Title: Electricity Distribution: Issues in multiyear tariff and Private Investment
1Electricity Distribution Issues in multi-year
tariff and Private Investment
Dept. of IME, IIT Kanpur Short-term
Course Challenges and Implementation Issues post
Electricity Act 2003 Regulatory, Policy
Technical Solutions April 10-14,
2004 This document can be downloaded
from www.iitk.ac.in/ime/anoops
- Prof. Ashok Banerjee
- Indian Institute of Management Lucknow
2Privatisation of Distribution
- In 1999, the Govt. of Orissa privatised the
distribution assets of GRIDCO selling a
controlling equity share in four companies. - A number of other states, including Delhi, AP,
Karnataka and UP have followed suit. - The Prime Ministers Economic Council has also
recommended that the privatisation of
distribution be implemented by state governments
to reduce high levels of theft and other
non-technical losses seen today in India.
3Privatisation of Distribution
- However, operators of these distribution assets
have expressed concern at the lack of clearly
defined paths for the prices that they are
allowed to charge to customers. - SERCs in India have thus far set prices on an
annual basis, although some performance-based
incentives have been introduced. - This reflects SERCs concern that the existing
information base does not support the development
of sufficiently accurate multi-year tariffs,
making it likely that either excess profits would
be made or companies would make high losses and
ask the regulator to reopen the price control.
4Distribution Provisions in the Electricity
Act,2003(Act,2003)
- Distribution licence may be granted to two or
more persons for distribution of electricity
through their own distribution system within the
same geographical area. - A distribution licensee will not require a
licence to undertake trading in electricity. - Open access to be allowed.
- Open access to all generators (excepting captive
users) will be subject to a surcharge on the
normal wheeling charges.
5Distribution Provisions in the Electricity
Act,2003(Act,2003)
- The charges for electricity supplied by a
distribution licensee - may include -
- (a) a fixed charge in addition to the charge for
the actual electricity supplied - (b) a rent or other charges in respect of any
electric meter or electrical plant provided by
the distribution licensee.
6Distribution Provisions in the Electricity
Act,2003(Act,2003)
- Where the State Commission permits a consumer or
class of consumers to receive supply of
electricity from a person other than the
distribution licensee of his area of supply, such
consumer shall be liable to pay an additional
surcharge on the charges of wheeling, as may be
specified by the State Commission, to meet the
fixed cost of such distribution licensee arising
out of his obligation to supply. - Such surcharge shall be utilised to meet the
requirements of current level of cross subsidy
within the area of supply of the distribution
licensee. - However, such surcharge and cross subsidies shall
be progressively reduced and eliminated.
7Distribution Provisions in the Electricity
Act,2003(Act,2003)
- If the distribution licensee fails to supply the
electricity within a specified period, he shall
be liable to a penalty which may extend to
Rs.1,000 for each day of default. - A distribution licensee may, with prior
intimation to the SERC, engage in any other
business for optimum utilisation of its assets.
However, a portion of the revenues derived from
such business shall be utilised for reducing its
charges for wheeling.
8Inter-state transmission provisions in the
Electricity Act (Act,2003)
- Transmission utilities are required to provide
non-discriminatory third party access to their
systems. - GOI earlier notified POWERGRID as the CTU.
- Act,2003 does not categorically identify
POWERGRID as the CTU. - Act,2003 also states that the central government
may transfer and vest any property, rights,
employees of the CTU to another transmission
licensee.
9Inter-state transmission provisions in the
Electricity Act (Act,2003)
- Transmission license will be granted to private
participants by the CRC (Commission). The CTU may
recommend to the Commission its view about the
granting of liecnse. But such recommendations
will not be binding on the Commission. - Presently the responsibility of systems
maintenance and inter-state load despatches rest
with POWERGRID (through RLDCs).
10Inter-state transmission provisions in the
Electricity Act (Act,2003)
- The Act,2003 intends to separate systems
maintenance and planning from the transmission
utilities. It provides for setting up of an
independent NLDC. - RLDCs may eventually be carved out of CTU.
- However, the Act,2003 retains the principal
functions (planning and co-ordination) of the
CTU.
