Electricity Distribution: Issues in multiyear tariff and Private Investment - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 51
About This Presentation
Title:

Electricity Distribution: Issues in multiyear tariff and Private Investment

Description:

Privatisation of Distribution. In 1999, the Govt. ... Privatisation of Distribution ... Prior to privatisation in Orissa, India had substantial experience with private ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:53
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 52
Provided by: iim9
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Electricity Distribution: Issues in multiyear tariff and Private Investment


1
Electricity Distribution Issues in multi-year
tariff and Private Investment
Dept. of IME, IIT Kanpur Short-term
Course Challenges and Implementation Issues post
Electricity Act 2003 Regulatory, Policy
Technical Solutions April 10-14,
2004 This document can be downloaded
from www.iitk.ac.in/ime/anoops
  • Prof. Ashok Banerjee
  • Indian Institute of Management Lucknow

2
Privatisation of Distribution
  • In 1999, the Govt. of Orissa privatised the
    distribution assets of GRIDCO selling a
    controlling equity share in four companies.
  • A number of other states, including Delhi, AP,
    Karnataka and UP have followed suit.
  • The Prime Ministers Economic Council has also
    recommended that the privatisation of
    distribution be implemented by state governments
    to reduce high levels of theft and other
    non-technical losses seen today in India.

3
Privatisation of Distribution
  • However, operators of these distribution assets
    have expressed concern at the lack of clearly
    defined paths for the prices that they are
    allowed to charge to customers.
  • SERCs in India have thus far set prices on an
    annual basis, although some performance-based
    incentives have been introduced.
  • This reflects SERCs concern that the existing
    information base does not support the development
    of sufficiently accurate multi-year tariffs,
    making it likely that either excess profits would
    be made or companies would make high losses and
    ask the regulator to reopen the price control.

4
Distribution Provisions in the Electricity
Act,2003(Act,2003)
  • Distribution licence may be granted to two or
    more persons for distribution of electricity
    through their own distribution system within the
    same geographical area.
  • A distribution licensee will not require a
    licence to undertake trading in electricity.
  • Open access to be allowed.
  • Open access to all generators (excepting captive
    users) will be subject to a surcharge on the
    normal wheeling charges.

5
Distribution Provisions in the Electricity
Act,2003(Act,2003)
  • The charges for electricity supplied by a
    distribution licensee
  • may include -
  • (a) a fixed charge in addition to the charge for
    the actual electricity supplied
  • (b) a rent or other charges in respect of any
    electric meter or electrical plant provided by
    the distribution licensee.

6
Distribution Provisions in the Electricity
Act,2003(Act,2003)
  • Where the State Commission permits a consumer or
    class of consumers to receive supply of
    electricity from a person other than the
    distribution licensee of his area of supply, such
    consumer shall be liable to pay an additional
    surcharge on the charges of wheeling, as may be
    specified by the State Commission, to meet the
    fixed cost of such distribution licensee arising
    out of his obligation to supply.
  • Such surcharge shall be utilised to meet the
    requirements of current level of cross subsidy
    within the area of supply of the distribution
    licensee.
  • However, such surcharge and cross subsidies shall
    be progressively reduced and eliminated.

7
Distribution Provisions in the Electricity
Act,2003(Act,2003)
  • If the distribution licensee fails to supply the
    electricity within a specified period, he shall
    be liable to a penalty which may extend to
    Rs.1,000 for each day of default.
  • A distribution licensee may, with prior
    intimation to the SERC, engage in any other
    business for optimum utilisation of its assets.
    However, a portion of the revenues derived from
    such business shall be utilised for reducing its
    charges for wheeling.

8
Inter-state transmission provisions in the
Electricity Act (Act,2003)
  • Transmission utilities are required to provide
    non-discriminatory third party access to their
    systems.
  • GOI earlier notified POWERGRID as the CTU.
  • Act,2003 does not categorically identify
    POWERGRID as the CTU.
  • Act,2003 also states that the central government
    may transfer and vest any property, rights,
    employees of the CTU to another transmission
    licensee.

9
Inter-state transmission provisions in the
Electricity Act (Act,2003)
  • Transmission license will be granted to private
    participants by the CRC (Commission). The CTU may
    recommend to the Commission its view about the
    granting of liecnse. But such recommendations
    will not be binding on the Commission.
  • Presently the responsibility of systems
    maintenance and inter-state load despatches rest
    with POWERGRID (through RLDCs).

10
Inter-state transmission provisions in the
Electricity Act (Act,2003)
  • The Act,2003 intends to separate systems
    maintenance and planning from the transmission
    utilities. It provides for setting up of an
    independent NLDC.
  • RLDCs may eventually be carved out of CTU.
  • However, the Act,2003 retains the principal
    functions (planning and co-ordination) of the
    CTU.

