Title: Lecture 2(a) Basics of Demand
1Lecture 2(a) Basics of Demand
2Why Study Demand
- Obvious Reason To help with forecasting
revenues - What will happen to sales tax revenues collected
from the sale of cigarettes if the price goes up
as a consequence of the Federal Governments
lawsuit? - Less Obvious Reason To help understand pricing
strategies - Why do some firms make it difficult to buy
unbundled--e.g., MS wants to sell Office or
Explorer as a package?
3What Is Involved in Building a Complete Theoryof
Demand?
- A complete theory is based on and begins with a
theory of individual demand - And then considers how individual behavior
aggregate to market behavior.
4The Theory of Individual Demand is Organized by
Conducting the Following Thought Experiment
What Determines How Much of _____ Do You Want to
Buy?
- Taste
- Price of the Good
- Income
- Price of Other Stuff
5Taste
- While may be the most important factor, but it is
also the factor that is most difficult to model
and forecast. - Therefore, the conventional approach in
microeconomics is to simply accept the consumers
tastes as given (often pretentiously invoking the
Latin expression non degustibus disputandemwhich
I think means, there is no arguing about tastes
and which I have no idea how to spell.) - Interestingly, though, a small but brave group of
economists have tried to formulate an economic
theory of taste formation. In this class,
though, well mostly accept the consumer as he or
she is.
6The Relationship Between Price and Quantity
- When price goes up, it seems very unlikely that a
consumer will choose to buy more (although can
you think of exceptions?) and there are good
reasons to think that higher prices will cause
consumption to fall . - (Note this prediction assumes that only price
changes.)
7This Seems Obvious, but It is Worth Thinking
About Exactly Why People Buy Less When Prices Go
Up
- Most consumers are likely to be faced with income
constraints and so as the price of something goes
up, they have less to spend on some goods. This
is easy to understand, but well give a simple
example in class. - Most consumers have preferences over most goods
that are consistent with diminishing marginal
utility.
8The relationship between prices of other goods
and demand(How Would My Demand for X Change if
the Price of Y Went Up?)
- Suppose X is a ticket to the opera in Verona,
Italy and Y is an airplane ticket to italy. - Suppose X is a ticket to the opera in Verona and
Y is a ticket to the first round of the Italian
Idol audition. - Obviously the relationship depends on the type of
goods - X is a Substitute for Y, if an increase in the
price of Y leads to an increase in the demand for
X - X is a Complement for Y, if an increase in the
price of Y leads to an decrease in the demand for
X
9The relationship between income and demand
- If I were Bill Gates, how would my life be
different? - Id buy more rides on private jets than I do now.
- But Id buy fewer coach tickets than now.
- The relationship between income and demand is
ambiguous. Thus, we have the following
definitions - Normal good Any good such that as income goes
up, demand goes up (e.g., Mercedes). - Inferior good Income goes up, demand goes down
(e.g., 1993 Mercury)
10Another way to make the same points
- What matters to most consumers is relative
values, such as the price of one good relative to
the price of another good and relative to the
income of the consumer
11A Useful Way to Describe Demand Demand Function
- It can be helpful in some circumstances to
express demand relationships mathematically. The
most common way this is done is to write out a
demand function relating the quantity demanded to
the other relevant variables. - Recall the Equibase problem where we might have
assumed that the quantity of track programs
demand (q) will depend on track attendance (A)
the price of the program (P) and the price of a
Daily Racing Form (Pd). Expressed in general
notation, we would have written - Q f(A,P,Pd)
- Of course these general expressions might not be
that helpful, in which case you might decide to
write down a more specific form of the function,
such as in the Equibase problem where we assumed - Q A(Pd-P) and A500, Pd5
- We dont have the time to talk about how one
might find a specific functional form for a
specific problem, except to point out that there
are ways. In particular a number of specific
statistical and econometric techniques have been
derived to estimate demand functions. - Sometimes it is useful to write the demand
relationship with Price on the left hand side of
the equation. Of course this is just a different
way of different way of saying the same thing,
but to help distinguish them we will refer to the
first expression (Q on the left hand side by
itself) as the demand function and the second
expression as the inverse demand functions. - When we draw a graph of such relationships it is
conventional to put the price on the vertical
axis and quantity on the horizontal axis. - Some economists (and most textbooks) make a
fetish out of the distinction between a shift in
the entire curve (usually caused by a change in
one of the many factors that influence demand and
referred to as a change in demand) and movement
along the demand curve (caused by a change in
price and referred to as a change in quantity
demanded.)
