Title: Finance and Banking
1Finance and Banking
- NAKE Course
- Lecture 4 Banking and Monetary Transmission
2Previous lectures have shown that..
- Loans are special as opposed to bonds private
and public assets differ in nature - Informational problems can lead to agency costs
and so induce a (higher) External Finance
Premiums - Net worth of borrowers is an important variable
in attracting new finance - Monetary transmission depends not only on the
interest rate channel but also on the bank
lending and balance sheet channel
3This lecture
- We turn to behavioral models of banks themselves
concern for the supply of loans - How do banks finance themselves? Is public
funding easy for small banks? How does the
availability of funding affect lending? - If there is relevance of the financing structure
of banks, and how does this finding affect
monetary policy? Is MM relevant to banks? - We first follow Stein (Rand Journal, 1998), next
we turn to Kashyap-Stein (2000) and conclude with
the bank capital channel by Van den Heuvel (2002)
4General notions (1)
- Banks attract deposits (insurable assets) and
non-deposits (debt and equity). Moreover they
generate equity capital via retained profits.
Romer-Romer (1990) argue that the financial
structure is indifferent (Modigliani-Miller for
banks). In that case lending is not affected by
reductions in reservable assets - On the other hand debt might be a problem see
Stein (1998) and Kashyap-Stein (1995, 2000).
Lending might be reduced after a reduction of
deposit finance - Equity might be a problem dividends need to be
positive Van den Heuvel (debt has a tax advance
over equity. Excessive equity accumulation is too
expensive (but required in order to face capital
restrictions)
5General notions (2)
- Deposit (or insured) finance is influenced by
monetary policy. A drop in deposit finance will
affect bank balance sheet decisions - Choice between reducing private assets (loans) or
public assets (securities) or attract more
noninsured liabilities (bonds) - Informational costs might affect these decisions.
Informational costs depend e.g. on bank size - What is the main informational problem?
Opaqueness of the value of bank assets (including
capital). This opaqueness can lead to adverse
selction
6Stein (1998)
- How do banks allocate their assets among loans
and securities and how do these allocations
respond to shocks in the availability of insured
deposit finance? - How do nonfinancial firms choose between bank and
nonbank sources of debt finance? - How does monetary transmission work, assuming
that the central bank can influence both the
interest rate level and the EFP?
7Stein (1)
- Adverse selection model of bank asset and
liability management. Bank management knows more
about the value of the banks assets than private
investors do - If the bank is able to finance itself fully with
insured deposits, there will be no problems
(lending is undistorted), but with uninsured
finance there are informational difficulties
(adverse selection in Stein) - Stein gives a model of bank portfolio choice, the
choice between bank- and non-bank debt, and
implications for monetary policy - Main result banks with a higher potential to a
better future ultimate capital position are more
prone to a loss of insured reserves and will lend
relatively less. The intuition is that bad
banks have nothing to loose and simply keep on
lending out. Banks with more informational
problems tend to be more sensitive to shocks
8Partial equilibrium bank model (1)
- First one-period version of the model
- Bank assets reserves R, new loans L, old assets
K. Liabilities insured deposits M, previously
raised non-deposit finance P, and incremental
non-deposit finance E. It is easy to assume that
K P. R ? ?M, where ? is the fractional reserve
requirement on insured deposits - L R M E, or L ? M(1 - ?) E
- Banks are assumed to be monopolists in the loan
market and face a loan demand LD a br, where
r is the loan rate (spread between loans and
securities). We assume the expected return on M
and E to be fixed to 0
9Partial equilibrium bank model (2)
- Asymmetric information about the value of old
assets K. Good banks (G) hold capital that will
ultimately be worth KH gt KL and bad banks (B)
KL. Define a measure of information asymmetry A
1 KL / KH. A higher A indicates more
informational problems, e.g. a small bank - Suppose M falls exogenously
- There will be a so-called unique separating
equilibrium the good and the bad are separated
in equilibrium through the design of the
contract. Main intuition the bad case proceeds
as ever, the good case adjusts - Type B maximizes interest income rL, so LB a/2
(from the profit maximizing interest rate r
a/2b) and must raise EB max(0, a/2 - M(1- ?))
10Partial equilibrium bank model (3)
- Type G raises less external finance and lends
less LG LB - Z. Z is underlending. It raises
less external finance EG EB Z. Type Gs
equity is worth more - Profit of G is ?G (a/2 Z)(a/(2b) Z/b)
?B Z2/b - Type B can try to mimic G. Profits will then
fall ?G ?B Z2/b. But it can sell overpriced
equity. This gain is equal to AEG. So Z2/b AEG.
