the institutional trader for it to add
    value.
  • Why would buyers agree to pay more than the
    expected value of the stock?
  • Overly optimistic traders
  • Specialist price may be low because of inventory
    concerns (he may be long the stock) and the
    syndicate may be more diversified
  • Perhaps traders are willing to pay up to do the
    block instead of a sequence of small trades
    (order processing costs)
  • Realistic?

21
Grossman (1992)Upstairs versus Downstairs
  • Can the upstairs market dominate?
  • Upstairs market is specialized in seeking out
    unexpressed demand (non-displayed liquidity).
  • Assume that the upstairs dealer has superior
    information on the state of the market.
  • But, upstairs trading involves search costs and
    the delay is associated with a loss of utility.
  • The main result is that if sufficiently many
    traders submit orders upstairs, the upstairs
    dealer can get an information advantage about
    displayed order flow gt the upstairs market will
    dominate

22
Seppi (1990)Order Splitting?
  • Why dont block traders simply split their orders
    over time?
  • Suppose that there is a single risk-neutral large
    trader that may be trading because of liquidity
    or information.
  • There are uninformed traders, several competitive
    specialists, and several competitive block
    dealers.
  • Important assumption
  • Block trading is not anonymous (no bagging the
    street)
  • Route informed order to block dealer gt penalty
    on subsequent trades gt compensates for losses on
    the (informed) block trade
  • How would the large trader trade?
  • Use block dealers when trading for liquidity
    reasons (b)
  • Use specialists when trading for information
    reasons (xt, t1, 2, , T)
  • Equilibria with randomization or informed trades
    also exist

23
Admati and Pfleiderer (1994)Sunshine Trading
  • Traders who announce to the market who they are,
    what they intend to do, the full extent of their
    orders, and why they intend to trade.
  • Would you believe the proclamations made by a
    sunshine trader?
  • Are there potential adverse consequences of the
    order exposure implicit in sunshine trades?
  • Model shows that this is optimal if a large
    trader wishes to trade for liquidity reasons in a
    market where there are also informed traders.

24
Madhavan and Cheng (1997)Upstairs versus
Downstairs Blocks
  • Study gt20K blocks in Dow stocks 12/93-1/94.
  • Compare the cost of upstairs versus downstairs
    trades, taking into account that traders
    optimally select where to send the order.
  • Confirms prediction (Seppi (1990)) that upstairs
    trading is cheaper (but the difference is small)
    because liquidity traders can signal that they
    are informed.
  • Estimate
  • Permanent price impact (20,-1)
  • Temporary Impact (0,20)
  • Pre-trade leakage (-1, -20)
  • Find that the permanent price impact of buys is
    much larger than for sells.

25
Madhavan and Cheng (1997)Upstairs versus
Downstairs Blocks
26
Madhavan and Cheng (1997)Upstairs versus
Downstairs Blocks
27
Madhavan and Cheng (1997)Upstairs versus
Downstairs Blocks
28
Bessembinder and Venkatamaran (2004)CLOB and
Upstairs Trading
  • Paris Bourse has CLOB, why then would there be a
    need for upstairs trading?
  • Most CLOBs actually do have a significant
    fraction of volume off-book.
  • BV (2004) find support for Grossman (1990) that
    upstairs brokers tap into unexpressed liquidity.
  • Costs for upstairs trades are much lower!
  • Also find support for Seppi (1990) than upstairs
    brokers certifu trades as uninformed.
  • Evidence suggests that upstairs market helps
    create liquidity
  • Enhances market quality

29
The Importance of TCA
  • A poorly executed trade can ruin the return on
    even the best ideas.
  • Trading costs can be very high, especially on
    large orders in small cap stocks.
  • Almost 2 percentage points on average!
  • Plexus Group estimates that ¾ of research and
    portfolio management effort is lost in the
    transaction process.
  • The easiest route to the top quartile of
    performance is to be in the bottom quartile of
    expense. Jack Bogle
  • Trading cost analysis is a crucial part of the
    investment process.

