Prof Sudipto Bhattacharya, LSE - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 53
About This Presentation
Title:

Prof Sudipto Bhattacharya, LSE

Description:

... especially with higher size preferred, When would Sub-optimal monitoring arise? ... Arising from sub-optimal monitoring, hence third-best loss of bank capital in ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:80
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 54
Provided by: Aus73
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Prof Sudipto Bhattacharya, LSE


1
Prof Sudipto Bhattacharya, LSE
  • Banks, Liquidity Crunches (to Crises) and
    Multiple Dimensions of Moral Hazards in the
    Regulated Economy

2
I Liquidity versus Risk-Shifting
  • Banks moral hazard w.r.t under-investment in
    liquid (shorter maturity) assets, happens to be
    just QUALITATIVELY DIFFERENT from that vis-à-vis
    Excessive Risk-Taking
  • For example, lower Bank borrowing rates encourage
    over-investment in ILLIQUID longer-maturity
    assets, even with perfect secondary markets for
    these, whereas THE

3
Some Lessons for Policy Makers
  • OPPOSITE IS TRUE for RISK-SHIFTING by banks with
    (in effect) insured depositors it is HIGHER bank
    borrowing rates which lead to more/excessive
    risk-taking by them
  • Indeed, there is NO JUSTIFICATION FOR Punitive ex
    post Interest Rates on Loans to Banks judged to
    be suffering from External- caused Liquidity
    Shocks, although there IS

4
Re What to Do in out of Crises
  • A CLEAR RATIONALE FOR HAVING A CENTRAL-BANK RUN
    INTERBANK
  • BORROWING-LENDING FACILITY with
  • Clear Pre-committed Borrowing Limits, and
  • Reserve Requirements for Internal Liquidity
    Provisions at Each Member Bank, which is
    completely de-linked from Macroeconomic Price
    Stability (Bhattacharya Gale, 1987)

5
II. When a Crunch is Systemic
  • Based on Diamond and Rajan in JoF, 2005
  • Two types of Banks A with 40 of Loans repayable
    early, 60 after one period, and B with the
    opposite. Each (long-term) loan of 1 generates
    investment returns of 1.6 if not liquidated
    early, of which bankers can collect 80, or 1.28
    per loan. On the other hand, if liquidated early,
    each loan yields

6
What Should Policymakers Do?
  • 0.4 immediately, and 0.5 after one period in
    alternative uses (transfers to other owners)
  • A bad (but not necessarily disastrous!) state of
    the economy has 60 of banks in the A category,
    and 40 in the B category, where
  • Depositors have Demandable Claims, and come to
    learn about their banks states just before even
    better bank loans can be repaid

7
Support Creation of Liquidity, or
  • NON-destruction thereof, VIA MARKETS!
  • Total available resources in the banking system
    to pay depositors in the first period without
    transfering/restructuring bank loans is 0.60.4
    0.40.61.6 .768, which is INSUFFICIENT TO
    MEET DEPOSITOR DEMANDS OF UNITY, even with banks
    fortunate borrowers investing/re-depositing

8
Process of Orderly Restructuring
  • Thus 0.232 of additional liquidity MUST be
    created via restructuring of Bank Loans. Is it
    the case that (inter-bank with investors in it
    too) MARKETS WILL DO THAT OK?
  • The answer is NO at any interest rate above 1.4,
    A-type banks would be insolvent even after
    restructuring, leading to EARLY (good quality)
    LOANS being RESTRUCTURED

9
B-TYPE BANKS WONT HELP
  • Via restructuring their loans too to create
    additional short-term liquidity unless inter-
    bank interest rates rise to 1.6, BUT THAT
  • IS EXACTLY WHAT THEY WOULD DO because attempted
    (forced) Restructuring by the Run A-type BANKS
    WOULD DRAIN LIQUIDITY AWAY WHEN B-banks try to
    PARTIALLY restructure, which they must

10
IN THEIR MYOPIC ACTIONS
  • ALBEIT IN A SMALL way only in that as 60 of
    their loans realised early, their loan base, of
    repayments PLUS investment by the lucky
    borrowers, CAN contribute THE AMOUNT 0.61.6
    .96 in the first period
  • BUT THESE INVESTORS WOULD BUY THE the
    restructured A-BANK LOANS as well, so the B
    banks would need to liquidate