This describes a non-mimicking equilibrium.
Remember A 1 KL / KH
11Partial equilibrium bank model (4)
- How big is Z?
- Z2/b AEG A(EB - Z), so
Z2 bAZ - bA EB 0, which is a quadratic
function in Z - So type B will use uninsured external finance
fully and leave lending unchanged. Type G are
reluctant to use external finance
12Partial equilibrium bank model (3)
- So if deposits are abundant, both types will lend
at the first-best levels - But if deposits fall short, bad banks will use
external finance fully. Good banks will be
reluctant to do so, and finance a fraction of the
shortfall and so reduce lending - So dLG/dM gt 0 and d2LG/dMdA gt 0. Good banks are
more sensitive to a larger degree of information
asymmetry. So small but good banks are sensitive
to deposit shocks
13Kashyap-Stein (Carnegie-Rochester, 1995) (1)
- Banks face an adverse selection problem in the
market for uninsured external finance - Two period model a simple way to model
precautionary or buffer stock motives to hold
securities in the first period - Loans cannot be liquidated at time 2 (and no new
lending opportunities arise at time 2).
Securities (no return, normalized to 0) can
costlessly be liquidated in period 2 and so give
a liquidity yield - Yield on loans is the loans-securities spread
14Kashyap-Stein (2)
- Again a partial equilibrium model of bank
portfolio behavior - Insured deposit supply (M1 at time 1 and M2 at
time 2) is completely out of control for banks
(and determined by the central bank) - Three possibilities for the bank in case of a
contraction of M1 (1) reduce supply of loans Ls,
(2) raise non-deposit finance E (we denote the
incremental amounts by E1 and E2), or (3) sell
securities S
15Simple balance sheet of banks
- Deposits M
- Non-deposits E
16Stochastics of deposits M
- M is stochastic a long-term unconditional mean
M, persistence ? and uniform distribution with a
variance ? - Given M1, M2 is uniformly distributed on the
interval
?M1 (1 - ?)m - ?/2,
?M1 (1 ?)m ?/2 - EM2 ?M1 (1 - ?)m
- VarM2 ?²/12, since the variance of a variable
that is uniformly distributed on the interval
a,b is equal to (b - a)²/12
17Non-deposits E
- At time 2 the total amount of non-deposit finance
is E1 E2. E1 can be raised at increasing
marginal costs ?1E1²/2, ?1 needs to be positive
in order to have a lending channel E2 has costs
?2E2²/2 - r is the interest rate on loans. r - rE must be
positive. Otherwise there is no lending channel.
We assume rE 0 - Lemons premium makes that ?1 and ?2 are probably
larger for smaller banks - For ?i 0 (i 1,2) we have Modigliani-Miller
- We could use adverse selection models (like
Stein, 1998) or costly state verification models
(Froot, Scharfstein, Stein, 1993) to get
quadratic cost functions as well
18Securities
- Banks use securities S as a buffer in order to
prevent the inefficient liquidation of loans - Loans are more profitable r gt rS (rS 0 for
convenience) - If E1 M2 gt L there is no problem and E2 0
- If E1 M2 lt L banks have to attract
E2 L - E1 - M2 - So E2 max(0, L - E1 - M2)
19Net revenue for banks
- Maximize expected profits on t 1
rL - ?1E1²/2 - E?2E2²/2 with respect to
E1, L, S - E?2E2²/2 ?2(L - E1 - ?M1 - (1 - ?)m ?
/2)²/6 (see the proof on the next slide) - E1 r / ?1 the marginal costs of obtaing
additional funds return - L r / ?1 3r / ?2 ?M1 (1 - ?)m - ?/2
if the ?-parameters become small
loan supply becomes more elastic more
uncertainty (a higher ?) reduces supply - S M1 E1 - L -3r / ?2 (1 - ?)(M1 - m) ?/2
20Derivation of the expected costs
- E?2E2²/2 ?2(L - E1 - ?M1 - (1-?)m ?/2)²/6
- E2 max0, L - E1 - M2
- Use M2 ?M1 (1 - ?)m - ?/2
- We are interested in the properties of
L - E1 - ?M1 - (1 - ?)m ?/2 on a uniform
interval - EE2 (L - E1 - ?M1 - (1 - ?)m ?/2)/2 and
varE2 (L - E1 - ?M1 - (1 - ?)m ?/2)²/12 - Use EX² varX EX²
21Results
- Non-deposit sources E1 depends positively on r
but negatively on the costs ?1. Large banks
probably attract more non-deposits - Loan supply depends positively on the available
amount of deposits M1 and the spread r, but
negatively on ?1 and ?2. Large banks respond more
to the spread. - Securities depend negatively on the spread r and
positively on the costs
22Equilibrium with a competitive homogeneous loan
market
- Loan demand Ld depends on general conditions Y
and the interest rate r Ld Y kr - We assume that a change in monetary stance has an
identical impact on bank i and j dM1i dM1j - Differentiate the equations we derived before wrt
M1 - dLi / dM1 (1/?1i 3/?2i) dr / dM1 ?