30
What is TCA?
  • The use of past order execution data to
  • Analyze the factors influencing trading costs
  • Evaluate execution quality
  • Compare the costs of alternative strategies and
    execution venues
  • Estimate expected trading costs
  • Develop order execution strategies to minimize
    trading costs/maximize net returns (given a
    trading decision).

31
Why is TCA Important?
  • The end of the bull market
  • Lower returns
  • Trading costs are more important
  • Increased complexity of execution strategies
  • Large orders
  • Transition trades
  • Proliferation of execution venues
  • Where to execute?
  • More choice more slippage?
  • Regulatory pressure
  • SECs regulatory agenda
  • SEC Rules 11Ac-5 and 6 November 2000
  • AIMR Trade Management Guidelines November 2002.

32
Small and Large Orders
  • Trading costs for small orders
  • Easy to measure
  • Easy to interpret
  • Easy to predict
  • Main measures
  • Commissions
  • Quoted spreads
  • Effective spreads
  • Trading costs for large orders
  • Difficult to measure
  • Difficult to interpret
  • Difficult to predict
  • Main measures
  • Commissions
  • Implementation shortfall
  • Deviations from VWAP

33
Direct and Indirect Trading Costs
  • Direct costs
  • Commissions
  • Easy to measure
  • Indirect costs
  • Spreads, implementation shortfall, deviations
    from VWAP
  • Hard to measure, especially for large orders

Indirect costs
Direct costs
Indirect costs
Direct costs
Large orders
Small orders
34
Quoted Spread
  • MyFund sends a buy order for 1,000 shares of ABC
    stock
  • Best offer price
  • Lowest displayed price at which we can buy
  • 25.42
  • Best bid price
  • Highest displayed price at which we can sell
  • 25.38
  • Quoted spread
  • Best offer best bid
  • 0.04 or 16 bps
  • Roundtrip cost when we buy at offer and sell at
    bid
  • Reward for liquidity providers
  • Quoted depth
  • 2,000 shares at the offer
  • 2,000 shares at the bid

Offer
Quotedspread
Bid
35
Effective Spread
  • Because there may be non-displayed liquidity
    inside the quote, small orders may execute at a
    price better than the quote
  • Price improvement
  • 0.01
  • Definition of effective spread
  • Buy orders (execution price minus mid-quote)2
  • 0.02 or 8 bps
  • Roundtrip costs if we trade taking into account
    the opportunity of price improvement

Execution price
Mid-quote
36
SEC Rule 11Ac-5 estimates(January 2005)
Universe SP 500 Component stocks Held
orders Less than 10,000 shares
Assuming a 30.00 stock
1 cent
0.033
Note NYSE argues that better matching shows
that the NYSE is cheaper
Source http//www.nasdaq.com/newsroom/stats/Perfo
rmance_Report.stm Note As of January 2005.
Source Market Systems, Inc. SEC 11Ac1-5 data.
Data are for all marketable orders, all sizes
under 10,000 shares, for SP 500 component stocks.
37
Large Orders
  • MyFund issues a buy order for 600,000 shares of
    ABC stock
  • Walk up the book using displayed liquidity
  • Buy 2,000 shares at 25.42
  • Buy 1,500 shares at 25.43
  • Buy 1,000 shares at 25.44
  • Buy 1,200 shares at 25.45
  • Etc.
  • Expensive
  • Liquidity impact
  • Access non-displayed liquidity and work order
    over time
  • shop the order
  • Send to upstairs broker-dealer to work over the
    day

38
Benchmarks for TCA
  • The industry uses several alternative benchmarks
  • Volume-Weighted-Average-Price (VWAP) of all
    trades over the period when the order was being
    filled (Abel/Noser).
  • Closing prices (SEI).
  • Implementation shortfall (Plexus Group).
  • Calculate the value of a paper-portfolio based on
    having bought (or sold) the shares at the
    prevailing price when the decision was made.
  • Usually, the benchmark price used is the
    mid-quote at the time the decision was made.
  • Compare the value of the paper portfolio to the
    actual value of the portfolio after all orders
    have been filled (transaction costs).
  • Multiply the unfilled sized by the difference
    between the current price and the benchmark price
    (missed trade opportunity cost)
  • Average of the daily opening, high, low, and
    closing prices (Elkins/McSherry).