11
Private Sector Participation in Transmission
  • While the Act,1998 provided for private sector
    participation under the overall supervision of
    CTU, the Act,2003 created favourable environment
    for such participation.
  • Private transmission licensees will no longer be
    under the direct supervision of CTU.

12
Why do we need private capital in transmission?
13
Models for Private Sector Participation
  • Joint Venture (JV)
  • Joint Venture Agreement (JVA)
  • Independent Power Transmission Company (IPTC)
  • Transmission Services Agreement (TSA)
  • (The Act,2003) favours this route)
  • Lease Operate Transfer (LOT)
  • Lease concessions of the existing assets.

14
New Approaches to Infrastructure Developments
  • Build-operate-transfer (BOT)
  • Build A private company agrees with a government
    to invest in a public infrastructure project
    (e.g., power station).
  • Operate The private developer then owns,
    maintains and manages the facility for an agreed
    concessionary period (e.g., 20 years) and recoups
    its investments through charges.
  • Transfer After the concessionary period the
    company transfers ownership and operation of the
    facility to the government or state authority.

15
New Approaches to Infrastructure Developments
  • Build-operate-own
  • The private sector builds, owns and operates the
    infrastructure facility for the entire life of
    the project.
  • Build-operate-lease-transfer (BOLT)
  • The private sector builds by taking the project
    on lease, operates during the lease period and
    transfers it back after the lease period to the
    government or state authority.

16
Issues in Project Costs
  • Installed capacity.
  • Capital costs.
  • Financial closure
  • Debt-equity mix.
  • Construction period.
  • Time overrun.
  • Costs overrun.
  • Guarantees.

17
(No Transcript)
18
(No Transcript)
19
(No Transcript)
20
(No Transcript)
21
(No Transcript)
22
(No Transcript)
23
Price regulation of distribution in India
  • Prior to privatisation in Orissa, India had
    substantial experience with private ownership and
    operation of distribution systems, with private
    electricity companies regulated as licensees
    under the Sixth Schedule of the Electricity
    (Supply) Act, 1948. This Schedule sets out that
    on a year-to-year basis, the profit earned by an
    operator should not exceed a reasonable return.
  • The definition of reasonable return is set in
    relation to prevailing government interest rates
    and the asset base.

24
Price regulation of distribution in India
  • Reform legislation from the 1990s has allowed
    regulators to incorporate other factors into
    pricing decisions to provide for incentives.
  • The new legislations explicitly allow regulators
    to deviate from the Sixth Schedule to promote
    efficiency, reflect the cost of service, and
    safeguard consumers.
  • In practice, SERCs have followed the format of
    Sixth Schedule closely, but have deviated
    substantially in that the full cost of supply are
    not reflected in tariff orders (Table 1).

25
(No Transcript)
26
Towards multi-year tariff
  • Although, SERCs have not yet adopted multi-year
    tariff orders, this issue has been discussed in
    various recent tariff orders and the UPERC, for
    example, provided incentives based on sharing of
    revenues if the company were to beat a set of
    pre-defined loss targets.
  • Two key concerns relating to multi-year tariff
  • The quality of information base used by SERCs in
    their price reviews, in particular loss levels
    and
  • The efficiency improvements generated by private
    distribution companies.

27
Some Examples of the Concerns
  • Most states see metered sales less than 50 of
    total sales.
  • In its tariff order of May 2000, the APERC said
    it was not possible to estimate the level of
    losses and to fix an appropriate loss target, and
    that the only reliable target to use was the
    level of billing.
  • The OERC Order of 2001 says that the
    authenticity of the loss level projected by the
    licensee has not been supported with verifiable
    data.

28
Towards multi-year tariff
  • Two strategies can be followed
  • The allocation of costs between controllable and
    uncontrollable elements, and the use of a
    pass-through mechanism for the latter.
  • Variants on the basic incentive mechanism through
    sliding scale (profit-sharing) and revenue
    controls.
  • Over 30 of the costs of an illustrative Indian
    distribution company can be considered as
    controllable.
  • Providing incentives to reduce these costs can
    have a significant impact on prices.

29
(No Transcript)
30
Cost elements and the degree of control
  • Demand Very limited.
  • Generation and transmission costs Very limited.
  • Losses Substantial.
  • Labour costs Some
  • Material costs Some
  • Rent and rates Very limited.
  • Depreciation Limited
  • Required Profit Some
  • Investment costs Some

31
Refinements to the incentive regime
  • The regulatory system can be designed such that
    excessive profits are not earned.
  • Probability of excess profits can be controlled
    by
  • ensuring companies only benefit from controllable
    cost savings
  • limiting the profits of the company through a
    profit-sharing regime
  • re-basing an element of the control to capture
    costs diverging from levels forecast in the
    review.