- dSi / dM1 -3/?2i dr / dM1 (1-?)
- dr / dM1 a dY / dM1 b, with a and b positive.
If dY / dM1 is small, dr / dM1 lt
0 the lending channel - Things become more complicated with heterogeneous
loan demand
23Testable hypotheses
- dLi / dM1 (1/?1i 3/?2i) dr / dM1 ?
- dSi / dM1 -3/?2i dr / dM1 (1 - ?)
- Smaller banks have larger ?s. So
- Proposition 1 The lending volume of small banks
falls more rapidly after a given contraction in
deposits (due to higher costs of adjustment) - Proposition 2 The securities holdings of small
banks falls more slowly after a contraction in
deposits (small banks value securities more at
the margin and are less willing to reduce them)
24Is it credit supply or demand?
- Is it so that after a restriction of monetary
policy the quantity of credit decreases through a
decrease in demand or supply? - Evidence on the macro level if the interest
spread increases it is probably a fall of supply - Evidence on the micro level if small banks react
more strongly than large banks it would be a
large coincidence
25Four Kashyap-Stein hypotheses
- d²L / dM dSize lt 0 smaller banks are more
sensitive to a reduction in deposits dL / dM - d²S / dM dSize lt 0 small banks are more
sensitive in adjusting securities dS / dM - d²L / dS dM lt 0 monetary policy has more effect
on lending behavior of banks with less liquid
balance sheets - d³L / dS dM dSize lt 0 for large banks financial
structure is less important
26Stein (1998, part 2) (1)
- A two-period adverse selection model
- A bank holds about 30-40 per cent of its assets
in liquidity and securities in Stein, part 1, we
abstracted from liquidity in securities - The bank faces an adverse selection problem in
the market for uninsured external finance in each
of the two periods. It might buffer using
liquidity - Securities held at time 1 can costlessly be
liquidated at time 2. It is costly to liquidate
loans an amount J (jettison, Dutch overboord
gooien) costs ?J2
27Stein (part 2) (2)
- Banks fund themselves with insured deposits M1
and M2 and common equity E - Stochastic structure of deposits is similar to
the above one Given M1, M2 is uniformly
distributed on the interval - ?M1 (1 - ?)M - ?/2, ?M1 (1 - ?)m ?/2
- EM2 ?M1(1 - ?)m. m is the unconditional
mean, ? defines the persistence of shocks - VarM2 ?²/12, so ? is the variance measure
28Stein (part 2) (3)
- E1 and E2 are the incremental amounts of external
finance raised. - r is the return on loans, all other returns are
equal to 0 - Balance sheet restrictions
- L S ? M1(1 - ?) E1 at time 1
- L J ? M2(1 - ?) E1 E2 at time 2
29Stein (part 2) (4)
- There is asymmetric information about the
ultimate value of the old assets K. The value of
K develops to a binomial process - K0 is unconditional value. After time1 a public
signal arrives. If the signal is good, with
probability p, the value of the assets rises to
uK0 with u gt 1. If the signal is bad (with (1 -
p)) to dK0 with d lt 1. Outside investors observe
the signal after period 1, but bank managers know
in advance, when making lending and financing
decisions at period 1. At time 2 a second public
signal arrives (maybe to d2K0 or u2K0). Define A
1 - d/u. A larger A again indicates more
informational problems
30Stein (part 2) (5)
- Type G bank any bank whose private information
(either at time 1 or 2) leads it to expect an
increase in the value of K when the next public
signal is released (and a type B bank the other
way round) - Define SF(M1) by that value of securities
holdings that is sufficient to insulate a bank
(not necessary to cut loans or raise new
securities funding) SF(M1) (1- ?)(M1 - m)(1 -
?) ?/2
31Stein Lemma 1
- A type B bank will hold SB ? SF(M1) and so will
lend at the first best. Type B will raise an
amount of external finance at time 1 E1B
max(a/2-(1- ?)?M1 (1 - ?)m - ?/2,0) - Illustration of the proof hereafter
32Stein Lemma 2
- Suppose that E1B ? 0. Then a bank type G at time
1 will have SG lt SF(M1). So bank G will not fully