11
IGNORING SYSTEMIC RISKS
  • More loans, and INTEREST RATES WILL RISE ABOVE
    1.95, CAUSING THEM TO BE INSOLVENT AS WELL,
    WHEREAS
  • IF THE GOVERNMENT FACILITATED restructuring of
    loans by the more illiquid banks, at a Gross
    Interest Rate BELOW 1.4, they and its lucky
    borrowers together would need to buy .6.6.5of
    future restructured

12
ARISING FROM SPILLOVERS
  • LOAN PAYOFFS, .18 FROM UNLUCKY BANKS. THAT and
    .016 liquidity injection to B-BANKS, would be
    partially provided BY THE NON-LIQUIDATED (LUCKY)
    BORROWERS OF THE UNLUCKY A- BANKS, THUS REQUIRING
    POLICY MAKERS TO INJECT VERY LITTLE AS SUBSIDY
    TO THE UNLUCKY BANKS!

13
HOW MUCH GOVERNMENT SUBSIDY WILL BE NEEDED?
  • To preclude runs that would require them to
    restructure even their early-realised loans, A
    banks need to obtain liquidity injection of
    1-.4(1.28)- .6(0.4) 0.248 each, additional to
    cash they obtain from restructured loans.
  • If they do so with ALL late loans, B-banks will
    not need to restructure any of their late loans
    lucky borrowers will fund them anew

14
MAKING USE OF A PRIVATE CUM PUBLIC PARTNERSHIP
  • A-BANKS HAVE 0.60.5 OF FUTURE PAYOFFS FROM THE
    RESTRUCTURED LOANS TO PUT UP AS COLLATERAL.
  • FOR BUYING THESE RESTRUCTURED LOANS, THEIR LUCKY
    BORROWERS CAN PUT UP A TOTAL OF .24(.32) - .4
    .04 .061, AFTER ADDING LIQUIDITY TO FUND
    WITHDRAWAL AT B-BANKS

15
WITH HIGH SOCIAL RETURN
  • Thus the GOVERNMENT NEED ONLY PROVIDE (.6.248)
    - .061 .088, AND
  • THEREBY ENSURE INTEREST RATES DO NOT RISE ABOVE
    .3/.248 1.21, OR 21 NET, SO THAT A-BANKS STAY
    SOLVENT,i.e., THEY CAN MEET THEIR
  • DEPOSITORS EARLY WITHDRAWAL DEMANDS, OF UNITY AT
    EACH BANK

16
INSOFAR AS GOVERNMENT
  • LIQUIDITY INJECTION OF .088 EARNS THE RESPECTABLE
    RETURN OF 21 NET, AND ENDS UP PREVENTING THE
  • ADDITIONAL RESTRUCTURING OF .6 .4 .24 OF
    EARLY-REALISED LOANS
  • THIS GENERATES A SOCIAL SURPLUS OF AT LEAST .24
    (1.6 - 0.4 - 0.5).168 A SPECTACULAR POLICY
    SUCCESS!!

17
WHAT THEY AND I DONT
  • KNOW is, myopia as above aside, WHY FLIGHT TO
    QUALITY OF BANKS IN SUCH CIRCUMSTANCES IS SO
    MUCH!
  • 64 BILLION QUESTION IS is it fear of adverse
    selection on the restructured loans?
  • IT IS NOT EXPLAINABLE VIA BANKS ENSURING ADEQUATE
    CAPITAL per se

18
EXCEPT HISTORICALLY
  • WHEN even during the Great Depression in USA,
    aggregate volume of Bank Deposits in banks
    Subjected to Runs was around 5 of US Deposit
    Base, but banks as a whole
  • Reduced their Loan-to Deposit ratios, from 85 or
    so to around 55 over five years!
  • To need 30-35 in Reserves to Insure any Losses
    on 55 in Loans, seems Excessive!

