Finance and Banking - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 48
About This Presentation
Title:

Finance and Banking

Description:

Informational problems can lead to agency costs and so induce a (higher) ... costly to liquidate loans: an amount J (jettison, Dutch: overboord gooien) costs ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:33
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 49
Provided by: ster8
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Finance and Banking


1
Finance and Banking
  • NAKE Course
  • Lecture 4 Banking and Monetary Transmission

2
Previous lectures have shown that..
  • Loans are special as opposed to bonds private
    and public assets differ in nature
  • Informational problems can lead to agency costs
    and so induce a (higher) External Finance
    Premiums
  • Net worth of borrowers is an important variable
    in attracting new finance
  • Monetary transmission depends not only on the
    interest rate channel but also on the bank
    lending and balance sheet channel

3
This lecture
  • We turn to behavioral models of banks themselves
    concern for the supply of loans
  • How do banks finance themselves? Is public
    funding easy for small banks? How does the
    availability of funding affect lending?
  • If there is relevance of the financing structure
    of banks, and how does this finding affect
    monetary policy? Is MM relevant to banks?
  • We first follow Stein (Rand Journal, 1998), next
    we turn to Kashyap-Stein (2000) and conclude with
    the bank capital channel by Van den Heuvel (2002)

4
General notions (1)
  • Banks attract deposits (insurable assets) and
    non-deposits (debt and equity). Moreover they
    generate equity capital via retained profits.
    Romer-Romer (1990) argue that the financial
    structure is indifferent (Modigliani-Miller for
    banks). In that case lending is not affected by
    reductions in reservable assets
  • On the other hand debt might be a problem see
    Stein (1998) and Kashyap-Stein (1995, 2000).
    Lending might be reduced after a reduction of
    deposit finance
  • Equity might be a problem dividends need to be
    positive Van den Heuvel (debt has a tax advance
    over equity. Excessive equity accumulation is too
    expensive (but required in order to face capital
    restrictions)

5
General notions (2)
  • Deposit (or insured) finance is influenced by
    monetary policy. A drop in deposit finance will
    affect bank balance sheet decisions
  • Choice between reducing private assets (loans) or
    public assets (securities) or attract more
    noninsured liabilities (bonds)
  • Informational costs might affect these decisions.
    Informational costs depend e.g. on bank size
  • What is the main informational problem?
    Opaqueness of the value of bank assets (including
    capital). This opaqueness can lead to adverse
    selction

6
Stein (1998)
  • How do banks allocate their assets among loans
    and securities and how do these allocations
    respond to shocks in the availability of insured
    deposit finance?
  • How do nonfinancial firms choose between bank and
    nonbank sources of debt finance?
  • How does monetary transmission work, assuming
    that the central bank can influence both the
    interest rate level and the EFP?

7
Stein (1)
  • Adverse selection model of bank asset and
    liability management. Bank management knows more
    about the value of the banks assets than private
    investors do
  • If the bank is able to finance itself fully with
    insured deposits, there will be no problems
    (lending is undistorted), but with uninsured
    finance there are informational difficulties
    (adverse selection in Stein)
  • Stein gives a model of bank portfolio choice, the
    choice between bank- and non-bank debt, and
    implications for monetary policy
  • Main result banks with a higher potential to a
    better future ultimate capital position are more
    prone to a loss of insured reserves and will lend
    relatively less. The intuition is that bad
    banks have nothing to loose and simply keep on
    lending out. Banks with more informational
    problems tend to be more sensitive to shocks

8
Partial equilibrium bank model (1)
  • First one-period version of the model
  • Bank assets reserves R, new loans L, old assets
    K. Liabilities insured deposits M, previously
    raised non-deposit finance P, and incremental
    non-deposit finance E. It is easy to assume that
    K P. R ? ?M, where ? is the fractional reserve
    requirement on insured deposits
  • L R M E, or L ? M(1 - ?) E
  • Banks are assumed to be monopolists in the loan
    market and face a loan demand LD a br, where
    r is the loan rate (spread between loans and
    securities). We assume the expected return on M
    and E to be fixed to 0

