Title: Challenges in estimating effects of trade reform
1Challenges in estimating effects of trade reform
- Kym Anderson
- Development Research Group, World Bank
- Washington DC
2Estimating ex ante effects of trade reform
- Global trade modeling began to make an impact
from the early 1980s - In agriculture, initially PE models were popular
for getting price, trade and welfare effects - Starting with single-commodity, then
multi-commodity - Okay for rich countries where agriculture is a
small part of the economy and manufacturing
tariffs are low, but otherwise welfare
calculations are unreliable - Unable to show inter-linkages between agric and
other sectors, as needed in UR multilateral trade
negotiations - CGE national and then global models (esp. GTAP)
have since become the main workhorse for MTNs
3CGE models have come a long way
- National models e.g. Evans (1972) for Australia,
leading to comparative static ORANI (1982) and
then dynamic MONASH (1998) - Global models e.g. Whalley (1985) and Deardorff
and Stern (1986, 1990), then SALTER (1991) which
led to GTAP - GTAP global database now Version 6, with 57
sectors (20 agr.) and 87 countries/regions - each with Armington elasticities (to capture
bilateral and intra-industry trade better)
4GTAP database, Version 6
- Based on 2001 market and policy data, it is
superior to earlier versions because it has - Bound as well as applied tariffs
- AVEs of specific and compound tariffs
- TRQs accounted for (if not very well)
- Non-reciprocal (EBA, AGOA, CBI, ACP) as well as
reciprocal (FTA) tariff preferences - Helps address concerns of Panagariya (2005)
5Where to from here?
- Improve the specification of existing and
alternative policy instruments - NTBs such as SPS and TBT measures, including new
ones such as GMOs - Creating a two-tier trading world? (Baldwin 2001)
- Safeguards and contingent protection
- e.g. continued use of agric variable levies by
EU, Chile while bound tariffs remain well above
applied rates - Export taxes/restraints (including contingent, as
with EU wheat in 1995, China textiles from 2005?)
- protection re-instrumentation
- Services trade and investment distortions
6Where to from here?
- Improve the specification of existing and
alternative policy instruments (cont.) - Better representation of agricultural TRQs and
other non-reciprocal preferences - Including who gets rent
- Quota underfill due to ROOs administration
- Blue-box supply restraint measures
- Green-box measures not fully decoupled
7Where to from here? (continued)
- Specify other domestic divergences
- Product, factor and income taxes/subsidies
- Labour union interventions
- Environmental and social concerns (whose?) that
are not being addressed? - But beware of excuses for intervention (e.g.
agricultures so-called multifuntionality) - What is the appropriate counterfactual?
- Its not necessarily the status quo
8Where to from here? (continued)
- Imperfect competition and scale economies
- EU modellers have made most progress here, as it
has been a major contributor to gains from moving
to a single EU market - Will be increasingly important as modelling
expands of the service sectors trade and
investment distortions - e.g. distribution services incl. retailing
(Walmart)
9Where to from here? (continued)
- Dynamics of trade liberalization potentially can
- Integrate growth and trade modelling
- Allow asset market to be included and hence
intergenerational effects to be estimated - Allow closer scrutiny of the options for
developing countries in accommodating to a
reduction in tariff revenue (e.g. via foreign
debt financing) - Show how much greater are the gains from trade,
and how small are the adjustments to reform
compared with normal adjustments to growth - Politicians want ests. of short-run adjustment
effects
10Where to from here? (continued)
- Effects on factor markets, esp. labour
- Not often done because of simplistic CGE
modelling of factor markets? - Need to improve so as to get more realistic
effects of trade reform, and also to feed into - Effects on household and regional income
disparities and poverty alleviation, by
integrating survey data into CGE models - major concordance challenges are being overcome
11Where to from here? (continued)
- Domestic policy responses to trade reform
- Positive analysis what might governments do to
domestic policies if trade reform is introduced? - Normative analysis what should governments do in
terms of domestic policies to more-efficiently
satisfy societys objectives (poverty
alleviation, income distribution, etc.) if/when
trade reform threatens them?
12Has better measurement of effects led to more
trade reform?
- How much credit is due to economists?
- Australias major reforms transformed its
economy from almost slowest- to fastest-growing
in OECD? - Analysis of East Asias export-led growth?