19
WHAT THEY SHOULDVE KNOWN, HOWEVER IS
  • THAT, AT LEAST FACED WITH SUCH EXTREME FLIGHTS
    TO QUALITY BY
  • (LUCKIER) BANKS, OPTIMAL POLICY
  • SHOULD HAVE BEEN TARGETED NOT AUCTIONED
    LIQUIDITY INJECTIONS, SELECTIVELY TO THE LESS
    LUCKY BANKS WHO MUST RESTRUCTURE, BUT STILL FAIL
    W/O SUCH SUBSIDY

20
Recent Banking Research on
  • Loan Rollover and Credit Freezes
  • Adverse Selection Impact Funding
  • And Optimal Bank Bailout Policies

21
Allen and Gale Rollover Risks
  • Economy in One of Two States at Each of N Dates,
    then a Terminal Date at T1
  • Terminal Asset Payoffs are Zero if state then is
    S1, and V gt 0 if it is S2. Earlier,
  • Asset is Funded ONLY with Debt, which
  • Is Short-term, Subject to Default Risks
  • States Evolve as a Markov Process with

22
Given Transition Probabilities
  • P,1-P from S1 to S1, S2 and 1-Q,Q from S2
    to S1, S2 further, Q gt (1-P)
  • Pessimistic Scenario Q 1, P is small
  • If there is Default on Debt, leading to an Asset
    Sale, it realizes only a fraction f in 0,1) of
    its next period pledgeable value
  • Examine Debt Capacity when N is large

23
Maximum Debt Funding
  • At date N, given the current state is S1, equals
    V(1-P) its promised payment V
  • At date (N - 1), it becomes, based again on a
    promised repayment D2 V, B2 (1-P)V
    PfV(1-P) lt V(1 - P2), the expected value of
    Terminal asset Payoff
  • Indeed, in the Limit as N goes to Infinity

24
Holding Constant Credit Risk
  • Or Probability of Default at the Terminal Date,
    at PP(N)(N1) the Initial Debt
  • Funding Level BoV(1-P)/(1-fP), which
    Approaches 0 given flt1 P(N) tends to 1
  • In Contrast, if the Markovian evolution is
    Optimistic, with Q in (0,1) and P 1, and the
    current state is S2, Maximal Debt at

25
Depends on Current Mood
  • Funding Level at the initial date equals Bo
    Q(N1)V, or EQUAL to Asset Value given
    expected terminal payoff!
  • More generally, given BOTH P and Q in (0, 1) with
    Q gt (1-fP), following are true
  • At any date, the Maximal Debt Funding level is
    Higher when the Economy is in

26
Or, The State of the Economy
  • State S2 than when its in State S1, and
  • The sub-Sequence of Maximal Funding Levels in S2
    state are increasing across time as we approach
    the terminal date
  • Whereas, the Opposite is True for the
    sub-Sequence of Maximal Debt funding levels in S1
    state A Crash vs a Bubble?

27
The Credit Freeze Implication
  • IS FRAGILE, if some Equity Capital is Available
    as well, especially in S1 state
  • For example, in a Pessimistic Scenario with Q
    1, and P in (0,1), the borrowing
  • Level in the final period would remain at B1
    V(1-P), on promised repayment V
  • BUT, in the penultimate period, it would

28
Need Not be Always Valid
  • Be Optimal to issue only Safe Debt with Promised
    Repayment D2 B1 V(1-P), to maximize Overall
    Payoff Z2 (1-P) (V-D2)Pmax(B1- D2,0)
    Proceeds of Debt Issue given D2 debt value B2
    equals D2 only if its no higher than B1
  • With three periods left, Safe Debt with a
    Promised Repayment D3 Z2 can then

29
Funding Capacity Expands
  • Leading to Overall Value equalling Z3
    (1-P)(V-Z2) Z2, and so on, so that as
  • The number of sub-periods N goes to its limit of
    infinity, the maximal and safe debt funding level
    Bo would approach
  • The Asset Value Ao V1 - P(N)(N1)
  • Result related to Geanakoplos (2003).

30
To Equal Full Asset Value
  • As the number of periods until Maturity
    Increases, PROVIDED that sufficient equity
    capital is available, to Take Up Slack when the
    bad state S1 continues
  • It is, of course, precisely such a lack of new
    equity capital injection, arising from past
    losses as A decreases, as well as Institutional
    Behavior, that needs study

31
Implications for SPV Capital?
  • In the funding sequence derived above, the
    sequences of debt, equity and total asset (A)
    values before maturity satisfy
  • B1V(1-P) B2V(1-P) B3V(1-P2)
  • E10 E2VP(1-P) E3VP2(1-P) ..
  • A1V(1-P) A2V(1-P2) A3(1-P3) ..
  • Limiting to the Initial Values at time 0 of