9
Partial equilibrium bank model (2)
  • Asymmetric information about the value of old
    assets K. Good banks (G) hold capital that will
    ultimately be worth KH gt KL and bad banks (B)
    KL. Define a measure of information asymmetry A
    1 KL / KH. A higher A indicates more
    informational problems, e.g. a small bank
  • Suppose M falls exogenously
  • There will be a so-called unique separating
    equilibrium the good and the bad are separated
    in equilibrium through the design of the
    contract. Main intuition the bad case proceeds
    as ever, the good case adjusts
  • Type B maximizes interest income rL, so LB a/2
    (from the profit maximizing interest rate r
    a/2b) and must raise EB max(0, a/2 - M(1- ?))

10
Partial equilibrium bank model (3)
  • Type G raises less external finance and lends
    less LG LB - Z. Z is underlending. It raises
    less external finance EG EB Z. Type Gs
    equity is worth more
  • Profit of G is ?G (a/2 Z)(a/(2b) Z/b)
    ?B Z2/b
  • Type B can try to mimic G. Profits will then
    fall ?G ?B Z2/b. But it can sell overpriced
    equity. This gain is equal to AEG. So Z2/b AEG.
    This describes a non-mimicking equilibrium.
    Remember A 1 KL / KH

11
Partial equilibrium bank model (4)
  • How big is Z?
  • Z2/b AEG A(EB - Z), so
    Z2 bAZ - bA EB 0, which is a quadratic
    function in Z
  • So type B will use uninsured external finance
    fully and leave lending unchanged. Type G are
    reluctant to use external finance

12
Partial equilibrium bank model (3)
  • So if deposits are abundant, both types will lend
    at the first-best levels
  • But if deposits fall short, bad banks will use
    external finance fully. Good banks will be
    reluctant to do so, and finance a fraction of the
    shortfall and so reduce lending
  • So dLG/dM gt 0 and d2LG/dMdA gt 0. Good banks are
    more sensitive to a larger degree of information
    asymmetry. So small but good banks are sensitive
    to deposit shocks

13
Kashyap-Stein (Carnegie-Rochester, 1995) (1)
  • Banks face an adverse selection problem in the
    market for uninsured external finance
  • Two period model a simple way to model
    precautionary or buffer stock motives to hold
    securities in the first period
  • Loans cannot be liquidated at time 2 (and no new
    lending opportunities arise at time 2).
    Securities (no return, normalized to 0) can
    costlessly be liquidated in period 2 and so give
    a liquidity yield
  • Yield on loans is the loans-securities spread

14
Kashyap-Stein (2)
  • Again a partial equilibrium model of bank
    portfolio behavior
  • Insured deposit supply (M1 at time 1 and M2 at
    time 2) is completely out of control for banks
    (and determined by the central bank)
  • Three possibilities for the bank in case of a
    contraction of M1 (1) reduce supply of loans Ls,
    (2) raise non-deposit finance E (we denote the
    incremental amounts by E1 and E2), or (3) sell
    securities S

15
Simple balance sheet of banks
  • Loans Ls
  • Securities S
  • Deposits M
  • Non-deposits E

16
Stochastics of deposits M
  • M is stochastic a long-term unconditional mean
    M, persistence ? and uniform distribution with a
    variance ?
  • Given M1, M2 is uniformly distributed on the
    interval
    ?M1 (1 - ?)m - ?/2,
    ?M1 (1 ?)m ?/2
  • EM2 ?M1 (1 - ?)m
  • VarM2 ?²/12, since the variance of a variable
    that is uniformly distributed on the interval
    a,b is equal to (b - a)²/12

17
Non-deposits E
  • At time 2 the total amount of non-deposit finance
    is E1 E2. E1 can be raised at increasing
    marginal costs ?1E1²/2, ?1 needs to be positive
    in order to have a lending channel E2 has costs
    ?2E2²/2
  • r is the interest rate on loans. r - rE must be
    positive. Otherwise there is no lending channel.
    We assume rE 0
  • Lemons premium makes that ?1 and ?2 are probably
    larger for smaller banks
  • For ?i 0 (i 1,2) we have Modigliani-Miller
  • We could use adverse selection models (like
    Stein, 1998) or costly state verification models
    (Froot, Scharfstein, Stein, 1993) to get
    quadratic cost functions as well

