Title: Managerial Economics
1Managerial Economics
- Lecture Six
- Alternate models of markets
2Recap
- Conventional model of competition taxonomic
- Classifies industries as competitive on basis
of number of firms market shares - Lots of firms/small share per firm competitive
- Price equal to marginal cost
- Few firms/large share per firm non-competitive
- Price exceeds marginal cost
3What is competition?
- Problems
- Taxonomy almost impossible to apply
- Few industries clearly competitive or non
- Most have few big firms, many small firms
- Results in weird classifications
- Computer industry uncompetitive
- Computer manufacturing is industry 334111 in USA
Manufacturing Census - Top 4 firms had 45.4 of market in 1997 (biggest
IBM 9th biggest firm in USA 2nd HP 11th biggest) - Top 8 68.5
- Top 20 92.9
- But also has rapidly falling prices, rising
quality - Is it uncompetitive?
4What is competition?
- Theory flawed anyway
- Corrected theory finds no difference between
competitive monopoly outcomes - Both produce where Price gt Marginal Cost
- Real firms face constant or falling marginal cost
anyway!
5How else to model markets?
- One alternative see competition as a process
- Firms compete by differentiating products
- Process over time reduces real price, increases
quality - Characterisation as competitive comparative
based on process and outcomes - Process
- whether firms enter/leave industry
- whether products change over time
- Outcomes
- whether price/quality improve
- Comparative with respect to other industries
6The motivation
- Many old monopolies/state enterprises being made
competitive - Entry deregulated
- Publicly owned assets privatised
- Success of policy judged according to
conventional economics - IF many firms enter AND original monopolist loses
dominance THEN competitive - The market works
- ELSE IF new entrants fail and monopolist remains
dominant THEN uncompetitive - The monopolist is exploiting its power
- Pro-competition regulations used to control
monopolist, force lower market share, etc.
7The motivation
- BUT many monopolists complain
- Have reduced prices/increased quality
- Competition fierce
- Failure of new entrants natural part of
competition - Ormerods approach produce computer model of
industry with - Differentiated firms (offering different
price/quality combinations) - Differentiated consumers (different price/quality
tradeoffs) - See what evolves
- IF instrumental outcome (price/quality) poor THEN
industry uncompetitive - IF outcome good then competitive
- Analyse correlation between standard taxonomic
view of competition instrumental view
8A Schumpeterian model of an industry
- Conventional micro models competition with
- Homogeneous product
- No quality differences between firms
- No technical change
- Quality costs constant
- Rising marginal costs and falling marginal
revenue - Schumpeter emphasises
- Differentiated products
- Quality differences between firms too
- Technical change
- Driving force of model/economy explanation for
profits - Shape of costs irrelevant when discontinuities
apply - innovator has lower costs, better quality than
rivals
9A Schumpeterian model of competition
- Archetypal industry telecommunications, post
- Starts as monopolised industry
- Deregulation allows new firms to enter
- Conventional expectation competition will
- Drive price down quality up
- Result in original monopolist losing market share
- Result in many firms in industry
- Actual results
- Price often driven down
- Quality generally up (but sometimes reliability
problems e.g., electricity in California,
Queensland) - BUT frequently also
- Original monopolist remains dominant (Telstra)
- Many entrants fail, industry remains concentrated
10A Schumpeterian model of competition
- Regulators often claim negative outcomes mean
ex-monopoly abusing market power - Telstra v Optus, Qantas v Virgin
- Ex-monopolies often claim outcome evidence that
industry competitive - We cant help it if were better than the new
guys - What is the truth?
- Anti-competitive behavior? or
- Thats just how the market works?
- Ormerods approach model functionally
competitive industry Rapid innovation in costs
quality - Is there a correlation between outcome (low price
high quality) and structural picture of
competition (lots of small firms)?