32
With Infinite Debt Sequence of
  • Ao V1-P(N)(N1) Bo V1-P(N)N Eo
    VP(N)N(1-P(N)), and in the limit
  • As N tends to infinity, and P(N) to One, Credit
    Risk P 1-Ao/V P(N)(N1)
  • Hence, to keep this chain of financing with
    Equity Injections and Riskfree Debt going until
    penultimate period, Expected

33
Debt and Equity Injections
  • Sum total of lost equity injections equals
  • T VNP(N)(N1)1-P(N) which is the
    Minimum Equity needed per asset, given
    independent risks across many
  • Since LN(P) Limit of (N1)LNP(N) and, as
    P(N) tends to 1 from below then LNP(N) P(N)
    - 1, hence we obtain

34
Equity Commitment Required
  • T VP- LN(P), where P(1 - Ao/V) measures
    the (initial) credit default risk,
  • Relative to the Maximal Payoff of Asset
  • When P is SMALL, say Ao/V .95 after a small
    regime shift from an Optimistic Scenario with Q
    1 and Ao V, Note
  • T/V PLN(1/P) gtgt P same for T/Ao

35
Can Far Exceed Magnitude of
  • Long Run Default Risk of Funded Asset
  • Note that Limit T(P) as P tends to zero is
    indeed zero, employing LHospitals Rule the
    more economically meaningful
  • T(P)/Ao P-LN(P)/(1-P) always has a
    strictly positive derivative w.r.t. P
  • Plus, P ltT(P)/Aolt1 for all P in (0, 1)

36
Bolton, Santos, Scheinkman
  • Build Model combining Liquidity Shocks with
    subsequent Adverse Selection due to private
    information accruing to owner of risky asset who
    seek interim liquidity
  • Two groups of investors, less and more patient,
    with former having access to a technology having
    high expected return
  • Coupled with above timing uncertainty

37
Multiple (REE) Equilibrium
  • Involving trading by the liquidity-seeking
    impatient asset owners at different time points
    pre- or post-resolution of private information
    about future asset returns
  • Surprisingly, delayed trading equilibrium when it
    exists, is ex ante Pareto Better it leads to
    more investment by impatient agents in illiquid
    risky asset, less cash

38
Inside vs Outside Liquidity
  • In essence, greater recourse to Outside Liquidity
    in Delayed Trading equilibrium, leads to More
    Gains from Trade among patient and impatient
    agents, and hence greater ex ante expected social
    surplus, despite adverse selection in asset price
  • HOWEVER, they ignore Problems such as Interim
    Runs, within Impatient Banks

39
Bhattacharya and Nyborg
  • Look at Optimal Bank Bailout Schemes which Seek
    to Remove Debt Overhang in Banks (in worse future
    states) that impede additional investments by
    them
  • In the face of Private Information about
    Distribution of their Future Asset Values and,
    the Option Values of Their Equities
  • While Minimizing Government Subsidy

40
Asset Buyout vs New Capital
  • If (size adjusted) Supports/Ranges, but Not
    Likelihoods of Future Returns Same across Banks,
    These Two Alternatives are Equivalent, and Either
    Measure can Recapitalize Banks with Subsidy Equal
    to their Outside (Equity) Option Values
  • If NOT, and Worse Quality Banks also Have Lower
    Worst-case future returns

41
MENUS Using Both Better
  • We need to have Menu of Bailout Tools, and
    heterogeneous Banks self-selecting
  • Ex1 Banks Future Payoffs 120. or 90, with
    Likelihoods 1/2, 1/2 and 2/3, 1/3 and Debt
    Due of 100. Either Buy 1/3 of Assets for 40 OR
    Take 1/3 Equity for 10
  • Ex 2 (Menu) Bad Bank Payoffs 120, or 80 1/2
    Equity for 40/3, Assets for 110

42
Proposal S. Bhattacharya, LSE
  • Dynamic Credit Risk Transfer, and Financial
    Stability Collaborators
  • Prof John Geanakoplos, Yale, USA
  • Prof Kjell Nyborg, NHH, Norway