18
Securities
  • Banks use securities S as a buffer in order to
    prevent the inefficient liquidation of loans
  • Loans are more profitable r gt rS (rS 0 for
    convenience)
  • If E1 M2 gt L there is no problem and E2 0
  • If E1 M2 lt L banks have to attract
    E2 L - E1 - M2
  • So E2 max(0, L - E1 - M2)

19
Net revenue for banks
  • Maximize expected profits on t 1
    rL - ?1E1²/2 - E?2E2²/2 with respect to
    E1, L, S
  • E?2E2²/2 ?2(L - E1 - ?M1 - (1 - ?)m ?
    /2)²/6 (see the proof on the next slide)
  • E1 r / ?1 the marginal costs of obtaing
    additional funds return
  • L r / ?1 3r / ?2 ?M1 (1 - ?)m - ?/2
    if the ?-parameters become small
    loan supply becomes more elastic more
    uncertainty (a higher ?) reduces supply
  • S M1 E1 - L -3r / ?2 (1 - ?)(M1 - m) ?/2

20
Derivation of the expected costs
  • E?2E2²/2 ?2(L - E1 - ?M1 - (1-?)m ?/2)²/6
  • E2 max0, L - E1 - M2
  • Use M2 ?M1 (1 - ?)m - ?/2
  • We are interested in the properties of
    L - E1 - ?M1 - (1 - ?)m ?/2 on a uniform
    interval
  • EE2 (L - E1 - ?M1 - (1 - ?)m ?/2)/2 and
    varE2 (L - E1 - ?M1 - (1 - ?)m ?/2)²/12
  • Use EX² varX EX²

21
Results
  • Non-deposit sources E1 depends positively on r
    but negatively on the costs ?1. Large banks
    probably attract more non-deposits
  • Loan supply depends positively on the available
    amount of deposits M1 and the spread r, but
    negatively on ?1 and ?2. Large banks respond more
    to the spread.
  • Securities depend negatively on the spread r and
    positively on the costs

22
Equilibrium with a competitive homogeneous loan
market
  • Loan demand Ld depends on general conditions Y
    and the interest rate r Ld Y kr
  • We assume that a change in monetary stance has an
    identical impact on bank i and j dM1i dM1j
  • Differentiate the equations we derived before wrt
    M1
  • dLi / dM1 (1/?1i 3/?2i) dr / dM1 ?
  • dSi / dM1 -3/?2i dr / dM1 (1-?)
  • dr / dM1 a dY / dM1 b, with a and b positive.
    If dY / dM1 is small, dr / dM1 lt
    0 the lending channel
  • Things become more complicated with heterogeneous
    loan demand

23
Testable hypotheses
  • dLi / dM1 (1/?1i 3/?2i) dr / dM1 ?
  • dSi / dM1 -3/?2i dr / dM1 (1 - ?)
  • Smaller banks have larger ?s. So
  • Proposition 1 The lending volume of small banks
    falls more rapidly after a given contraction in
    deposits (due to higher costs of adjustment)
  • Proposition 2 The securities holdings of small
    banks falls more slowly after a contraction in
    deposits (small banks value securities more at
    the margin and are less willing to reduce them)

24
Is it credit supply or demand?
  • Is it so that after a restriction of monetary
    policy the quantity of credit decreases through a
    decrease in demand or supply?
  • Evidence on the macro level if the interest
    spread increases it is probably a fall of supply
  • Evidence on the micro level if small banks react
    more strongly than large banks it would be a
    large coincidence

25
Four Kashyap-Stein hypotheses
  • d²L / dM dSize lt 0 smaller banks are more
    sensitive to a reduction in deposits dL / dM
  • d²S / dM dSize lt 0 small banks are more
    sensitive in adjusting securities dS / dM
  • d²L / dS dM lt 0 monetary policy has more effect
    on lending behavior of banks with less liquid
    balance sheets
  • d³L / dS dM dSize lt 0 for large banks financial
    structure is less important

