Title: The Demand for Medical Insurance
1The Demand for Medical Insurance
- Professor Vivian Ho
- Health Economics
- Fall 2009
These slides draw from material in Santerre
Neun, Health Economics Theories, Industries and
Insights, Thomson, 2007
2Topics to cover
- A theoretical model of health insurance
- When theory meets the real world...
3Logic
- The consumer pays insurer a premium to cover
medical expenses in coming year - For any one consumer, the premium will be higher
or lower than medical expenses - But the insurer can pool or spread risk among
many insurees - The sum of premiums will exceed the sum of
medical expenses
4Characterizing Risk Aversion
- Recall the consumer maximizes utility, with
prices and income given - Utility U (health, other goods)
- health h (medical care)
- Insurance doesnt guarantee health, but provides
to purchase health care - We assumed diminishing marginal utility of
health and other goods
5- In addition, lets assume diminishing marginal
utility of income
Utility
Income
6- Assume that we can assign a numerical utility
value to each income level - Also, assume that a healthy individual earns
40,000 per year, but only 20,000 when ill
Income
Utility
20,000
70
Sick
40,000
Healthy
90
7Utility when healthy
Utility
90
A
B
70
Utility when sick
Income
20,000
40,000
8- Individual doesnt know whether she will be sick
or healthy - But she has a subjective probability of each
event - She has an expected value of her utility in the
coming year - Define P0 prob. of being healthy
- P1 prob. of being sick
- P0 P1 1
9- An individuals subjective probability of illness
(P1) will depend on her health stock, age,
lifestyle, etc. - Then without insurance, the individuals expected
utility for next year is - E(U) P0U(40,000) P1U(20,000)
- P090 P170
10- For any given values of P0 and P1, E(U) will be a
point on the chord between A and B
Utility
A
90
B
70
Income
20,000
40,000
11- Assume the consumer sets P1.20
- Then if she does not purchase insurance
- E(U) .8090 .2070 86
- E(Y) .8040,000 .2020,000 36,000
- Without insurance, the consumer has an expected
loss of 4,000
12Utility
90
A
86
C
B
70
Income
20,000
40,000
36,000
13- The consumers expected utility for next year
without insurance 86 utils - Suppose that 86 utils also represents utility
from a certain income of 35,000 - Then the consumer could pay an insurer 5,000 to
insure against the probability of getting sick
next year - Paying 5,000 to insurer leaves consumer with 86
utils, which equals E(U) without insurance
14Utility
90
A
D
86
C
B
70
Income
20,000
40,000
36,000
35,000
15- At most, the consumer is willing to pay 5,000
in insurance premiums to cover 4,000 in expected
medical benefits - 1,000 ? loading fee ? price of insurance
- Covers
- profits
- administrative expenses
- taxes
16Determinants of Health Insurance Demand
- Price of insurance
- In the previous example, the consumer will forego
health insurance if the premium is greater than
5,000 - Degree of Risk Aversion
- Greater risk aversion increases the demand for
health insurance
17If there is no risk aversion, utility expected
utility, and there is no demand for insurance
Utility
A
B
Income
40,000
20,000
18- Income
- Larger income losses due to illness will increase
the demand for health insurance - Probability of ILLNESS
- Consumers demand less insurance for events most
likely to occur (e.g. dental visits) - Consumers demand less insurance for events least
likely to occur - Consumers more likely to insure against random
events
19The horizontal distance between the utility
function and the chord represents the loading fee
that the consumer is willing to pay
Utility
Income
20Estimates of Price Income Elasticities for
Demand for Health Ins.
- Price elasticities b/w -.03 and -.54
- At the individual level
- Enrollment or premium expenditure
- Elastic or Inelastic demand?
- Income elasticities b/w 0.01 and 0.13
From SN, Table 6-2
21Estimates of Price Income Elasticities for
Demand for Health Ins.
- What about when employees are choosing between
the menu of plans offered by their employer? - Range of choices is more limited
- Price elasticites are found to range between -2
and -8.4, depending on age, job tenure, medical
risk category - Dowd and Feldman 1994, Strombom et al. 2002
22Assumptions underlying the theoretical model of
health insurance demand
- Consumers bear the full cost of their own health
insurance - Insurance companies can appropriately price
policies - Individuals can afford health insurance/health
care - The above 3 assumptions do not always hold in the
real world
23The majority of Americans have employer-provided
health insurance
- Employer-paid health insurance is exempt from
federal, state, and Social Security taxes - Employee will prefer to purchase insurance
through work, rather than on his own
24Example Insurance and take-home pay when income
is 1,000 per week and income tax rate is 28
- Employee Purchased
- 1,000
- 28 tax lt280gt
- after tax 720
- insurance lt50gt
- net pay 670
- Employer Purchased
- 1,000
- insurance lt50gt
- subtotal 950
- 28 tax lt266gt
- net pay 684
25Employer Health Insurance Coverage of U.S.