43
Main Issues to be Addressed
  • Impact of CRT on Monitoring Incentives of Loan
    Originators, in Varying Macro States
  • Secondary Market Trading of CRT Assets
  • Liquidity Shocks and Provision at Banks
  • Adverse Selection Effects, and Cycles, in Trading
    Liquidity Sharing among Banks
  • Resulting Shock Propagation Mechanisms

44
A CRT Monitoring (Chiesa)
  • Unlike most authors -- see the Duffie (2007)
    survey -- who judge CRT to be harmful for the
    originating banks monitoring incentives
  • Chiesa (2007) considers a set up in which
    Monitoring is Unimportant in a Good state,
    leading to (say) zero proportion of defaults, but
    it Matters in Bad states, in which default is by
    say 2 with 5 without monitoring

45
Violation of MLRP and CRT
  • Hence, with agents having SYMMETRIC beliefs on
    underlying states, realisation of 2, rather than
    0, default is indicative of bank monitoring
    Rewarding Bank Insiders, as much as feasible,
    THEN is thus Optimal
  • This is achieved by CRT, in the format of Selling
    the Most Toxic Tranch of payoff to arise from 0
    over 2 defaults, to Market

46
But, What if Monitoring Matters
  • Also in Good States, in which without it the
    default rate would be 2 instead of 0, so CRT is
    harmful for banks monitoring given good states,
    in which 0 default signals it?
  • Further, suppose Bank Insiders who provide costly
    monitoring Effort obtain Asymmetric information
    regarding realised state a period in advance,
    before choosing CRT level offer

47
Partial Transfers of Toxic Tails
  • Would now be optimal, indeed None IF the bank
    insiders obtain Perfect Information on the
    realised local macro state Good vs Bad!
  • In Dynamic contexts, with Markovian shifts across
    Good and Bad states, would Market Equilibrium
    Yield a Constrained Optimum?
  • If Not, especially with higher size preferred,
    When would Sub-optimal monitoring arise?

48
Giving Rise to Debt-Deflation
  • Cycles even Without Irrational Exuberance?
  • Arising from sub-optimal monitoring, hence
    third-best loss of bank capital in Good states
    making for Sub-optimal bank Capital levels, and
    THUS lending volume, in Bad states to follow
    inexorably, modulo serial correlation
  • Is there a Role for Bank Capital Regulation,
    above level required for ex ante incentives?

49
B. Liquidity Shocks and Adverse Selection in
Inter-Bank Markets
  • Focus on ex ante inefficiencies in portfolio
    choices of banks, e.g., Bhattacharya Gale
    (1987), Bhattacharya, Goodhart, Sunirand,
    Tsomocos (Economic Theory, 2007), with
  • Adverse Selection ex interim in Inter-Bank Loan
    cum Liquidity Provision Markets, and
  • The impact of Securitization cum Tranching of
    bank-originated loans on these processes

50
CRT as Diversification Versus
  • Net Transfer of the overall Banking System Loan
    Default Risks to Other Market Agents
  • Empirically Gross CRT position holdings of banks
    Dwarfs Net position, summed across them, by
    factor of seven to eight Duffie 07
  • However, with Demandable Deposits access to net
    outside transfer of bank loan portfolio risks
    matters in low aggregate liquidity state

51
Efficient Contingent Risk Transfers to Non-Bank
Players
  • This channel is emphasised in the work of Diamond
    and Rajan (J of Finance, 2005) in which non-bank
    investors are banks Lucky borrowers themselves
    Bank Runs Imperil Their interim Ability to
    subsequently Invest
  • Is CRT, Requiring Tranching to cope with adverse
    selection (Demarzo and Duffie), an
  • efficient Mode of interbank Diversification?

52
Non-Bank Investors and DPM
  • Other Non-Bank Participants in CRT assets are
    Funds, very often managed by delegated Portfolio
    Managers with incentive contracts
  • Can Processes of Herding, arising from say
    Reputational Concerns (Dasgupta and Prat,
  • Theoretical Economics, 2006) contribute to
    explaining extent of liquidity withdrawal in

53
Inter-bank CRT Markets when
  • Liquidity Shocks may be Confounded with
    fundamental Solvency Shocks for a subset? Witness
    the massive lowering of their loan-deposit ratios
    by US Banks overall in 30s!
  • Analogously, sharply differing flights to
    liquidity cum safety by banks, as opposed to
    security market participants, in ASEAN economies,
    during 1997-98 flow reversals
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com