insulate loan supply - Bank G will also lend less than bank B
- So bank G will cut lending if M decreases
- The link between M and LG is stringer when the
information asymmetry A increases
33Solving the two-period model (1)
- The model can be solved backwards (start at time
2). Remember we have good (G) and bad (B) banks - We again look for a separating equilibrium
- Type B will raise at time 2 EB max(0,L - E1 -
M2(1 - ?)), just enough not to liquidate loans - Type G will raise at time 2 E2G E2B J
- The incentive constraint is, like before, ?J2
AE2G, from which we can solve for J - When do we liquidate (as expected at time 1)? If
short L - E1 (1- ?)(?M1 (1 - ?)m - ?/2) lt
0 - Expected costs of liquidation X p C(short),
where p is the probability of an up move (and so
being a G) and C(.) a convex cost function (with
C(0) 0)
34Solving the two-period model (2)
- Now we turn to period 1
- Type B lends LB a/2 (remember loan demand LD
a - br). Type B just maximizes lending profit.
Type B will also raise enough external funds at
time 1 so that it never has to raise further
external funds at time 2. This amount is - SF(M1) (1- ?)(M1 - m)(1 - ?) ?/2. A bank
that is type B at time 1 will hold SB SF(M1) - We have LB SB ? M1(1 - ?) E1B at time 1
- a/2 (1- ?)(M1 - m)(1 - ?) ?/2 ? M1(1 - ?)
E1B - So E1B max(a/2 - (1- ?)?M1 (1 - ?)m -
?/2,0) and XB 0 (XB the expected
costs of liquidation for bank B)
35The consequences
- If E1B gt 0, a G-type bank in period 1 will have
SG lt SF(M1), so hold less than full-insurance and
lend less than the first-best a/2. Securities
holdings are discouraged by adverse selection in
the time 1 market - If E1B gt 0, type G will react to a decrease in M1
by reducing lending and d2LG/dM1dA gt 0 if loan
demand is rather inelastic - So, again informational asymmetries determine
both lending and financing behavior
36The Bank Capital Channel
- Traditional monetary theories focus on the role
of reserves in determining the volume of demand
deposits. The bank lending channel analyzes the
role of reserves in loan supply - Van den Heuvel (2002) discusses the role of (an
imperfect market for) bank equity. He assumes a
perfect market for debt - Lending will depend on the financial structure of
the bank. The model also focuses on the maturity
mismatch of assets and liabilities - Conclusion lending by banks with low capital has
a delayed, but amplified, reaction to interest
rate shocks
37Heuvel (1)
- The model includes capital adequacy regulations.
The Basle accord established minimum capital
requirements - The bank cannot readily issue new equity. But
equity capital is endogenous through retained
earnings - There is a tax advantage on debt (earnings are
taxed at a rate ? gt 0) - Banks perform maturity transformation, leading to
a serious interest rate risk. Banks are
leveraged (compared to real firms), such that an
interest rate increase results in a larger
percentage change in equity (given that there is
a profit squeeze)
38Heuvel (2)
- Assets loans L and securities S liabilities
debt B and equity E. A L S B E - The bank issues Nt new loans at the beginning of
each period. Each period a fraction ?u lt 1 is
due. 1/ ?u is the loan portfolios average
maturity. ?t1 is the fraction of loans actually
repaid at the end of t (and can deviate from the
due rate) - Loans are risky a fraction ?t1 of outstanding
loans Lt goes bad as well as a fraction bt1 of
the new loans Nt - Lt1 (1 - ?t1 - ?t1) Lt (1 - ?t1 bt1)Nt
39Heuvel (3)
- Downward sloping demand curve for loans some
market power on part of the bank (due to whatever
reason) - Contractual interest rate on new loans is a
decreasing function of the amount of new loans
made Nt ?(Nt) and ?(.) lt 0 - The average contractual interest rate on all
outstanding loans in period t, ?at is given by - ?at1 (1-?t1-?t1)Lt ?at(1-?t1bt1)Nt
?(Nt) /Lt1 - bt1 b(Nt, ?t1) and b(.,.) increases in N
40Heuvel (4)
- Banks debt B is all short. Loans have a maturity