39
Profile of Large Buy Order
1310 execution completed
1230 second execution
1050 first execution
25.85
25.80
1045 order arrives at broker-dealer
25.75
25.70
945 MyFund decides to buy 600,000 shares of ABC
25.75 average execution price
25.60
25.40
Broker-dealer splits order in three 200,000-share
executions
25.35
Trader shops order
Source Goldman Sachs, Trading and Market
Structure Analysis
40
Implementation Shortfall
Average execution price
1045 order arrives at broker-dealer
25.80
945 MyFund decides to buy
25.75
ES
IS
25.60
PC
25.40
IS Implementation shortfall (including fees)
PC Pre-trade cost
ES Execution shortfall of Venue B
IS PC ES commissions
Source Goldman Sachs, Trading and Market
Structure Analysis
41
Factors affecting Implementation Shortfall
Liquidity impact Strain on liquidity caused by
the three executions
25.80
Information leakage Accelerates adverse price
move against MyFund
Fundamental-price move Change in price of stock
over execution horizon had MyFund not decided to
trade Can be favorable or unfavorable Not caused
by MyFund or broker-dealer MyFund faces an
unfavorable base-price move Fundamental-price
changes create execution risk
25.40
25.35
Source Goldman Sachs, Trading and Market
Structure Analysis
42
Chan and Lakonishok (1997)Trading Costs for
Institutional Orders
  • Institutional orders are often broken up into a
    sequence of trades.
  • To estimate the trading costs, we need
    information on the timing and size of orders.
  • Plexus Group provided data on large trades for 33
    investment management (IM) firms, 1989-1991.
  • Styles and strategies
  • Buy and sell
  • IM identities, broker IDs
  • Commissions and Price impact
  • Packages (5 days)
  • Impact is measured compared to two benchmarks
  • Pre open on the first day
  • Post close 5 days after order is completed
  • Remove market-wide movements using a
    size-controlled benchmark portfolio.

43
Order characteristics
  • Stock liquidity
  • Average daily share-volume
  • Turnover
  • Complexity/Difficulty
  • Order size relative to normal trading volume.
  • Dollar order size
  • Urgency
  • Risk increases with time to execution
  • Risk aversion
  • More volatility gt Increased urgency

44
Chan and Lakonishok (1997)Trading Costs for
Institutional Orders
  • Objective is to compare institutional trading
    costs on Nasdaq to institutional trading costs on
    NYSE.
  • Nasdaq orders are more difficult (complexity)
    than NYSE orders.
  • More easy orders in NYSE stocks
  • Sorting trading costs by characteristics gt less
    clear that costs on the NYSE are lower than those
    on Nasdaq gt more controls?
  • Controlling for firm size, order complexity, IM
    identity, price, trading volume, etc, in a
    regression framework.
  • Costs for trading small firms are lower on Nasdaq
  • Costs for trading large firms are lower on the
    NYSE.
  • Evidence that the price impact of buys is larger
    than that of sells is not clear

45
Chan and Lakonishok (1997)Trading Costs for
Institutional Orders
46
Chan and Lakonishok (1997)Trading Costs for
Institutional Orders
47
Chiyachantana, Jain, Jiang, and Wood
(2004)International Institutional Trading Costs
  • Study a large cross-section of 37 countries,
    1997-1998 and 2001.
  • Institutional order data from Plexus
  • Document international institutional trading
    costs and the importance of benchmarks
  • Confirm the prediction (Saar (2001)) that the
    price impact of buys (sells) exceeds that of
    sells (buys) after market run-ups (declines).