32
Framework for choosing he appropriate approach
  • Incentives for efficiency savings.
  • Incentives for regulatory gaming.
  • Political acceptability.
  • Ease of implementation
  • What new information is required each year
  • The new incentive framework should address above
    issues.
  • A system based on a revenue cap with cost
    pass-through for non-controllable costs would
    seem most appropriate given its stronger ability
    to allow real incentives for the company while
    controlling for political acceptability.

33
Revenue-based tariff
  • If revenues were forecast for 5 years, the only
    annual adjustments would be to incorporate
  • inflation
  • efficiency savings (the X factor)
  • over-or under-recovery of revenue compared to
    control
  • mechanical correction for out-turn uncontrollable
    costs being different from forecast

34
Multi-year Tariff An adaptive Model
35
Effectiveness of the Model Three situations
  • Out-turn demand diverges from forecast demand.
  • Planned investment announced at the price review
    not undertaken.
  • Losses prove easier to deal with than anticipated
    by the regulator.

36
Incorporating incentives for losses in the Model
  • Two options for increasing the incentive for loss
    reduction
  • any increases in revenue that are not associated
    with an increase in electricity purchases by the
    distributor can be kept by the company as higher
    profits, and
  • a separate item relating to measured losses is
    introduced in the formula whereby losses are
    directly calculated and incorporated in the Model.

37
Incorporating incentives for losses in the Model
  • The first approach tries to separate the two
    elements of movements in revenue, namely
  • Increases or decreases in the level of demand,
    and
  • improved collection of bills or reduction in
    technical losses.
  • To distinguish between the two revenue drivers,
    the level of electricity purchases may be used.

38
Revenue Split
  • Revenue can be split into four elements
  • The number of units of electricity purchased by
    the distribution company.
  • The generation and transmission price per unit of
    electricity purchased.
  • Distribution costs.
  • Losses (both technical and commercial).

39
Multi-year Tariff An adaptive Model
40
Multi-year Distribution Tariff a five-year
tariff model
  • The basic pricing formula should be CPI-X rather
    than rate of return.
  • In adopting CPI-X, distributors should submit
    forward-looking revenue benchmarks reflecting the
    requirements of the distributors over the next
    five years.
  • These benchmarks are based on assumptions about
    efficient levels of expenditure that the
    distributors would need to incur over the
    five-year period to meet the target levels of
    service reliability and quality, expected demand
    growth and the cost of capital financing.

41
Forward-looking Revenue Benchmarks
  • In order to establish each distributors
    benchmark revenue requirement, the following data
    need to be collected from each distributor
  • the target levels of service to be delivered over
    five-year
  • expected demand over the same period
  • corresponding capital and operating expenditure
    benchmarks
  • incentive allowances reflecting improvements in
    efficiency made in the first regulatory period
    and
  • the cost of capital financing, including the cost
    of capital, the cost of tax, regulatory asset
    values, and depreciation or the return of capital.

42
Multi-year Distribution Tariff a five-year
tariff model
  • These benchmarks are used to derive X factors
    which, together with the consumer price index,
    determine the annual percentage change in average
    tariffs.
  • That is, average prices for the use of the
    distribution system will change by the CPI, less
    the X applying in that year.

43
The X Factor
  • The regulator will define the real reductions in
    average distribution charges expected over the
    next five year.
  • However, the actual price reductions seen by
    different classes of customer in first year will
    depend upon distributors decisions regarding the
    structure of their tariffs under the price
    controls established by the regulator.

44
(No Transcript)
45
(No Transcript)
46
(No Transcript)
47
(No Transcript)
48
The X Factor Example
49
Multi-year Tariff
  • The forward-looking revenue benchmarks are
    established independent of past revenues on the
    basis of current and prospective electricity and
    capital market conditions.
  • Returns generated by favourable market conditions
    (e.g., unanticipated demand growth, reduction in
    cost of capital) during the first regulatory
    period are not captured in the process of
    establishing the revenue benchmarks for next
    regulatory period.

50
Multi-year Tariff
  • Under the CPI X price cap approach, the
    distributors retain the benefits of these
    favourable outcomes (and incur the costs of any
    unfavourable outcomes) that occur during the
    period covered by the initial price caps.
  • However, the benefits of favourable outcomes
    enjoyed in the past regulatory period is to be
    passed on to the consumer in the first year of
    the next regulatory period (X0).

51
Determination of X0 Example
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com