longer than one, so there is a maturity mismatch - The bank can borrow liquidity freely at a rate rt
- Only B - S can be determined, so tradable
securities S 0 is assumed - No role for reservable or demand deposits (a bank
can borrow/lend freely at the riskless rate r) - Banks have perfect access to insured and
nonreversable deposits contracts (and this is not
the case in the basic bank lending channel models)
41Heuvel (5)
- Accounting value of equity Et Lt - Bt
- Equity evolves according to Et1 Et - Dt (1
- ?)?t1 Dt dividends paid out and ?t1
pre-tax accounting profits interest income on
loans minus interest paid on banks debt net
charge-offs on loans - ?t1 ?at(1 - ?t1)Lt (1 - bt1)Nt ?(Nt)
rt(Lt Et Nt Dt) - (?t1Lt bt1Nt)
?F - ?F represents othe profit components
42Heuvel (6) debt
- Law of motion of debt. Note that debt has a tax
advantage - Bt1 (1(1-?)rt)(Bt Nt Dt) - ?t1(Lt Nt )
(1- ?)(?at(1-?t1)Lt (1-bt1)Nt ?(Nt) ?F) -
?(?t1Lt bt1Nt ) - Interest costs are discounted by (1 - ?), ?t1 is
the fraction of loans actually repaid at the end
of t, net of tax interest receipts and the tax
shield from charge-offs on loans
43Heuvel (7) bank balance sheet (including new
loans and dividend)
- Assets
- Loans Lt Nt
- Securities St ?St
- Total At Nt ?St
- Liabilities
- Debt Bt Nt ?St Dt
- Equity Et - Dt
- Total At Nt ?St
44Heuvel (8) capital regulation
- Basle loans are in the highest risk category,
mortgages and residential property have a risk
weight of 50 and riskless securities in 0.
Basle sets ?, the regulatory minimum, equal to
0.04 for tier 1 capital and 0.08 for tier 2 - The risk adjusted capital asset ratio RACAR at
the beginning of the period RACARt Et / Lt - If Et gt ?Lt then Et - Dt ? ?(Lt Nt)
- If Et lt ?Lt then Nt 0 and Dt 0 no new loans
and no dividends
45Heuvel (9) financial constraint
- The bank cannot issue new equity, this implies
that dividends must be nonnegative Dt ? 0 - Shareholders do not price the risk of bank shares
(risk neutral valuation) - Market value of bank equity is
- Vt max Et?s0?( ?u0s-1(1 rtu)-1)Dts
- So the problem is to maximize the market value of
the bank subject to the constraints listed above.
The bank assumes the interest rate rt, the
repayment rate ?t and the fraction ?t of
outstanding loans Lt that goes bad as given
46Heuvel (10) optimization
- State variables st (Et, Lt, ?at, rt). Control
variables Dt and Nt - Bellman equation V(st) maxDt 1/(1 rt) Et
V(st1) - Without the financial constraint we have VU. The
lending decision is then independent of the
financial position of the bank. The optimal
policy functions of the unconstrained problem are
NU(st) and DU(st) - NU(st) is NU(rt) only the interest rate matters
MM! Optimal financial policy is to keep the risk
adjusted capital ratio exactly to the minimum
DU(st) Et - ?(Lt
NU(rt)) - Since the bank can always raise capital there is
no need to hold a costly precautionary buffer of
capital above the regulatory minimum
47Heuvel (11) constrained
- A constrained bank can lend at the unconstrained
level NU(rt) if it starts its period with
sufficient capital Et ? ?(Lt
NU(rt)) - Holding the additional equity is costly (debt is
cheaper due to taxation), but will lead to a
smaller likelihood that the financial constraint
will bind. The bank should have Et-1 - Dt-1
sufficiently high to ensure that Et ? ?(Lt
NU(rt)) for all realizations of rt, ?t, and ?t - There is a tradeoff between holding more equity
against the tax disadvantage - The optimal trade-off involves a positive
probability of being financially constrained (see
Heuvel for a proof) - It is not the case that financially constrained
banks will always lend less N(st) ? NU(rt)
48Summary
- This lecture provides basic models of bank
behavior under constraints - Constraints lead to relevance of financial
structure and more complicated impact of monetary
policy - Constraints differ in nature for instance the
inability to raise new equity or the costs
involved to liquidate loans