- Agricultures inclusion in the UR and DDA, and
prioritization of measures? - See next two tables
13(No Transcript)
14(No Transcript)
15What are the highest priorities for trade policy
analysts now?
- Better estimates of distortions to agricultural
and services markets - Better understanding of the political economy
process - Build relations with policymakers their
advisors - Address the empirical questions in the minds of
policy makers/advisors/NGOs - evaluate alternative measures, including buyouts?
- Become more-effective advocates for liberal
trade? e.g. in disseminating the following Doha
simulation results
16Key elements of the Doha Agenda
- Agric market access is by far the biggest
potential contributor to global and
developing-country welfare gains - We assume no services reform, but we model the
following - Phase-out agricultural export subsidies
- Reduction of agricultural domestic support
- Cuts in agric and non-agric bound tariffs under
various alternative market access packages
17Agricultural market access
- Tiered formula for cutting bound tariffs (with
Special and Differential Treatment for developing
countries, or SDT) - allow a few sensitive products to be exempt
- We compare it with a proportional cut of same
average size for high-income and developing
countries - And we look at effects of imposing a tariff cap
of 200
18Agricultural domestic support
- Cut in bound AMS need not reduce applied support,
because of binding overhang (with 1986-88 ref.
prices) - and overhang can be increased by abolishing admin
prices used to calculate MPS - Removes MPS from current AMS, but leaves it in
binding - We apply a tiered reduction to the bound AMS 75
if AMSgt20, otherwise 60 - Leads to only 5 countries reducing support
- Thailand 30, US 28, Norway 18, EU 16,
Australia 10
19Other bits of the Doha package
- 50 cut in bound tariffs on non-agricultural
goods for high-income countries and 33 for
developing countries (except zero for LDCs) - We also examine the effects of developing
countries becoming full participants in Doha
(foregoing Special and Differential Treatment) - recalling from earlier GATT Rounds that
developing countries only got what they gave, in
terms of increased market access - Finger (1974, 1976, 2001)
20Results from Doha agric reform
- Tiered formula cut in tariffs with SDT gives the
world 72 billion per year - but only 7 billion go to developing countries
- and if rich countries exempt just 2 as sensitive
products, global gain shrinks to 16 billion and
developing countries lose - although a 200 tariff cap reduces much of that
shrinkage - If tiered formula is replaced by a proportional
one to yield same average tariff cuts, global
gain is nearly as high (64 billion) - ? Worth bothering to negotiate a complex tiered
formula? Or use a Swiss formula instead?
21Adding non-agric market access
- boosts global gain from 72 to 95 billion
- which gets the world 1/3rd of the way to the
potential gains from complete free trade in
merchandise - If developing countries were to forego SDT in
market access, global gain would rise from 95 to
119 billion per year - and developing countries gain would rise by 50,
to 23 billion per year - and US gain would nearly double, to 7 billion
22Implications for developing countries
- Most of their gains go to large agricultural
exporters, while low-income Sub-Saharan African
countries gain little - To gain more, poor countries have to liberalize
more - which they would be better off doing under Doha,
so as to get reciprocity (greater market access
abroad) and/or more aid, than unilaterally?
23 DC welfare gains with SDT (percent change
from baseline income in 2015)
24 DC welfare gains without SDT(Percent
change from baseline income in 2015)
25 DC gains from full global libn(Percent
change from baseline income in 2015)
26Conclusions and policy implications
- Potential gains from further trade reform are
large - Even after UR and recent accessions to WTO and EU
- ?Must find the political will for Doha success
- DCs would gain disproportionately from reform
- Notwithstanding non-reciprocal tariff preferences
- But as much would come from South-South as
South-North trade growth, hence the importance of
developing countries own liberalization - After outlawing export subsidies, agric tariff
cuts are the highest priority from a welfare
viewpoint and if Doha is to be pro-development/pro
-poor
27Conclusions and implications (cont)
- Cuts in agric tariffs and domestic support
bindings need to be large to get beyond binding
overhang - Even large cuts in agric tariffs do little if
sensitive and special products are exempt - Unless a tariff cap of, say, 100 is enforced
- DCs would have to make few cuts because of their
huge binding overhang - So they can afford to tone down their demands for
SDT (and special products) and trade it for
greater access to rich-country markets ( fewer
sensitive product exemptions by rich countries)