12Issues
- Market demand vs individual demand.
- At on level, this is just arithmetic. For
example, if each of 60 students demand 3 beers at
a price of 3, market demand will be 180. - But can you think of some goods where, an
individuals demand may be influenced by the
number of others demanding the good? - Market demand vs firm demand.
- This is something well think a lot more about
when we get to the part of the course on
competitive markets, but for now think about why
this distinction should matter. Also, think
about why the market demand is probably less
sensitive to price than an individual firms
demand. - What exactly do we mean by a good? That is, a
good can be distinguished by (among other
things). - Geography (beer at the ball park versus beer at
home) - Quality (diet beer versus heavy beer)
- Since demand measures a flow (that is, the amount
demanded over some period of time), what is the
relevant time.
13From Demand to Revenue
- It is obviously possible to derive total revenue
from demand simply by multiplying Q by P. - TRPQ.
- Since this is economics, we of course want
marginal revenue - Words MR is the change in TR when Q changes
- For discreet changes MRChange in TR/Change in Q
(approximate) - Calculus MR d TR/ dQ (precise)
14(No Transcript)
15- This example is consistent with demand being
given by - Q 1300- P or P1300-Q
- Thus
- Total Revenue PQ (1300-Q)Q 1300 Q Q2
- and
- Marginal Revenue dTR/dQ 1300 2Q
- (Remember the numbers for MR derived in the table
are only an approximation).
16Puzzle Why Does TR Increase and Then Decrease?
- Good News When price falls from to 500 from
600, you get 100 new passengers. Each of these
contributes an extra 500 in revenues. - Bad News In order to get the new customers, you
had to cut the price of tickets by 100 (from
600 to 500) for 700 passengers who would have
been willing to fly without the price reduction. - Summary MR(Revenue from new sales at the
new price-revenue lost from sales to old
customers at old price)/(number of new
customers. - Obvious (but useful) insight MR will be bigger,
the more new customers are attracted by the
reduced price
17Measuring the Responsiveness of Demand to Price
Elasticity of Demand
- Consider how much vital information is presented
by the following formula - Elasticity ( change in Quantity
Demanded)/(Change in Price) - If, for example, you were contemplating a 10
price cut, and you know the value for demand
elasticity, you would immediately be able to
predict how much sales would increase.
18Formulas for Demand Elasticity and Some
Observations
- Since demand elasticity is expressed in terms of
percentage changes (BTW, see if you can figure
out why it is important to work with percentages
instead of absolute changes), one way to write
the formula is - (?Q/Q)/(?P/P) (?Q/?P)(P/Q)
- When measuring discreet changes in any variable,
the calculation of change may depend on the
context of the problem. (Quick, tell me the
difference between a price of 5 and 4.) - In order to eliminate any confusion, it is often
useful to explicitly rely on calculus to express
elasticity. If we can write the demand function
as xD(p), then elasticity is - D(p)p/x
19More Fun Facts About Elasticity
- The value of elasticity will change depending on
where you are taking the measurement. That is,
for different values of p and x, the value of
elasticity may be different (I say may because
there are such things as constant elasticity
demand curves.) - Elasticity is actually a negative number (since
dp/dx is always negative). It is a common, but
not universal, convention to report it as an
absolute value. But if that convention is not
honored then elastic demand would describe a
situation where elasticity lt -1
20Relationship between MR and Elasticity
- If absolute value of elasticitygt1 (defined as
elastic), then MRgt0. This means that when p
goes down and q goes up, TR goes up. - If absolute value of elasticitylt1 (defined as
inelastic), then MRlt0 (I.e., when p goes down
and q goes up, TR goes down). - If absolute value of elasticity1 (defined as
unit elasticity), then MR0 (I.e., when p goes
down and q goes up, TR remains constant). - We can see from our example that this is true and
a bit of clever algebra done with the exact (that
is, calculus) definition of MR will also confirm
that it is true. But if you really understand
the intuitive definition of elasticity, it is
really almost common sense. - In fact, there is an extremely useful formula
that captures this entire relationship. Letting
v(x) stand for elasticity
21Quantity Price TR MR ?Q ?P Elasticity
500 800 400,000
600 700 420,000 200 18 13 1.36
700 600 420,000 0 15 15 1.00
800 500 400,000 -200 13 18 0.73
900 400 360,000 -400 12 22 0.53
Elasticity gt 1 means TR goes up
Elasticity lt 1 means TR goes down