Population (percent)
26Consequences for costs
- Too many services were covered by insurance
- Coverage of more small claims increased
administrative costs - Employers offering more than 1 plan often fully
subsidized the more expensive plans
27Empirical Evidence
- Long Scott (1982)
- Regression analysis of the determinants of of
compensation paid to employees as health
insurance -
- Annual U.S. data 1947-1979
- N32
28Empirical Evidence
- PCTHLINS -8.64 .0284 MTR .0498 RFRAMINC
- (6.22) (3.98)
(1.14) - -.0094 UNION .088 PCTFEM .1283 PCTSERV
- (.57) (3.72)
(5.52) - R2 .9968
- PCTHLINS of compensation as health insurance
- MTR average marginal tax rate
- RFAMINC average real family income
- UNION of labor force unionized
- PCTFEM employees female
- PCTSERV employees in service industries
-
29Empirical Evidence
- How does an increase in the marginal tax rate
affect the workers compensation package? - The implied elasticity of PCTHLTINS with respect
to MTR is 0.41. If a cut in the income tax rate
is approved, will demand for health insurance
rise or fall?
30Physicians Managed Care
- Traditional fee-for-service gives physicians
incentive to overutilize medical services - Managed care A broad set of policies designed by
3rd-party-payers to control utilization and cost
of medical care - utilization review
- alternative compensation schemes
- quality control
31Managed care and Physician Incentives
- HMOs are a type of managed care organization, but
there are a variety of HMOs - Staff model Physicians employed by HMO on a
salary basis - No incentive to over-provide care
- Group model HMO contracts w/ group practice,
which is paid by capitation - Incentive to limit services
32- Network model HMO contracts w/ gt1 group
practice, all paid by capitation. - Incentive to limit services
- IPA model HMO contracts w/ multiple docs in
various practices paid by discounted
fee-for-service - Some incentive to over-utilize
33Types of Managed Care Orgs
34Preferred Provider Organization
- Insurer contracts w/ multiple physicians but
enrollees can pay higher deductible or copay to
see physician outside network - Discounted fee-for-service
- Some incentive to over-utilize
35Point-of-Service Plan (POS)
- Insurer contracts w/ multiple physicians but
enrollees can pay higher deductible or copay to
see physician outside network - Like a PPO
- However, enrollees are also assigned a primary
caregiver who acts as a gatekeeper to specialists
and inpatient care
36Source Kaiser Employer Health Benefits 2006
Annual Survey, Section 5
37Practice Question
- If you had the choice between a traditional FFS
plan with a 10 copay and a staff HMO with no
copay, at what percentage difference in premiums
(10, 20, 30) would you be indifferent between
the 2 plans? Do you think your choice is a
function of your age/health status? - If you were elderly and/or sick, which plan would
you prefer if they cost the same amount? Why?
38Provider Management Strategies
- Selective contracting
- MCOs will contract with an exclusive set of
providers - Based on quality or cost-effective practice
patterns - Physician profiling
- MCOs monitor physicians track record regarding
referrals, quality, patient satisfaction
39Provider Management Strategies
- Utilization review
- determine whether specific services are
medically necessary and whether they are
delivered at an appropriate level of intensity
and cost - Practice guidelines
- Inform providers of the appropriate medical
practice in certain situations - Formularies
- restricted list of drugs physicians may prescribe
40Performance of MCOs Are they good or not??
- Ideally, MCOs should encourage preventive and
coordinated primary care, which reduces the need
for more expensive specialty/inpatient care - But most MCOs are concerned with short-term
profitability - Why pay for cholesterol-lowering pills when the
enrollee is likely to leave your HMO years before
he has a heart attack?
41Performance of MCOs Are they good or not??
- In general, studies show that HMOs provide
medical cost savings of 15-20, mostly through
reduced hospital care - The impact of HMOs on quality of care is less
definite - Health care providers treat patients belonging to
a variety of plans