11Private Sector Participation in Transmission
- While the Act,1998 provided for private sector
participation under the overall supervision of
CTU, the Act,2003 created favourable environment
for such participation. - Private transmission licensees will no longer be
under the direct supervision of CTU.
12Why do we need private capital in transmission?
13Models for Private Sector Participation
- Joint Venture (JV)
- Joint Venture Agreement (JVA)
- Independent Power Transmission Company (IPTC)
- Transmission Services Agreement (TSA)
- (The Act,2003) favours this route)
- Lease Operate Transfer (LOT)
- Lease concessions of the existing assets.
14New Approaches to Infrastructure Developments
- Build-operate-transfer (BOT)
- Build A private company agrees with a government
to invest in a public infrastructure project
(e.g., power station). - Operate The private developer then owns,
maintains and manages the facility for an agreed
concessionary period (e.g., 20 years) and recoups
its investments through charges. - Transfer After the concessionary period the
company transfers ownership and operation of the
facility to the government or state authority.
15New Approaches to Infrastructure Developments
- Build-operate-own
- The private sector builds, owns and operates the
infrastructure facility for the entire life of
the project. - Build-operate-lease-transfer (BOLT)
- The private sector builds by taking the project
on lease, operates during the lease period and
transfers it back after the lease period to the
government or state authority.
16Issues in Project Costs
- Installed capacity.
- Capital costs.
- Financial closure
- Debt-equity mix.
- Construction period.
- Time overrun.
- Costs overrun.
- Guarantees.
17(No Transcript)
18(No Transcript)
19(No Transcript)
20(No Transcript)
21(No Transcript)
22(No Transcript)
23Price regulation of distribution in India
- Prior to privatisation in Orissa, India had
substantial experience with private ownership and
operation of distribution systems, with private
electricity companies regulated as licensees
under the Sixth Schedule of the Electricity
(Supply) Act, 1948. This Schedule sets out that
on a year-to-year basis, the profit earned by an
operator should not exceed a reasonable return. - The definition of reasonable return is set in
relation to prevailing government interest rates
and the asset base.
24Price regulation of distribution in India
- Reform legislation from the 1990s has allowed
regulators to incorporate other factors into
pricing decisions to provide for incentives. - The new legislations explicitly allow regulators
to deviate from the Sixth Schedule to promote
efficiency, reflect the cost of service, and
safeguard consumers. - In practice, SERCs have followed the format of
Sixth Schedule closely, but have deviated
substantially in that the full cost of supply are
not reflected in tariff orders (Table 1).
25(No Transcript)
26Towards multi-year tariff
- Although, SERCs have not yet adopted multi-year
tariff orders, this issue has been discussed in
various recent tariff orders and the UPERC, for
example, provided incentives based on sharing of
revenues if the company were to beat a set of
pre-defined loss targets. - Two key concerns relating to multi-year tariff
- The quality of information base used by SERCs in
their price reviews, in particular loss levels
and - The efficiency improvements generated by private
distribution companies.
27Some Examples of the Concerns
- Most states see metered sales less than 50 of
total sales. - In its tariff order of May 2000, the APERC said
it was not possible to estimate the level of
losses and to fix an appropriate loss target, and
that the only reliable target to use was the
level of billing. - The OERC Order of 2001 says that the
authenticity of the loss level projected by the
licensee has not been supported with verifiable
data.
28Towards multi-year tariff
- Two strategies can be followed
- The allocation of costs between controllable and
uncontrollable elements, and the use of a
pass-through mechanism for the latter. - Variants on the basic incentive mechanism through
sliding scale (profit-sharing) and revenue
controls. - Over 30 of the costs of an illustrative Indian
distribution company can be considered as
controllable. - Providing incentives to reduce these costs can
have a significant impact on prices.
29(No Transcript)
30Cost elements and the degree of control
- Demand Very limited.
- Generation and transmission costs Very limited.
- Losses Substantial.
- Labour costs Some
- Material costs Some
- Rent and rates Very limited.
- Depreciation Limited
- Required Profit Some
- Investment costs Some
31Refinements to the incentive regime
- The regulatory system can be designed such that
excessive profits are not earned. - Probability of excess profits can be controlled
by - ensuring companies only benefit from controllable
cost savings - limiting the profits of the company through a
profit-sharing regime - re-basing an element of the control to capture
costs diverging from levels forecast in the
review.