11A Schumpeterian model of competition
- Approach is multi-agent modelling
- Define artificial agents
- Consumers who seek best price/quality
combination - Producers who seek most effective price/quality
combination for gaining market share - Run simulation and see what happens
- Model
- 1000 consumers
- Each has different linear preferences for price v
quality - Monopolist has 100 of market (1000 customers) at
start - By definition, a monopolist has a sales network
which connects it to all consumers in the
particular market.
12A Schumpeterian model of competition
- New entrants come in offers are known by
(randomly decided) fraction of consumers - Consumers can only buy from those companies of
whose product they are aware. The phrase 'sales
network' in this paper means the set of
connections from a firm to consumers. - consumers on the network of firm fi are both
aware of the offer from firm fi and are willing
to consider buying from it. - First new firm might have sales network of (e.g.)
34 of market (340 customers) - Sales network held constant during simulation
13A Schumpeterian model of competition
- There are three obvious reasons why new firms in
the market do not have potential access (in
general) to all consumers, which can obtain
either singly or in combination. First, the
regulator could impose restrictions so that, for
example and purely by way of illustration from
the telephone market, a new entrant could be
permitted to offer international calls but not
domestic ones. Second, the marketing strategy of
the firm may be such that not all consumers are
aware that the firm is making an offer in the
market. In reality, marketing strategies vary
widely in effectiveness, and this is reflected in
our model. Third, the firm itself may
deliberately target only a small percentage of
consumers. In the context of British land line
phone calls, for example, several firms now
specialise in offering cheap calls to India, say,
or to the United States. (8)
14A Schumpeterian model of competition
- Initial (monopolist) price highest (1) and
quality lowest (also 1 for convenience) - New entrants offer different (randomly allocated)
price/quality combination between best (0,0)
(1,1) - Consumers can switch if new entrants deal more
appealing to them than current deal - Switch probable only each consumer has (randomly
allocated) propensity to switch - Models real-world uncertainties
- Costs in switching (ignored in conventional
theory) - Uncertainty re reliability of new supplier
- Heterogeneity of product means new deal might
not be relevant to one consumer - Inertia too many other things to do
15A Schumpeterian model of competition
- product offers are not perfect substitutes
the lowest (p,q) supplier may specialise in an
offer which is not very important to a given
consumer. Someone who makes only local phone
calls will not be interested in a firm which
provides only cheap international calls. Second,
consumers may have doubts about the reliability
of a previously unknown supplier. there may be
costs involved in switching. To take an obvious
example, if changing suppliers involved having to
change telephone number staying with the
telecomm example - for most people the savings on
price would have to be considerable to offset the
inconvenience involved consumers may simply
exhibit inertia and stay with their existing
supplier, perhaps because the savings involved
are small. (9)
16A Schumpeterian model of competition
- 40 iterations (like 40 quarters 10 years)
- Possibility of new entrant(s) every quarter
- At each iteration, each firm can alter
price/quality offering to try to improve
attractiveness to market - Firms desire to move to most popular (on
average) price/quality combination - Probability, not certainty of switch
- The ability of the firm to do achieve the
desired (p,q) depends on the firms flexibility
level ji. (10) - Models variations in internal flexibility, etc.
17A Schumpeterian model of competition
- After new price/quality offers made, consumers
can decide to switch again - Consumers then review their choice of suppliers
given the revised set of (p,q) from existing
suppliers, and given the (p,q) offered by new
entrants (if any) in that period. (10) - Process causes jiggling of price/quality offers
market shares over time - Average price quality tend to rise
- What happens to structure of industry?
- Is price lower, quality higher when market shares
small? - Simulation run 1,000 times to see overall
tendencies
18A Schumpeterian model of competition
- Price outcome
- Not one single market price
- Each firm offers different price
- Average price tends towards competitive (0)
outcome
- The single most frequently observed outcomes for
the market price is in the range 0.05-0.10. In
other words, price does fall to a level close to
the minimum which is feasible. - However occasionally price is high
19A Schumpeterian model of competition
- The mean level of market price after 40 periods
is 0.145, with a minimum of 0.00007 and a maximum
of 0.650. The inter-quartile range from 25-75
of outcomes is between 0.057 and 0.206. (17) - Quality behaves similarly quality rises (tends
towards 0) - So outcomes competitive what about structure?