26
Stein (1998, part 2) (1)
  • A two-period adverse selection model
  • A bank holds about 30-40 per cent of its assets
    in liquidity and securities in Stein, part 1, we
    abstracted from liquidity in securities
  • The bank faces an adverse selection problem in
    the market for uninsured external finance in each
    of the two periods. It might buffer using
    liquidity
  • Securities held at time 1 can costlessly be
    liquidated at time 2. It is costly to liquidate
    loans an amount J (jettison, Dutch overboord
    gooien) costs ?J2

27
Stein (part 2) (2)
  • Banks fund themselves with insured deposits M1
    and M2 and common equity E
  • Stochastic structure of deposits is similar to
    the above one Given M1, M2 is uniformly
    distributed on the interval
  • ?M1 (1 - ?)M - ?/2, ?M1 (1 - ?)m ?/2
  • EM2 ?M1(1 - ?)m. m is the unconditional
    mean, ? defines the persistence of shocks
  • VarM2 ?²/12, so ? is the variance measure

28
Stein (part 2) (3)
  • E1 and E2 are the incremental amounts of external
    finance raised.
  • r is the return on loans, all other returns are
    equal to 0
  • Balance sheet restrictions
  • L S ? M1(1 - ?) E1 at time 1
  • L J ? M2(1 - ?) E1 E2 at time 2

29
Stein (part 2) (4)
  • There is asymmetric information about the
    ultimate value of the old assets K. The value of
    K develops to a binomial process
  • K0 is unconditional value. After time1 a public
    signal arrives. If the signal is good, with
    probability p, the value of the assets rises to
    uK0 with u gt 1. If the signal is bad (with (1 -
    p)) to dK0 with d lt 1. Outside investors observe
    the signal after period 1, but bank managers know
    in advance, when making lending and financing
    decisions at period 1. At time 2 a second public
    signal arrives (maybe to d2K0 or u2K0). Define A
    1 - d/u. A larger A again indicates more
    informational problems

30
Stein (part 2) (5)
  • Type G bank any bank whose private information
    (either at time 1 or 2) leads it to expect an
    increase in the value of K when the next public
    signal is released (and a type B bank the other
    way round)
  • Define SF(M1) by that value of securities
    holdings that is sufficient to insulate a bank
    (not necessary to cut loans or raise new
    securities funding) SF(M1) (1- ?)(M1 - m)(1 -
    ?) ?/2

31
Stein Lemma 1
  • A type B bank will hold SB ? SF(M1) and so will
    lend at the first best. Type B will raise an
    amount of external finance at time 1 E1B
    max(a/2-(1- ?)?M1 (1 - ?)m - ?/2,0)
  • Illustration of the proof hereafter

32
Stein Lemma 2
  • Suppose that E1B ? 0. Then a bank type G at time
    1 will have SG lt SF(M1). So bank G will not fully
    insulate loan supply
  • Bank G will also lend less than bank B
  • So bank G will cut lending if M decreases
  • The link between M and LG is stringer when the
    information asymmetry A increases

33
Solving the two-period model (1)
  • The model can be solved backwards (start at time
    2). Remember we have good (G) and bad (B) banks
  • We again look for a separating equilibrium
  • Type B will raise at time 2 EB max(0,L - E1 -
    M2(1 - ?)), just enough not to liquidate loans
  • Type G will raise at time 2 E2G E2B J
  • The incentive constraint is, like before, ?J2
    AE2G, from which we can solve for J
  • When do we liquidate (as expected at time 1)? If
    short L - E1 (1- ?)(?M1 (1 - ?)m - ?/2) lt
    0
  • Expected costs of liquidation X p C(short),
    where p is the probability of an up move (and so
    being a G) and C(.) a convex cost function (with
    C(0) 0)