48
Chiyachantana, Jain, Jiang, and Wood
(2004)International Institutional Trading Costs
49
Chiyachantana, Jain, Jiang, and Wood
(2004)International Institutional Trading Costs
50
Liquidity impact, stock liquidity, and order
complexity
Closing price on day preceding the day the
decision to trade was made. Price prevailing
when institution releases order to trading desk.
Source Chiyachantana, C., P. Jain, C. Jiang, and
R. Wood, Institutional Trading Behavior and
Price Impact, Journal of Finance, 2004.
51
Trading costs for institutional-size orders (2001)
Emerging Markets
Developed Markets
Source Chiyachantana, C., P. Jain, C. Jiang, and
R. Wood, Institutional Trading Behavior and
Price Impact, Journal of Finance, 2004.
52
Chiyachantana, Jain, Jiang, and Wood
(2004)International Institutional Trading Costs
53
The Plexus Iceberg of Transaction Costs (US, 2007)

Direct Costs

Execution Shortfall
Pre-trade Costs (PC)
54
Managing the Process
  • Lessons from the Plexus Iceberg
  • Reducing execution shortfall and commission will
    not suffice to improve performance significantly.
  • The firm also needs to work on delays (Pre-Trade
    Costs) and missed opportunities.
  • They can be identified with proper record-keeping
  • They can be reduced significantly
  • Improving the process by shortening the pre-trade
    lifecycle of an order can enhance performance
    significantly.
  • Monitoring incomplete fills, and providing proper
    order instructions to executing brokers will also
    significantly reduce trading costs.

55
A Solution
  • Start with the existing portfolio
  • Estimate the difference in performance between
    the desired purchases and the sales gt
    incremental performance
  • Project the total costs (TCA) of buying and
    selling.
  • If the estimated incremental performance exceeds
    the projected TC, complete the executions.
  • If it does not, go back to the drawing board.
  • Substitute high t-cost stock for highly
    correlated low t-cost stock?
  • Track incremental performance

56
Conclusions
  • The regulatory and market environment gt TCA is
    necessary
  • Evaluating TC is relatively straight-forward (IS
    vs. VWAP)
  • Predicting TC is challenging
  • Order characteristics and order strategies go
    hand in hand
  • Liquidity
  • Complexity
  • Urgency
  • Work on the process to reduce pre-trade costs and
    missed trades
  • Integrate the TCA into the portfolio allocation
    process

57
References
  • Admati, A., and P. Pfleiderer, 1991, Sunshine
    trading and financial market equilibrium, Review
    of Financial Studies 4, 443-481.
  • Bessembinder, H., and K. Venkatamaran, 2004, Does
    an electronic stock exchange need an upstairs
    market, Journal of Financial Economics 73, 3-36.
  • Burdett, K., and M. OHara, 1987, Building
    blocks An introduction to block trading, Journal
    of Banking and Finance 11, 193-212.
  • Chan, L., and J. Lakonishok, 1997, Institutional
    equity trading costs NYSE versus Nasdaq, Journal
    of Finance 52, 713-735.
  • Chiyachantana, C., P. Jain, C. Jiang, and R.
    Wood, 2004, Institutional trading behavior and
    price impact, Journal of Finance.
  • Grossman, G., 1992, The informational role of
    upstairs and downstairs markets, Journal of
    Business 65, 509-529.
  • Madhavan, A., and M. Cheng, 1997, In search of
    liquidity An analysis of upstairs and downstairs
    trades, Review of Financial Studies 10, 175-204.
  • Saar, G., 2001, Price impact asymmetry of block
    trades An institutional trading explanation,
    Review of Financial Studies 14, 1153-1181.
  • Seppi, D., 2000, Equilibrium block trading and
    asymmetric information, Journal of Finance 45,
    73-94.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)