- Not competitive, according to conventional
theory - Monopolist hangs on to substantial share of
market - Quite frequently, the incumbent monopolist
retains a very high market share The average
market share of the monopolist after 40 periods
is 53.5 per cent, with a minimum of 3.4 and a
maximum of 100 per cent. The inter-quartile range
is wide, between 32.1 and 75.9 per cent. (18)
20A Schumpeterian model of competition
- Important factor in eventual market share is
flexibility of monopolistability to match best
price/quality offer of new entrants
21A Schumpeterian model of competition
- A high level of flexibility is by no means a
guarantee of a high eventual market share, but
the simple correlation between the two variables
is 0.712. (19)
22A Schumpeterian model of competition
- Many new entrants fail in that market share
becomes zero
- Grim outcome in terms of standard theory but
very similar to reality - The mean number of firms is 8.2, so that on
average almost 12 out of the 20 firms fail
completely i.e. have no sales at all. This seems
compatible with the outcomes which are observed
in practice (see, for example, Carroll and Hannan
(2000)). (20)
23A Schumpeterian model of competition
- Market share outcome uncompetitive on standard
theory
- But results fit data
- a good approximation to the size distribution of
the largest 8 firms after 40 periods is provided
by a power law. explained later Axtel (2001)
shows that this a general characteristic of the
distribution of firm sizes in the United States.
(21)
- A log-log least squares fit of average market
share in Figure 6 on the rank of the firm by
market share gives an R2 of 0.983 and an
estimated exponent of 2.09 (21)
24A Schumpeterian model of competition
- Would standard competition policy
- Reduce share of ex-monopoly/largest firm
- improve outcomes?
- it is often thought that reducing the market
share of a monopolist (for example by competition
policy) will ensure lower prices. (23) - Regression shows almost no relationship between
monopolist share of market and market price - We can examine whether there is any connection
here between the eventual market share of the
monopolist and the prevailing market price The
simple correlation between the two is 0.014.
(23-24)
25Aside whats happening to electricity price?
- Competition policy forces marginal cost style
bidding on suppliers. Price pattern over time is
Suppliers make 30 of revenue in 0.2 of year ½
a day!
26A Schumpeterian model of competition
- Effectively no correlation between market share
of monopolist market price
- What about market price number of firms?
- standard economic theory implies a relationship
between the equilibrium market price and the
number of firms in the market. The fewer the
number of firms, the more the price will be above
the level which just covers both costs and a
normal rate of profit. (24)
27A Schumpeterian model of competition
- Figure 8 below plots the relationship between
the eventual market price and the number of firms
in the market. It is clear that there is little
or no connection between the two. The simple
correlation is in fact 0.05.
- a very low price can obtain with just one or two
firms in the market. Equally, a relative high
price may exist with 10 or even 15 firms in the
market. (26) - Compare this to Cournot oligopoly theory
28A Schumpeterian model of competition
- The key difference between our model and that
of, say, the Cournot model is that with the
latter there is a deterministic relationship
between the number of firms in the market and the
market price which obtains. The more the number
of firms, the closer the price becomes to the
theoretical level of a perfectly competitive
market. In our model, in any particular solution
of it there is no necessary connection at all
between price and the number of firms This
difference between the Cournot model and our own
is much more important than any similarities.