34
Solving the two-period model (2)
  • Now we turn to period 1
  • Type B lends LB a/2 (remember loan demand LD
    a - br). Type B just maximizes lending profit.
    Type B will also raise enough external funds at
    time 1 so that it never has to raise further
    external funds at time 2. This amount is
  • SF(M1) (1- ?)(M1 - m)(1 - ?) ?/2. A bank
    that is type B at time 1 will hold SB SF(M1)
  • We have LB SB ? M1(1 - ?) E1B at time 1
  • a/2 (1- ?)(M1 - m)(1 - ?) ?/2 ? M1(1 - ?)
    E1B
  • So E1B max(a/2 - (1- ?)?M1 (1 - ?)m -
    ?/2,0) and XB 0 (XB the expected
    costs of liquidation for bank B)

35
The consequences
  • If E1B gt 0, a G-type bank in period 1 will have
    SG lt SF(M1), so hold less than full-insurance and
    lend less than the first-best a/2. Securities
    holdings are discouraged by adverse selection in
    the time 1 market
  • If E1B gt 0, type G will react to a decrease in M1
    by reducing lending and d2LG/dM1dA gt 0 if loan
    demand is rather inelastic
  • So, again informational asymmetries determine
    both lending and financing behavior

36
The Bank Capital Channel
  • Traditional monetary theories focus on the role
    of reserves in determining the volume of demand
    deposits. The bank lending channel analyzes the
    role of reserves in loan supply
  • Van den Heuvel (2002) discusses the role of (an
    imperfect market for) bank equity. He assumes a
    perfect market for debt
  • Lending will depend on the financial structure of
    the bank. The model also focuses on the maturity
    mismatch of assets and liabilities
  • Conclusion lending by banks with low capital has
    a delayed, but amplified, reaction to interest
    rate shocks

37
Heuvel (1)
  • The model includes capital adequacy regulations.
    The Basle accord established minimum capital
    requirements
  • The bank cannot readily issue new equity. But
    equity capital is endogenous through retained
    earnings
  • There is a tax advantage on debt (earnings are
    taxed at a rate ? gt 0)
  • Banks perform maturity transformation, leading to
    a serious interest rate risk. Banks are
    leveraged (compared to real firms), such that an
    interest rate increase results in a larger
    percentage change in equity (given that there is
    a profit squeeze)

38
Heuvel (2)
  • Assets loans L and securities S liabilities
    debt B and equity E. A L S B E
  • The bank issues Nt new loans at the beginning of
    each period. Each period a fraction ?u lt 1 is
    due. 1/ ?u is the loan portfolios average
    maturity. ?t1 is the fraction of loans actually
    repaid at the end of t (and can deviate from the
    due rate)
  • Loans are risky a fraction ?t1 of outstanding
    loans Lt goes bad as well as a fraction bt1 of
    the new loans Nt
  • Lt1 (1 - ?t1 - ?t1) Lt (1 - ?t1 bt1)Nt

39
Heuvel (3)
  • Downward sloping demand curve for loans some
    market power on part of the bank (due to whatever
    reason)
  • Contractual interest rate on new loans is a
    decreasing function of the amount of new loans
    made Nt ?(Nt) and ?(.) lt 0
  • The average contractual interest rate on all
    outstanding loans in period t, ?at is given by
  • ?at1 (1-?t1-?t1)Lt ?at(1-?t1bt1)Nt
    ?(Nt) /Lt1
  • bt1 b(Nt, ?t1) and b(.,.) increases in N

40
Heuvel (4)
  • Banks debt B is all short. Loans have a maturity
    longer than one, so there is a maturity mismatch
  • The bank can borrow liquidity freely at a rate rt
  • Only B - S can be determined, so tradable
    securities S 0 is assumed
  • No role for reservable or demand deposits (a bank
    can borrow/lend freely at the riskless rate r)
  • Banks have perfect access to insured and
    nonreversable deposits contracts (and this is not
    the case in the basic bank lending channel models)