32Framework for choosing he appropriate approach
- Incentives for efficiency savings.
- Incentives for regulatory gaming.
- Political acceptability.
- Ease of implementation
- What new information is required each year
- The new incentive framework should address above
issues. - A system based on a revenue cap with cost
pass-through for non-controllable costs would
seem most appropriate given its stronger ability
to allow real incentives for the company while
controlling for political acceptability.
33Revenue-based tariff
- If revenues were forecast for 5 years, the only
annual adjustments would be to incorporate - inflation
- efficiency savings (the X factor)
- over-or under-recovery of revenue compared to
control - mechanical correction for out-turn uncontrollable
costs being different from forecast
34Multi-year Tariff An adaptive Model
35Effectiveness of the Model Three situations
- Out-turn demand diverges from forecast demand.
- Planned investment announced at the price review
not undertaken. - Losses prove easier to deal with than anticipated
by the regulator.
36Incorporating incentives for losses in the Model
- Two options for increasing the incentive for loss
reduction - any increases in revenue that are not associated
with an increase in electricity purchases by the
distributor can be kept by the company as higher
profits, and - a separate item relating to measured losses is
introduced in the formula whereby losses are
directly calculated and incorporated in the Model.
37Incorporating incentives for losses in the Model
- The first approach tries to separate the two
elements of movements in revenue, namely - Increases or decreases in the level of demand,
and - improved collection of bills or reduction in
technical losses. - To distinguish between the two revenue drivers,
the level of electricity purchases may be used.
38Revenue Split
- Revenue can be split into four elements
- The number of units of electricity purchased by
the distribution company. - The generation and transmission price per unit of
electricity purchased. - Distribution costs.
- Losses (both technical and commercial).
39Multi-year Tariff An adaptive Model
40Multi-year Distribution Tariff a five-year
tariff model
- The basic pricing formula should be CPI-X rather
than rate of return. - In adopting CPI-X, distributors should submit
forward-looking revenue benchmarks reflecting the
requirements of the distributors over the next
five years. - These benchmarks are based on assumptions about
efficient levels of expenditure that the
distributors would need to incur over the
five-year period to meet the target levels of
service reliability and quality, expected demand
growth and the cost of capital financing.
41Forward-looking Revenue Benchmarks
- In order to establish each distributors
benchmark revenue requirement, the following data
need to be collected from each distributor - the target levels of service to be delivered over
five-year - expected demand over the same period
- corresponding capital and operating expenditure
benchmarks - incentive allowances reflecting improvements in
efficiency made in the first regulatory period
and - the cost of capital financing, including the cost
of capital, the cost of tax, regulatory asset
values, and depreciation or the return of capital.
42Multi-year Distribution Tariff a five-year
tariff model
- These benchmarks are used to derive X factors
which, together with the consumer price index,
determine the annual percentage change in average
tariffs. - That is, average prices for the use of the
distribution system will change by the CPI, less
the X applying in that year.
43The X Factor
- The regulator will define the real reductions in
average distribution charges expected over the
next five year. - However, the actual price reductions seen by
different classes of customer in first year will
depend upon distributors decisions regarding the
structure of their tariffs under the price
controls established by the regulator.
44(No Transcript)
45(No Transcript)
46(No Transcript)
47(No Transcript)
48The X Factor Example
49Multi-year Tariff
- The forward-looking revenue benchmarks are
established independent of past revenues on the
basis of current and prospective electricity and
capital market conditions. - Returns generated by favourable market conditions
(e.g., unanticipated demand growth, reduction in
cost of capital) during the first regulatory
period are not captured in the process of
establishing the revenue benchmarks for next
regulatory period.
50Multi-year Tariff
- Under the CPI X price cap approach, the
distributors retain the benefits of these
favourable outcomes (and incur the costs of any
unfavourable outcomes) that occur during the
period covered by the initial price caps. - However, the benefits of favourable outcomes
enjoyed in the past regulatory period is to be
passed on to the consumer in the first year of
the next regulatory period (X0).
51Determination of X0 Example