(26) - However, despite this empirical difference,
outcome of model better than conventional theory
29A Schumpeterian model of competition
- Purely by coincidence, given the average number
of firms which survive in 1,000 solutions of the
model, the average price across these solutions
is very similar to that of the in the standard
Cournot model. - On average, after 5 years there are 5.54 firms in
total in the market in the simulations of our
model, rising to 8.21 after 10 years. Two widely
used illustrations of the Cournot model are with
a linear and log-linear market demand function,
respectively. With a linear demand function, the
mark-up on cost is (1 1/(N1)), and with a
log-linear one it is (1 1/(N-1)). These imply,
respectively, a market price after 5 years which
is 15 and 22 per cent above cost. After 10 years
the figures are 11 and 14 per cent above cost.
(26-27)
30A Schumpeterian model of competition
- Conclusions
- the market price generally falls from the level
set by the initial monopolist to close to the
minimum which is both technologically feasible
and consistent with a normal margin of profit - the market price is on average very similar to
that implied by the Cournot equilibrium given the
average number of firms with non-zero sales - however, in any individual solution of the model,
the market price which eventually obtains is not
really influenced by the number of firms which
remain in the market - the monopolist retains, in general, a substantial
share of the market
31A Schumpeterian model of competition
- judged on the conventional criterion of the
distribution of market shares, at any point in
time the market structure is, in general,
anti-competitive. But as the outcome on market
price shows, the model is highly competitive in
any meaningful sense of the word. - the majority of new entrants fail, which seems
to fit empirical evidence - the distribution of market share is approximated
closely by a power law, which again conforms with
empirical evidence. (28-29)
32A Schumpeterian model of competition
- Implications for competition policy
- The results of this approach to the issue should
give regulators and policy makers pause for
thought when considering contestable markets. For
example, it is not the case that a competitive
market (in the sense of having a competitive
price), will necessarily have lots of firms, or
will have driven down the original incumbents
market share. Further, although market share is
often used as an indicator indeed as a primary
indicator of the presence of monopoly power
which may lead to anti-competitive behaviour,
these results show that this can be seriously
misleading. Finally, the existence of an
incumbent by itself does not necessarily tell us
much about whether the price is low or high and
whether the market is competitive or not. (29)
33A Schumpeterian model of competition
- Ormerod/multi-agent model very different to
conventional economics - Rather than single equations with simplifying
assumptions, computer program with many realistic
assumptions - some unrealistic ones can be altered later (e.g.,
no change in firms networks over time) - Outcome comparable to actual statistics
- Majority of markets in USA dominated by top 8
firms - Firm size follows power law
- Wide range of firm sizes in most industries
- Industries neither monopoly nor oligopoly nor
competitive
34Power Laws an empirical regularity
- Power law
- Characteristic of systems where components
interact with each other - E.g., tectonic plates on earths crust
- Movement by one plate causes movements in others
- Slip along one perimeter increases likelihood of
slip on another - Large release of energy reduces overall energy
- So large quake followed by other large quakes
- Period of high seismic activity followed by
period of low - Results in linear relationship between log of
size of event and log of frequency - Earthquake data is classic power law example
- But many otherse.g., word usage in a language
35Power Laws an empirical regularity
- Log of number of earthquakes of size X is a
times log of X - Log of number of species extinctions of size X
is a times log of X - Log of number of meteor impacts of size X is a
times log of X - In case of market competition
- Log of number of firms of size X in an industry
is a times log of X - Firstly, earthquake data example
- Plot of log of magnitudes of earthquakes (log of
4 on Richter scale 4) against log of frequency
(log of -1 1 such quake every ten years)
36Power Laws an empirical regularity
- Example Earthquakes in S.E. USA
1000
10
Number/Year?
1
0.1 10-1
Richter scale?