41
Heuvel (5)
  • Accounting value of equity Et Lt - Bt
  • Equity evolves according to Et1 Et - Dt (1
    - ?)?t1 Dt dividends paid out and ?t1
    pre-tax accounting profits interest income on
    loans minus interest paid on banks debt net
    charge-offs on loans
  • ?t1 ?at(1 - ?t1)Lt (1 - bt1)Nt ?(Nt)
    rt(Lt Et Nt Dt) - (?t1Lt bt1Nt)
    ?F
  • ?F represents othe profit components

42
Heuvel (6) debt
  • Law of motion of debt. Note that debt has a tax
    advantage
  • Bt1 (1(1-?)rt)(Bt Nt Dt) - ?t1(Lt Nt )
    (1- ?)(?at(1-?t1)Lt (1-bt1)Nt ?(Nt) ?F) -
    ?(?t1Lt bt1Nt )
  • Interest costs are discounted by (1 - ?), ?t1 is
    the fraction of loans actually repaid at the end
    of t, net of tax interest receipts and the tax
    shield from charge-offs on loans

43
Heuvel (7) bank balance sheet (including new
loans and dividend)
  • Assets
  • Loans Lt Nt
  • Securities St ?St
  • Total At Nt ?St
  • Liabilities
  • Debt Bt Nt ?St Dt
  • Equity Et - Dt
  • Total At Nt ?St

44
Heuvel (8) capital regulation
  • Basle loans are in the highest risk category,
    mortgages and residential property have a risk
    weight of 50 and riskless securities in 0.
    Basle sets ?, the regulatory minimum, equal to
    0.04 for tier 1 capital and 0.08 for tier 2
  • The risk adjusted capital asset ratio RACAR at
    the beginning of the period RACARt Et / Lt
  • If Et gt ?Lt then Et - Dt ? ?(Lt Nt)
  • If Et lt ?Lt then Nt 0 and Dt 0 no new loans
    and no dividends

45
Heuvel (9) financial constraint
  • The bank cannot issue new equity, this implies
    that dividends must be nonnegative Dt ? 0
  • Shareholders do not price the risk of bank shares
    (risk neutral valuation)
  • Market value of bank equity is
  • Vt max Et?s0?( ?u0s-1(1 rtu)-1)Dts
  • So the problem is to maximize the market value of
    the bank subject to the constraints listed above.
    The bank assumes the interest rate rt, the
    repayment rate ?t and the fraction ?t of
    outstanding loans Lt that goes bad as given

46
Heuvel (10) optimization
  • State variables st (Et, Lt, ?at, rt). Control
    variables Dt and Nt
  • Bellman equation V(st) maxDt 1/(1 rt) Et
    V(st1)
  • Without the financial constraint we have VU. The
    lending decision is then independent of the
    financial position of the bank. The optimal
    policy functions of the unconstrained problem are
    NU(st) and DU(st)
  • NU(st) is NU(rt) only the interest rate matters
    MM! Optimal financial policy is to keep the risk
    adjusted capital ratio exactly to the minimum
    DU(st) Et - ?(Lt
    NU(rt))
  • Since the bank can always raise capital there is
    no need to hold a costly precautionary buffer of
    capital above the regulatory minimum

47
Heuvel (11) constrained
  • A constrained bank can lend at the unconstrained
    level NU(rt) if it starts its period with
    sufficient capital Et ? ?(Lt
    NU(rt))
  • Holding the additional equity is costly (debt is
    cheaper due to taxation), but will lead to a
    smaller likelihood that the financial constraint
    will bind. The bank should have Et-1 - Dt-1
    sufficiently high to ensure that Et ? ?(Lt
    NU(rt)) for all realizations of rt, ?t, and ?t
  • There is a tradeoff between holding more equity
    against the tax disadvantage
  • The optimal trade-off involves a positive
    probability of being financially constrained (see
    Heuvel for a proof)
  • It is not the case that financially constrained
    banks will always lend less N(st) ? NU(rt)

48
Summary
  • This lecture provides basic models of bank
    behavior under constraints
  • Constraints lead to relevance of financial
    structure and more complicated impact of monetary
    policy
  • Constraints differ in nature for instance the
    inability to raise new equity or the costs
    involved to liquidate loans
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com