37Power Law in USA firm size
- Size distribution of US firms follows similar
law - Plot of log of employees against log of per cent
of firms with that many employees is straight
line
- OLS regression line through the data has a slope
of 2.059 and adjusted R2 0.992) (Axtell 2001
1819)
38Power Law in USA firm size
- Same relationship turns up when analysed in terms
of log of revenue (so 1061 million) and log of
percentage of firms with that much revenue
(roughly 10-1 or 1/10 10)
39Power Law in USA firm size
- Axell comments that The Zipf Power Law
distribution is an unambiguous target that any
empirically accurate theory of the firm must
hit. (1820) - Ormerod model generates power law with exponent
-2.09 - Conventional economic models (monopoly,
oligopoly, monopolistic competition) dont fit
power law - All firms of one size no firms of any other size
40Ormerod model
- Standard economic model a set of (unfortunately
false!) assumptions - Rising marginal cost
- Homogeneous product, undifferentiated consumers
- Price competition only
- And mathematical maximisation equations
- (True formula) Maximise profit by setting gap
between marginal revenue marginal cost equal to
(n-1)/n times gap between price and marginal
cost - Multi-agent model a computer simulation
41Ormerod model
- (1) Creates arrays to store information about
- Consumers
- consumers(,1) rand(1000,1) price/quality
weighting - consumers(,2) rand(1000,1) switch prob.
- consumers(,3) 1 firm purchasing from
- Firms
- suppliers(1,1)1 Monopolist market penetration
- suppliers(1,2)1 Monopolist initial price
- suppliers(1,3)1 Monopolist initial quality
- suppliers(1,4)mean(consumers(,1))suppliers(1,2)
(1-mean(consumers(,1))) suppliers(1,3)
Consumer rating of monopoly - suppliers(1,5)rand(1,1) Monopolist flexibility
42Ormerod model
- Network between them (which customers buy from
which firms) - consfirm(,1) ones(1000,1) All consumers
connected to monopolist - Then for 40 iterations
- for k240 k1 is when monopoly only firm
- IF there are less than 20 firms already
- if firms lt 20
- THEN create new firm(s) (probabilistically)
- newfirms round(1/5 rand(1,1))
- Allocate initial properties of each new entrant
43Ormerod model
- for createnew 1newfirms
- suppliers(firmscreatenew-1,1)rand(1,1)
market penetration and also - Initial Price offered
- Initial quality offered
- Average consumer rating of initial offers
- Firm Flexibility
- How many consumers on firms network
- network_size round(suppliers(firmscreatenew-1,1
) 1000) - Each consumer then rates each firm according to
own preferences for price quality
44Ormerod model
- for i11000 for each consumer
- Rate offerings of all firms
- offers ( consumers(i,1) suppliers(,2)
(1-consumers(i,1)) suppliers(,3) ) .
full(consfirm(i,)') - Work out best offer
- bestoffer,bestofferfirm min(offers(find(offers
))) - Toss a coin based on individual propensity to
switch - prob_change sqrt(consumers(i,2) rand(1,1))
- Switch if coin comes up heads
- if prob_change gt 0.5
- consumers(i,3)bestofferfirm
- end
45Ormerod model
- Next firms work out best practice
- C,I min(suppliers(actual_suppliers,4))
- Toss a coin
- for i1firms
- dice rand(1,1)
- prob_change suppliers(i,5) dice
- If coin comes up heads
- if prob_change gt 1
- Copy offerings of best practice firm
- suppliers(i,2)suppliers(I,2)
- suppliers(i,3)suppliers(I,3)
- end
46Ormerod model
- Process continues to next round and each stage
graphed - Ormerods program repeats process 1,000 times and
records outcomes of each run. - This program runs once (40 iterations) and shows
market outcome at each time step (1 iteration 3
months real time) - Similar qualitative outcomes to Ormerod program
- Monopolist tends to hang on to lions share of
market - But competitive outcome (falling price/rising
quality) independent of number of firms - A few sample runs
47Ormerod model
- (1) A monopolist with the lot
48Ormerod model
49Ormerod model
50Ormerod model
- Wide range of structural outcomes
- Little difference in practical outcomes
- Price still falls
- Quality still rises
- The bottom line
Competition is a process, not a structure
- Next week
- Macroeconomics from a management perspective
- Managing a firm in a cyclical economy
- Aside dynamic version of last weeks model